You are on page 1of 10

environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/envsci

Modeling the impact of carbon farming on land use


in a New Zealand landscape

Jason M. Funk a,*, Christopher B. Field b,1, Suzi Kerr c,2, Adam Daigneault d,3
a
Environmental Defense Fund, 1875 Connecticut Ave. NW, Washington, DC 20009, USA
b
Department of Global Ecology, Carnegie Institution of Washington, 260 Panama St. Stanford, CA 94305, USA
c
Motu Economic and Public Policy Research, Level 1, 97 Cuba Street, PO Box 24390, Wellington 6142, New Zealand
d
Manaaki Whenua/Landcare Research, 231 Morrin Road St Johns Auckland 1072, Private Bag 92170 Auckland Mail
Centre, Auckland 1142, New Zealand

article info abstract

Article history: The opportunity for private landowners to receive carbon credits from reforestation, or
Received 23 January 2013 ‘‘carbon farming,’’ will change the relative value of land uses for landowners, potentially
Received in revised form having an impact on land-use decisions. We constructed a spatial model to evaluate the
13 August 2013 potential scale and location of carbon farming in a New Zealand landscape, the size of resulting
Accepted 13 August 2013 carbon stocks, and the economic trade-offs for landowners considering carbon farming. We
Available online 7 September 2013 modeled the carbon accumulation, economic value, and potential uptake of a carbon farming
management system that utilized native forest regeneration on set-aside land.
Keywords: For the study area, the Gisborne District of New Zealand, we found that regrowth of
Carbon sequestration native forest species on estimated Kyoto-eligible marginal pasture has the technical poten-
Carbon farming tial to store 104.2 Mt CO2-e over 70 years over 379,000 eligible hectares. We found 102,951 ha
Forest carbon where the potential economic revenues from carbon in our most conservative scenario
Land-use modeling could generate NZ$912 million in excess of expected grazing revenues over 70 years of forest
Emissions trading regeneration. Our results suggest that reforestation could out-compete grazing on at least
Land-use change 27% of eligible land in the Gisborne District. Sensitivity analysis shows that uncertainty
about the scale of carbon sequestration can have a sizeable effect on the estimated
profitability of carbon farming, but estimated land conversion is strongly affected by the
choice of discount rates among landowners and the utilization of compatible incentives for
other environmental services. Potential profits from carbon farming are strongly affected by
the uncertainty of the future value of carbon credits.
# 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

available to landowners. Here, we develop an approach to


1. Introduction estimate the impact of these rewards on land use for a New
Zealand landscape by (1) developing a modeling methodology
Policy incentives for land management activities that seques- for quantifying the spatial and temporal dynamics of potential
ter carbon create a shift in the rewards for different land uses carbon sequestration, (2) examining the revenue potential

* Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 202 572 3388.


E-mail addresses: jfunk74@gmail.com, jfunk@edf.org (J.M. Funk), cfield@ciw.edu (C.B. Field), suzi.kerr@motu.org.nz (S. Kerr),
daigneaulta@landcareresearch.co.nz (A. Daigneault).
1
Tel.: +1 650 462 1047.
2
Tel.: +64 4 939 4250.
3
Tel.: +64 9 574 4100.
1462-9011/$ – see front matter # 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2013.08.008
2 environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10

under a variety of carbon price scenarios, (3) exploring the 1.1. Research objectives
impact of concurrent incentives for reforestation, and (4)
comparing the expected revenue from reforestation with This analysis had several objectives:
expected returns from grazing.
New Zealand adopted a policy in 2007 called the Perma- 1. Model the amount of Kyoto credits that could be generated
nent Forest Sink Initiative (PFSI), which creates a mechanism by the conversion of eligible land in the Gisborne District to
for landowners to receive carbon credits for eligible forests on native forest;
their lands (MAF, 2007b). Under New Zealand’s domestic 2. Model the economic revenue potential of these credits
rules, any net conversion of land use to new forests after the under several price scenarios;
baseline date of January 1, 1990 is considered eligible to 3. Model how complementary incentives add to the value of
receive carbon credits. native reforestation as a ‘‘carbon farming’’ land manage-
The availability of carbon credits to private landowners ment system;
will increase the economic value of reforestation on 4. Compare carbon farming as a land use with the opportunity
eligible lands. Other incentives, such as non-timber forest cost of grazing.
products and subsidies for erosion control or biodiversity
protection can provide additional revenues for permanent
forests. Therefore, landowners who manage their land to 2. Study area: land-use and policy
comply with one or more of these programs can earn multiple interactions
revenues from a single block of land. For some lands, the
additional revenue earned from carbon credits may make The Gisborne District in the North Island of New Zealand has a
forest regrowth economically competitive with other land number of factors that could make it favorable for carbon
uses. To encompass all of these possibilities, we use the broad farming. It is a large area (about 835,500 ha) dominated by
term ‘‘carbon farming’’ to refer to any land use in which rugged hills, and it has relatively small population of 44,460, of
landowners capture economic benefit linked to the amount of whom 19,758 (44.4%) self-identify as Ma-ori, the indigenous
carbon sequestration. people of New Zealand (Statistics New Zealand, 2013).
Although this definition could also include timber Residents are relatively isolated and remote from access to
plantations, in the analysis presented here, we examine a markets. Geologically, much of the area has a high risk of
land management system that utilizes native forest landslides on steep slopes, especially slopes that have been
restoration to earn carbon credits through the PFSI. We cleared of trees (Phillips and Gomez, 2007; Glade, 2003). After a
analyze native forest regeneration for several reasons: (1) major cyclone caused extensive landslides in 1989, the NZ
because the potential for carbon policy to trigger government sponsored a program called the East Coast
expansion of the extent of native forests is important Forestry Project (ECFP) to subsidize landowners planting trees
ecologically and culturally, (2) because native forests deliver on erodible areas.
a greater variety of ecological co-benefits than timber In the Gisborne District, native forests can regenerate on
plantations, and (3) because the conditions necessary for abandoned pastures in a forest successional process that
earning credits would require substantial changes to the predominantly begins with the invasion of manuka tree
current management regimes of timber forests, which is species (Leptospermum scoparium), or sometimes kanuka
not the focus of this work. Nevertheless, we recognize (Kunzea ericoides). These pioneer species establish easily in
that under some conditions, a modified system of timber pastures where grazing pressure is low (i.e. less than 2 stock
forestry to include carbon credits may be optimal in many units per hectare per year), which is frequently the case with
places. hill country pastures in the Gisborne District, where carrying
Our purpose is to identify areas and conditions where a capacity is low (Landcare Research, 2000). Without periodic
carbon management system could compete economically clearing, manuka typically sprouts from wind-dispersed seeds
with grazing. By mapping these areas spatially, we estimate in pastures, grows through a shrub phase, and eventually
the areas of potential conversion and the total resulting matures as a closed canopy ‘‘scrub’’ phase of small Trees 6–10
carbon sequestration in the region, as well as identify areas m in height (Wardle, 1991; Stephens et al., 2005). Its rapid
of higher or lower revenue potential from carbon farming. establishment and growth mean that some areas that were
For this study, we examined the Gisborne District of New still pasture in 1990 were closed-canopy scrub by the
Zealand – a district with large areas of marginal grazing beginning of the first Kyoto commitment period in 2008, even
land, where native tree species quickly invade pastures with when managed for low-intensity grazing.
low grazing pressure, and where indigenous Ma-ori land- Native forests in various stages of maturity offer econom-
owners often struggle to profitably manage large areas of ically valuable goods and services. For instance, residents use
communally owned land. To evaluate whether carbon native forests and scrub as a source of fuelwood, medicine,
farming could be a beneficial enterprise, we compare the and food (Stephens et al., 2005). The manuka tree (L.
net present value of carbon farming and grazing over a long scoparium) is used for medicinal tea and oil, and it supplies
time horizon (70 years) in order to capture the long-term honey with unique antibacterial properties (Stephens et al.,
implications of a commitment to ‘‘permanent’’ reforesta- 2005; Allen et al., 1991; Molan and Russell, 1988). Manuka oil
tion. We also evaluate a variety of discount rates to reflect and honey from the Gisborne District are produced commer-
the different time preferences that landowners may apply to cially and marketed internationally (Kerr, M., personal
their land-use decisions. communication, 2006).
environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10 3

Native forest cover also provides other co-benefits, such as different uses, including average stock carrying capacity
reduction in soil erosion and improvement to water quality, and (CCAV), average annual rainfall, and soil fertility (Landcare
some of these are incentivized through government programs Research, 2000).
for new forest establishment. Because these programs could 4. Political boundaries, roads, rivers, and lakes.
deliver supplementary revenues on some areas eligible for the
PFSI, we analyzed the financial implications of these revenues 3.2. Carbon model
for landowners, in combination with the PFSI.
In 1992 the government initiated the ECFP for the Gisborne We constructed a spatial and temporal model of carbon
District, administered at that time by the Ministry of accumulation for indigenous forests, using data from the LUC
Agriculture and Forestry (MAF) (MAF, 2006). This program and NZLRI databases. Our model uses soil fertility and average
offers grants to private landowners to stabilize erodible land, annual rainfall as spatial parameters in a forest growth model.
including through an option for native forest regeneration. In The model is based on empirical work by Trotter et al. (2005).
2011, the ECFP had enrolled and facilitated forest establish-
ment on over 35,552 ha of land (MAF, 2011b). 3.2.1. Carbon growth model
In 2008, the government introduced the Afforestation Grant Following Trotter et al. (2005), we constructed a model of tree
Scheme (AGS), delivering grants to plant exotic or indigenous growth and carbon sequestration, using empirically derived
tree species (MAF, 2008), but this program is not consistent relationships to such factors as soil quality and annual
with our definition of carbon farming because revenues to precipitation. We assumed that the accumulation of carbon
landowners are not linked to the amount of carbon seques- over the first 70 years would be due primarily to the growth of
tration the land delivers.4 Therefore, we do not include the manuka (L. scoparium), which establishes dense stands in
AGS in this analysis. abandoned pastures and remains the dominant species for
Other programs are targeted at biodiversity protection. several decades. Our model is consistent with empirical
Through the Department of Conservation (DoC), landowners estimates of carbon accumulation over time in abandoned
may enroll in one of two programs for retiring land for pastures in the Gisborne District, in which manuka and
biodiversity conservation: the Queen Elizabeth II Trust (QE2) kanuka were dominant for at least 55 years (Ford-Robertson
and Nga Whenua Rahui (NWR).5 These programs provide et al., 1999; Scott et al., 2000). In the model, the accumulation of
landowners with financial assistance for fencing and pest carbon within each age class was estimated using a Gompertz
management for lands with high biodiversity value. equation for a sigmoidal growth curve, of the form:

1eðxtÞ
YðtÞ ¼ a  eb 0:1 (1)
3. Methods
where t is time since establishment, in years; Y(t) is accumu-
3.1. Data lated CO2-equivalents for the area, in tons.
We fit the following parameters for the model using
To model the carbon sequestration potential for the regener- Trotter’s empirical data: a = 2.93; b = 0.46; x = 0.07.
ation of native forests in the Gisborne District, we used the In addition to the estimation of carbon accumulation for
following datasets: each age class, we also modeled the area of coverage that each
new age class would occupy in each year. We assumed the
1. LUCAS Land Use Map 1990–2008 (LUM v003), a national cumulative distribution of the area occupied by each succes-
land-use classification database created for greenhouse gas sive age class would also follow a sigmoidal curve. Starting
reporting (Thompson et al., 2003). with bare ground in year 0, we constructed a function to model
2. Land Use Capability (LUC) classification, a ranking system the fraction of the area, f(t), covered by trees, resulting in total
of land quality for different productive uses, including coverage by age 10. This equation was of the form:
forest productivity (Jessen et al., 1999).
1
3. NZ Land Resources Inventory (NZLRI), a database that f ðtÞ ¼ 1  (2)
1 þ 1=etþ5
includes factors that influence the productivity of land for
where t is the number of years since establishment. Thus,
4
for each year t up to year 10, a new age class is established for
In this case, the AGS is not compatible with carbon farming as
some fraction of the area and the accumulation of carbon
defined here, because (1) the government owns the rights to
carbon credits generated in the program, (2) landowners bid
within the age class is modeled for that age class according to
through a tender process, which may not directly link to the Eq. (1).
amount of carbon they sequester during the grant period, (3) lands This model was used to calculate carbon accumulation for
enrolled in the PFSI, ECFP, or other government programs are not soil of average productivity (class 3) and high rainfall
eligible, and (4) lands already partially or wholly reforested are not (1500 mm). For other soil and rainfall classes, we assumed
eligible. These factors eliminate much of the land considered in each soil class difference resulted in a 6% change in carbon
our analysis and make comparisons with grazing management
sequestration and each 100 mm decrease in rainfall from the
less interesting, since economic theory would suggest that land-
owners should offer a tender just higher than their opportunity highest class (1500 mm) resulted in a 5% decrease in carbon
cost, which is represented by our grazing scenarios in this analy- sequestration (see Trotter et al., 2005). In total, we modeled 40
sis. unique combinations of soil and rainfall classes, of which 27
5
The NWR program applies only to Māori land. were found on eligible land in the study area, to generate a
4 environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10

carbon sequestration potential ranging from 204 and 348 t under various policy constraints (van Vuuren et al., 2007; Tol,
CO2/ha. More details on the data used to develop the soil 2005; Nordhaus and Boyer, 2000).6 We incorporated recent
fertility and rainfall classifications are discussed in the projections of the price of carbon rising at a real rate of 3.8%
Supplementary Material. per year, and used three scenarios for different starting prices:
The model was calculated using Microsoft Excel and output NZ$15, NZ$25 and NZ$35 per ton CO2-e, respectively. These
tables were imported into the spatial attribute files for the price scenarios are higher than recent carbon prices in NZ, but
productivity layer in the spatial database. they are consistent with scenarios used in NZ government
policy assessments (Denne and Bond-Smith, 2010).
3.3. Management scenarios
3.5. Comparison scenarios for grazing
In addition to the impact of the value of carbon, the uptake of
carbon farming will also depend upon the value of overlapping We calculated the comparative income from grazing using a
revenue streams from other management activities – such as combination of data on grazing productivity and average gross
biodiversity and erosion control incentives, and private margins. Grazing productivity was calculated on a per hectare
markets for manuka honey – in the areas set aside for forest basis using the average stock carrying capacity spatial data
regeneration. We used spatial data to analyze the potential for layer (CCAV) for the Gisborne District, as mapped in the NZLRI
different areas to yield revenue from two scenarios for carbon database. This data layer is based on empirical quantification
farming, incorporating the timing of the revenues into the NPV of the average carrying capacity that can be maintained by a
calculation. We present the analysis of the following scenari- grazing operation with average levels of inputs for that land
os: type, expressed in normalized ‘‘stock units.’’ The estimated
A: Carbon alone. We estimate the area eligible for the PFSI carrying capacity of a particular grazing species (or combina-
and calculate the net present value of the stream of revenue tion of species) can be readily converted to ‘‘stock units’’ using
from carbon, under a range of price scenarios detailed below. standard conversion rates included in the database.
B: Carbon + ECFP + Conservation Program + manuka hon- We used a range of expected gross margins – defined as
ey. We estimate the area eligible for each of these sources of ‘‘the gross income from an enterprise less the variable costs
revenue, then we estimate the net present value of the incurred in achieving that income’’ (Rae, 2003) – to test the
revenue that landowners would receive by taking advantage of sensitivity of land conversion to farmers’ expectations about
as many of these sources as they can. This scenario provides their ability to earn profits. Gross margins do not include fixed
an upper bound estimate of the potential economic benefits to or overhead costs, which can vary from farm to farm. The
landowners from afforestation. average gross margin for each stock unit was multiplied by the
We attempted to explicitly incorporate the value of non- stock unit carrying capacity for each hectare, yielding the
carbon benefits in our model using the following information: expected stream of grazing gross margins for all areas of
eligible land, under each price scenario. To compare these
grazing scenarios to carbon revenue scenarios, we discounted
- ECFP: We model a total payment of $1512 per ha, with a each revenue stream to obtain the net present value.
payment of $756 in year 1 and a payment of $756 in year 5, as For grazing, we used three scenarios, with constant real
accepted in the revised ECFP guidelines released in 2007 gross margins of NZ$10, NZ$20, and NZ$30 per stock unit,
(Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2007a). respectively. These scenarios were based on weighted pre-tax
- Manuka honey: We model payments of $50 per ha per year, farm profit per stock unit reported in the Beef and Lamb/
starting in year 1 and continuing through year 70. Actual Economic Service Farm Survey, conducted in participating
revenues from honey production are difficult to estimate for farms, which ranged from $2.49 to $29.79 per stock unit in the
both biological and economic reasons, so we have used a years 2003–2011 on hill country in the Eastern North Island,
conservative estimate of the additional marginal revenue to including the Gisborne District (Beef and Lamb, 2011). A more
landowners from honey from native forests. recent report confirmed that prices have continued within a
- Conservation Program: Nga Whenua Rahui/QE2 Trust: We similar range in recent years (MAF, 2011a). Historically, farm
model a payment of $150 in year 1. Actual payments per profit per stock unit in real dollars has been relatively stable in
hectare from these programs depend on the quality of the this range (Beef and Lamb, 2011), following a period of
habitat being protected and the costs of project establish- adjustment after economic reforms in the mid-1980s. We
ment (Mohi, M., Nga Whenua Rahui, personal communica- include a high profit scenario of NZ$30 per stock unit to reflect
tion, 2006). We adopted a simple case of enrolling land in one the possibility that landowners may expect grazing to be more
of these programs in the year of establishment and receiving profitable in the future than it has been historically.
a payment of $150 per ha. We expect costs to be lower for carbon farming than
grazing, on average, because of reductions in (1) labor units, (2)
3.4. Carbon price scenarios: creation and application costs of capital, and (3) depreciation of capital inputs.
Therefore, we expect that a comparison of gross margins to
The value of carbon sequestration for farmers will depend
upon the future price of carbon credits or other incentives. 6
This price need not be delivered through a market for carbon
There are many plausible scenarios for the future price of credits; the comparisons presented here are valid for any incen-
carbon, including a set of studies that use general equilibrium tive if the value of the incentive is proportional to the annual
modeling to calculate an expected shadow price for carbon amount of carbon sequestered.
environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10 5

gross margins will yield a conservative estimate of conversion higher, and all of class 8. We mapped these areas and created
to carbon farming. However, on some farms the relative attribute fields with values corresponding to the NPV of grant
savings from converting grazing to carbon farming may be payments (on a per hectare basis) announced in July 2007
partially or completely offset by the added costs of (1) (MAF, 2007a). We applied discount rates of 0%, 5%, and 10% to
additional fencing, (2) specialized labor from certifiers, and these payments, to match the rates applied to carbon and
(3) application and audit processing in the PFSI. These costs grazing revenues.
can vary from farm to farm and are not captured in this We performed similar procedures for manuka honey
analysis. production and conservation. We considered all Kyoto-eligible
land to also be eligible for conservation incentives and honey
3.6. Discount rates production, and we added the combined value of these
additional discounted revenues to each appropriate scenario,
The selection of discount rates reflects the potential variation to evaluate the impact of these revenues on potential land
in landowners’ real rate of time preference and allows us to conversion.
compare today’s land-use allocation decisions on an equiva-
lent basis, even though revenues from each system will differ 3.9. Comparison of carbon farming to grazing
across management scenarios from year to year. We model
carbon revenue each year as the sequestration that year Similarly, we modeled the expected value of grazing under
multiplied by the carbon price. Since the flow of income from three price scenarios. We used the average stock carrying
carbon farming varies over time, discounting the stream of capacity layer to map the sustainable stock density across the
income from carbon farming and the comparable stream from landscape. We then applied an expected gross margin of $10,
the current land use allows us to normalize the net present $20, and $30 per stock unit, respectively. Grazing gross
value (NPV) of the different options. margins were discounted at each of the rates applied to the
We used three discount rates commonly used by the NZ carbon scenarios (0%, 5%, and 10%). We compared the net
Government to evaluate the impacts of policies: 0, 5, and 10% present value of grazing gross margins to the net present value
(New Zealand Treasury, 2005). The combination of discount of carbon farming revenues under all scenarios, matched by
rates and gross margins serve to represent landowner profiles discount rate. Our approach is similar to Kerr et al. (2012), but
that we have observed in the Gisborne District. For instance, the analysis differs because we used finer-grained spatial data
some landowners take into account the impacts of land-use to map the economic potential for conversion, whereas Kerr
decisions far into the future – a view that can be represented and colleagues estimated conversion on the basis of empirical
by applying a low discount rate of 0%. Other landowners may data about past conversions, mapped in a grid at a coarser
be ‘‘capital starved’’ and have opportunities to invest in farm level. This means that our results represent the economic
improvements with a high rate of return once they get access potential for carbon farming, whereas Kerr and colleagues
to capital. These landowners are represented by applying a estimate actual potential based on past behavior.
high discount rate of 10%. Discount rates in the intermediate
range represent landowners who have access to capital and
may have other low- to moderate-risk opportunities for 4. Results
investment (not necessarily on their own farms).
4.1. Carbon potential on eligible land
3.7. Spatial integration
Using our carbon model, we estimated that if all eligible land
For each area of analysis, NPV of revenue per hectare from were reforested, it would store about 104.2 Mt CO2-e by the end
each scenario was calculated and mapped. We compared the of the 70-year time period. For comparison, New Zealand’s
NPV of each grazing scenario to each carbon farming scenario, total greenhouse gas emissions in 2010 were 71.65 Mt CO2-e
under all management options, using the same landowner (MfE, 2012).
discount rate to compare each pair of land-use options (carbon On eligible land, our model predicted a range of total carbon
farming vs. grazing). These are not the exhaustive set of all storage between 204.2 and 347.6 t CO2-e per ha. The maximum
price possibilities, but they are useful for showing how a range in any one year on the most productive land was 12.8 t CO2-e
price scenarios affects the revenue from carbon farming. We per ha. The area-weighted mean sequestration after 70 years
then projected the expected difference in revenue for each was 275.16 t per ha. The distribution reflects the spatial
year on each unique area of land. distribution of land with different cumulative carbon storage
capacity across the district (Fig. 1).
3.8. Estimating eligible land and modeling carbon
sequestration potential 4.2. Value of carbon farming on eligible land

We estimated the extent of PFSI eligible land using the Under a conservative price scenario starting at NZ$15 per ton
database of eligible land available from the Ministry for the CO2-e, if all estimated eligible land were reforested, the total
Environment (MfE, 2010). expected revenue (0% discount rate) from carbon credits over
In addition, areas eligible for ECFP were considered. The 70 years for the Gisborne District would exceed NZ$4.42
target land for ECFP is based on Land Use Capability billion, or an average annual revenue of NZ$63 million (NZ$167
classification of highly erodible lands: LUC classes 7e18 and per ha per year). The spatial distribution of the revenue reflects
6 environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10

Fig. 1 – Map of cumulative CO2-e storage after 70 years on Fig. 3 – The estimated present value of grazing ($/ha) in the
eligible land. East Cape, assuming constant margins of $20 per stock
unit and a discount rate of 0%. The boundary of the study
area is shown with a dashed line.

the pattern of carbon accumulation (Fig. 2) because the spatial


factors affecting sequestration (soil quality, rainfall) are static convert their land to carbon farming, even if carbon farming
in the model. would deliver greater value to future owners of the land.
The effect of discounting revenues allows us to evaluate the
relative importance of price scenarios in the future. Compar- 4.3. The impact of complementary incentives on the value
ing scenarios across discount rates, we see that the discount of native reforestation
rate has a strong effect on the value of a decision to enter
carbon farming today. Landowners may express different By adding supplemental revenues to the carbon farming
discount rates across the Gisborne District (or even apply management system, complementary incentives increase the
different discount rates to different decisions), but the impact total revenue on some areas of land, and potentially increase
of applying a uniform discount rate to the district creates the area converted to carbon farming. With certain areas of
important results. land eligible for multiple revenues, the attractiveness of
Comparing price scenarios within discount rates, we see carbon farming increased, shifting revenues upward in those
that at rate of 5% leads to areas of conversion that are equal or areas. In some cases, the combined revenues are sufficient to
less than those expected a rate of 0%, and a rate of 10% leads to make carbon farming competitive on more land.
areas equal or less areas than a 5% rate. This suggests that Comparing total potential revenues from carbon credits to
landowners who value short-term profits will be less likely to these other revenues, none of them approach the same impact
on the district as carbon revenues, but the additional revenues
add substantially to the NPV per hectare on eligible areas,
resulting in more potential conversion (Table 2).

4.4. Comparisons of carbon farming to grazing

To the extent that economics determine land use, the impact


of carbon farming on the land-use composition of the district
will depend upon its value to landowners, relative to other
land-use options. As a result, we must compare the net
present value of carbon farming to the net present value of
competing land uses. Here, we compare the present value of 70
years of carbon farming to the present value of 70 years of
grazing on estimated Kyoto-eligible land.
We made a spatial comparison of the economic value of
carbon farming to the economic value of grazing, since grazing
productivity varies widely across the Gisborne District (Fig. 3).
We then selected areas where the NPV of carbon farming
Fig. 2 – Spatial distribution of present value of carbon ($/ha) exceeded grazing by overlaying and subtracting the NPV of
on eligible land with a carbon price of $15 per ton, rising grazing from the NPV of carbon farming. This estimate of land
3.8% per year, using a discount rate of 0%. that earns higher returns from carbon farming provides a
environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10 7

Fig. 4 – Estimated areas of conversion from grazing to carbon Fig. 5 – Estimated areas of conversion from grazing to
farming and net revenue in excess of expected grazing carbon farming with farmers utilizing carbon revenue and
margins with farmers utilizing carbon revenue only, revenues from compatible activities, starting with a
starting with a carbon price of $15 per ton and rising 3.8% carbon price of $15 per ton and rising 3.8% per year,
per year, assuming gross margins of $20 per stock unit, assuming gross margins of $20 per stock unit, applying a
applying a discount rate of 10%. Total area = 98,339 ha. discount rate of 10%. Total area = 277,692 ha.

spatially explicit estimate of potential land-use conversion


(Fig. 4). 5. Discussion
For a conservative scenario starting with a relatively low
price for carbon ($15 per ton), moderate gross margins for 5.1. Implications for land use and rural development
grazing ($20 per stock unit), and a discount rate of 10%, we
estimate 98,339 ha of conversion if only carbon revenue is Carbon farming in the Gisborne District is not a panacea for
considered. However, when revenues from other sources are New Zealand’s climate obligations, nor will it provide the
also considered, this figure rises to 277,692 ha (Fig. 5). Of this majority of emissions reductions to help the country meet its
area, about 160,000 ha are lands where the NPV of carbon international commitments. However, the Gisborne District
farming is at least 20% greater than the NPV of grazing does have substantial capacity to create forest sinks that can
(including about 34,000 ha where the estimated NPV of grazing reduce New Zealand’s net emissions for years to come. If
is zero). Results of all price and management scenarios are policies continue to deliver incentives for carbon sequestra-
presented in Tables 1 and 2. tion along with existing incentives for other non-carbon

Table 1 – Estimated conversion areas under different price scenarios and discount rates, comparing grazing gross margins
to carbon revenue only.
Starting carbon price Grazing gross margins per stock unit

$10/SU $20/SU $30/SU


Area of conversion (ha; percentage of eligible area)
0% discount rate
$15/t CO2-e 356,082 (94%) 276,971 (73%) 102,951 (27%)
$25/t CO2-e 358,129 (95%) 353,605 (93%) 102,951 (27%)
$35/t CO2-e 358,129 (95%) 355,663 (94%) 102,951 (27%)
5% discount rate
$15/t CO2-e 353,892 (93%) 245,795 (65%) 98,339 (26%)
$25/t CO2-e 358,106 (95%) 345,240 (91%) 102,951 (27%)
$35/t CO2-e 358,129 (95%) 355,629 (94%) 344,524 (91%)
10% discount rate
$15/t CO2-e 333,590 (88%) 98,339 (26%) 75,570 (20%)
$25/t CO2-e 356,082 (94%) 276,971 (73%) 102,951 (27%)
$35/t CO2-e 357,869 (95%) 344,524 (91%) 266,596 (70%)
Carbon farming with revenue from carbon only.
8 environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10

Table 2 – Estimated conversion areas under different price scenarios and discount rates, comparing grazing gross margins
to combined revenues from carbon and other sources.
Starting carbon price Grazing gross margins per stock unit

$10/SU $20/SU $30/SU


Area of conversion (ha; percentage of eligible area)
0% discount rate
$15/t CO2-e 360,471 (95%) 334,905 (88%) 152,479 (40%)
$25/t CO2-e 361,182 (95%) 356,273 (94%) 355,120 (94%)
$35/t CO2-e 361,182 (95%) 356,556 (94%) 354,690 (94%)
5% discount rate
$15/t CO2-e 360,605 (95%) 337,539 (89%) 152,931 (40%)
$25/t CO2-e 361,246 (95%) 358,518 (95%) 335,120 (88%)
$35/t CO2-e 361,246 (95%) 358,716 (95%) 354,690 (94%)
10% discount rate
$15/t CO2-e 359,458 (95%) 277,692 (73%) 106,790 (28%)
$25/t CO2-e 361,440 (95%) 348,024 (91%) 263,184 (70%)
$35/t CO2-e 361,669 (95%) 358,752 (95%) 335,394 (89%)
Carbon farming with revenue from ECFP, honey, and conservation programs.

benefits, a conservative scenario (using a 10% discount rate, conversion is often greater than 70% of the eligible area, so
starting price of $15 per ton CO2-e, and expected gross margins revenue from other sources has its greatest effect on
of $20 per stock unit) suggests that landowners in the Gisborne conversion at low carbon prices and high grazing margins.
District would be marginally better off if they converted up to For example, at a discount rate of 5%, initial carbon price of $25
278,000 ha of eligible land to carbon farming. Within this area per ton, and grazing margins of $30 per SU, revenues from
are over 75,000 ha of erodible land eligible for the ECFP. The non-carbon sources would be sufficient to trigger an expan-
addition of carbon revenue will make conversion of this sion in the converted area from 102,951 ha to 335,102 ha. The
erodible land more attractive to landowners, potentially dynamics of the honey market, in particular, may play an
leading to better protection of soil, waterways, and down- important role in real conversion of land use, due to the fact
stream infrastructure. that it requires little input by the landowner, it pays back on an
Nevertheless, reasonable expectations about farmers’ annual basis, and landowners could easily expand to take
behavior would suggest that uptake will be well below the advantage of increases in the market over the next few years.
economic potential. A sensitivity analysis that varies farm- Whether these short-term dynamics will stimulate the
ers’ expectations of future gross margins creates substantial conversion of land to forest is uncertain, but they could
changes in the predicted area of conversion. Farmers’ time strongly mitigate the problem of short-term revenue for
preference (expressed in the discount rate) also has a carbon farming.
large impact, partly because the rising value of carbon in In our model scenarios, revenue from manuka honey
the future carries greater weight today when we apply low becomes available immediately after setting aside clear
discount rates. With higher discount rates, grazing repre- pasture because farmers may incorporate adjacent areas of
sents a better option on more land, because it yields existing scrub, smoothing the stream of income over time and
greater value in the near term. Such variations in expressed increasing their cash flow during the period of conversion
time preferences (in both directions) might be found more from forest to pasture. Sophisticated landowners could use
commonly among Ma-ori landowners, who often value the timing of carbon and other revenues to smooth their
benefits to future generations (sometimes leading to low income with strategic timing of land retirement to achieve a
discount rates) but also face de facto institutional barriers to steady stream of income from carbon credits by enrolling land
capital (sometimes leading to high discount rates). as it approaches peak sequestration rates, 15–20 years after
Changes in the average carbon price have a strong effect on manuka establishment. This would reduce the impact of
predictions of conversion, especially at moderate and high enrollment costs, while allowing farmers to continue grazing
discount rates. For example, at a discount rate of 0%, carbon on some pastures. Enrollment in the ECFP could accelerate this
only outcompetes grazing on about 103,000 ha regardless of process on land eligible for that program.
the carbon price, but at a discount rate of 5% a change in initial Where landowners are willing to sacrifice economic
carbon price from $15 to $35 triggers an increase in conversion returns for the sake of non-economic benefits from forests,
by an additional 242,000 ha. The same change in initial carbon the area of uptake might increase markedly. Many landowners
price has a lower impact on conversion when a discount rate find value in protecting areas of native forest. The opportunity
of 10% is applied, triggering an additional 164,000 ha of carbon to earn carbon credits during the process may be enough of an
farming (Table 1). incentive to make large-scale conversions worthwhile. This
The addition of non-carbon revenues greatly increases the raises intergenerational equity issues, because today’s owners
area of land that would be retired, although the increase varies will benefit from selling carbon credits, but future owners
with the discount rate. For moderate to high carbon prices and could inherit large liabilities if they decide to deforest the land.
low to moderate grazing margins, the predicted area of However, if carbon prices rise as predicted by some models,
environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10 9

the overall benefit of carbon farming may be economically reasonable expectations. Much of this area is truly marginal
worthwhile, especially over long time horizons – though for grazing, supporting less than two stock units per ha. At the
recent carbon prices in New Zealand have not supported this farm level, some of this land may even be earning negative
prediction (Point Carbon, 2013). If the cultural value of forests returns, implying that land abandonment is already the best
is high among owners – as is evident among many Ma-ori alternative. Carbon farming, using native forest regeneration
landowners – then native forest reversion might be taken up combined with other compatible sources of revenue, offers a
broadly. If it occurred over a large fraction of the available financially attractive land-use option for many low-produc-
land, the decrease in scale of farming activities in the Gisborne tivity pastures in the Gisborne District.
District could have important implications for the District’s Expectations about the adoption of carbon farming under
tax base, as well as infrastructure and services for grazing the PFSI or other initiatives in the Gisborne District must be
operations. Negative impacts of retiring land could be framed by a variety of factors relevant to land-use decisions.
mitigated, at any scale, by investing carbon farming revenues Our analysis shows substantial potential for carbon seques-
into the intensification of production on other land. This raises tration, due to favorable biophysical factors, including (1) rapid
questions about leakage from these projects, but under regrowth rates, (2) large area of eligibility, and (3) areas with
current rules any additional emissions from reinvestment low productivity for other uses. Under reasonable expecta-
would not be counted as leakage. tions for carbon prices, conversion of Kyoto-eligible land from
Landowners may also find management options that are grazing to carbon farming could generate competitive income
intermediate between forestry and grazing, such as agrofor- on much of the eligible land area (378,672 ha), with higher
estry, and these could combine benefits of both management areas of conversion expected when landowners also utilize
practices. Such intermediate management scenarios might complementary incentives.
have an added benefit of mitigating market risk and policy risk Landowners have reasons for caution, due to scientific
for the revenue streams evaluated separately in this analysis. uncertainties in measurements and models, market uncer-
However, the eligibility criteria for the PFSI, ECFP, and tainties about the price of carbon, and policy uncertainties,
biodiversity programs, by design, would make it difficult to which could lead to a collapse of carbon markets or substantial
integrate these with on-going grazing. As a result, the changes in the price of carbon. Policymakers could encourage
potential for integrated management systems in NZ is limited. more certainty by standardizing and simplifying enrollment
The greatest value of land-use conversion in the Gisborne procedures in multiple sustainability initiatives, and estab-
District may be in other areas besides climate mitigation. The lishing guidelines for monitoring procedures, establishing
impact of reforestation for providing unpriced benefits from durable rules for trading carbon credits in order to improve
ecosystem services may add to or even surpass the value of landowners’ ability to make land-use commitments based on
forests for climate mitigation. These impacts depend largely long-term expectations. Flexibility in commitments for land-
on the spatial location of reforestation. In erodible catch- owners, such as rewarding temporary storage of carbon, could
ments, increasing forest area may reduce sediment loading to also encourage participation.
streams, improving water quality and freshwater habitat, as
well as reducing peak flows and sediment transport down-
stream, which affect infrastructure such as bridges and roads. Acknowledgements
Increases in forest cover may also provide other important
biological benefits. Where new forests extend existing forests The authors would like to thank Amy Rosenthal and Charles
or provide corridors between them, they may create dispersal Huang (World Wildlife Fund) and two anonymous reviewers
pathways for species to reach new habitats. However, the for their generous and thoughtful contributions to this work.
biodiversity impacts of dispersal pathways and increased The work was supported by the Tindall Foundation (New
forest area might not all be positive: these can also facilitate Zealand), the National Science Foundation (United States), and
the higher populations and greater dispersal of introduced the Sustainable Farming Fund (New Zealand).
exotic species like the brushtail possum (Trichosurus vulpecula),
which negatively impact the diversity and health of native
forest ecosystems and can be costly to control (Jones et al., Appendix A. Supplementary data
2012). These interactions between land cover, connectivity,
species diversity, and carbon accumulation are complex and Supplementary data associated with this article can be
should provide fruitful opportunities for future research. found, in the online version, at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/
j.envsci.2013.08.008.

6. Conclusions references

Identifying the spatial locations favorable for carbon seques-


tration is important for landowners making decisions about Allen, K.L., Molan, P.C., Reid, G.M., 1991. A survey of the
antibacterial activity of some New Zealand honeys. J. Pharm.
land-use allocation, as well as for policymakers who need to
Pharmacol. 43, 817–822.
understand the land-use impacts of policy choices. In this
Beef and Lamb New Zealand, 2011. Sheep and Beef Farm Survey
analysis, we demonstrated that 75,000–361,000 ha of land (20– Eastern North Island. http://www.beeflambnz.com/
96% of eligible land) in the Gisborne District could earn higher information/on-farm-data-and-industry-production/sheep-
gross margins from carbon farming than from grazing, under beef-farm-survey/eni/ (accessed 11.08.13).
10 environmental science & policy 37 (2014) 1–10

Denne, T., Bond-Smith, S., 2010. Carbon Price Forecasts. July Sink Covenant. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry,
2010 Covec Report Prepared for Parliamentary Wellington.
Commissioner for the Environment. . Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2006. East Coast Forestry
Ford-Robertson, J., Robertson, K., Maclaren, P., 1999. Modelling Program Review. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry,
the effect of land-use practices on greenhouse gas emissions Wellington.
and sinks in New Zealand. Environ. Sci. Policy 2, 135–144. Molan, P.C., Russell, K.M., 1988. Non-peroxide antibacterial
Glade, T., 2003. Landslide occurrence as a response to land use activity in some New Zealand honeys. J. Apicultural Res. 27,
change: a review of evidence from New Zealand. Catena 51 62–67.
(2003) 297–314. New Zealand Treasury, 2005. Cost Benefit Analysis Primer,
Jones, C., Barron, J., Warburton, B., Coleman, M., Lyver, P.O’B., Version 1.12. The Treasury, Wellington http://
Nugent, G., 2012. Serving two masters. Reconciling economic www.treasury.govt.nz/publications/guidance/planning/
and biodiversity outcomes of brushtail possum (Trichosurus costbenefitanalysis/primer/15.htm (accessed 27.12.12).
vulpecula) fur harvest in an indigenous New Zealand forest. Nordhaus, W.D., Boyer, J., 2000. Warming the World: Economic
Biol. Conserv. 153, 143–152. Models of Global Warming. MIT Press.
Jessen, M.R., Crippen, T.F., Page, M.J., Rijkse, W.C., Harmsworth, Phillips, J.D., Gomez, B., 2007. Controls on sediment transport
G.R., McLeod, M., 1999. Land use capability classification of from the Waipaoa River basin, New Zealand. Basin Res. 19 (2)
the Gisborne-East Coast region: A report to accompany the 241–252.
second edition New Zealand Land Resource Inventory. Point Carbon, 2013. Carbon Market Australia–New Zealand. 06
Landcare Research, Science Series No. 21, Lincoln. (07) 1–7 http://www.pointcarbon.com/polopoly_fs/
Kerr, S., Anastasiadis, S., Olssen, A., Power, W., Timar, L., Zhang, 1.2470534!CMANZ20130719.pdf (accessed 11.08.13).
W., 2012. Spatial and temporal responses to an emissions Rae, G., 2003. Profit Plan: Crop and Livestock Gross Margins.
trading scheme covering agriculture and forestry: simulation Canterbury Agriculture Ltd., Ashburton, New Zealand.
results from New Zealand. Forests 3, 1133–1156. Scott, N.A., White, J.D., Townsend, J.A., Whitehead, D.,
Landcare Research, 2000. New Zealand Land Resources Leathwick, J.R., Hall, G.M.J., Marden, M., Rogers, G.N.D.,
Inventory, Version 3.1. http://lris.scinfo.org.nz/layer/76/ Watson, A.J., Whaley, P.T., 2000. Carbon and
(accessed 11.08.13). nitrogen distribution and accumulation in a New
Ministry for the Environment, 2012. New Zealand’s Greenhouse Zealand scrubland ecosystem. Can. J. For. Res. 30,
Gas Inventory 1990–2010. Ministry for the Environment, ME 1246–1522.
1095. Statistics New Zealand, 2013. 2006 Census Tables. http://
Ministry for the Environment, 2010. Land Use and Carbon www.stats.govt.nz/Census/2006CensusHomePage/
Analysis System: Satellite Imagery Interpretation Guide for Tables.aspx (accessed 23.01.13).
Land-use Classes. Ministry for the Environment, ME 1024, Stephens, J.M.C., Molan, P.C., Clarkson, B.D., 2005. A review of
Wellington. Leptospermum scoparium (Mytaceae) in New Zealand. New
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2011a. Pastoral Monitoring Zealand Journal of Botany 43 (2) 431–449.
2011: National Sheep and Beef. http://www.maf.govt.nz/ Thompson, S., Gruner, I., Gapare, N., 2003. New Zealand Land
news-resources/statistics-forecasting/statistical- Cover Database Version 2: Illustrated Guide to Target
publications/pastoral-monitoring.aspx (accessed 27.12.12). Classes. Terralink, Wellington, New Zealand.
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2011b. Review of Tol, R.S.J., 2005. The marginal damage costs of carbon dioxide
Afforestation Schemes: Permanent Forest Sink Initiative, emissions: an assessment of the uncertainties. Energy Policy
Afforestation Grant Scheme, East Coast Forestry Project, 33, 2064–2074.
Sustainable Land Management (Hill Country Erosion) Trotter, C., Tate, K., Scott, N., Townsend, J., Wilde, H., Lambie,
Programme. MAF Information Paper No. 2011/07. Ministry of S., Marden, M., Pinkney, T., 2005. Afforestation/reforestation
Agriculture and Forestry, Wellington. of New Zealand marginal pasture lands by indigenous
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2008. Afforestation Grant shrublands: the potential for Kyoto forest sinks. Ann. For.
Scheme Guidelines. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, Sci. 62 (8) 865–871.
Wellington. van Vuuren, D.P., Den Elzen, M.G.J., Lucas, P.L., Eickhout, B.,
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2007a. East Coast Forestry Strengers, B.J., van Ruijven, B., Wonink, S., van Houdt, R.,
Project Guidelines. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2007. Stabilizing greenhouse gas concentrations at low
Wellington. levels: an assessment of reduction strategies and costs.
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2007b. The Permanent Clim. Change 81 (2) 119–159.
Forest Sink Initiative: A Consultation Document on the Wardle, P., 1991. Vegetation of New Zealand. Cambridge
Proposed Regulations, Cost Recovery Methods, and Forest University Press, Cambridge.

You might also like