You are on page 1of 13

MARGARET C.

CAMPBELL *

Using two studies, the author examines the influence of the inferred
motive for a firm's price increase on perceptions of price unfairness. Prior
to the research presented here, the only established causal antecedent
of perceived price unfairness was increased relative profit. In Study 1, the
author extends the existing research by demonstrating that the inferred
motive, as well as inferred relative profit, provides causal explanation of
perceived price unfairness. When participants inferred that the firm had a
negative motive for a price increase, the increase was perceived as sig-
nificantly less fair than the same increase when participants inferred that
the firm had a positive motive. In addition, the author shows in Study 2
that the firm's reputation can influence the inferred motive, thereby alter-
ing perceptions of price unfairness. Specifically, participants sometimes
gave a firm with a good reputation the benefit of the doubt when inferring
motive. If the "good" firm did not profit from the price increase, participants
inferred significantly more positive motives than if it did profit. The firm
with a poor reputation did not receive this benefit; inferred motive was
equally negative regardless of whether the firm profited from the price
increase. Together, these studies provide evidence that consumer infer-
ences of the motive for a price increase influence the perceived fairness
of the increase. Furthermore, reputation is shown to moderate the effect
of inferred relative profit on inferred motive. Finally, analyses show that
perceived unfairness leads to lower shopping intentions and demonstrate
that perceived unfairness mediates the effects of inferred motive and
relative price on consumers' shopping intentions.

Perceptions of Price Unfairness:


Antecedents and Consequences

A critical activity for many marketing managers is to pricing decisions effectively, the marketer must be able to
establish product pricing strategy. To set effective prices, the understand both economic and psychological responses to
marketer attempts to predict how consumers are likely to various prices and price changes.
respond to different price points or price changes. Research Perceived price fairness has been identified as one psy-
has established the importance of the psychological under- chological factor that exerts an important influence on con-
pinnings of price perception and demonstrated that a variety sumers' reactions to prices (e.g., Etzioni 1988; Kahneman,
of psychological factors influence consumers' responses to Knetsch, and Thaler 1986a, b). Research suggests that con-
price (Kamen and Toman 1970; Monroe 1973). To manage sumers sometimes are concerned with the fairness of a price,
particularly of a price increase, and that they dislike and are
often unwilling to pay a price that is perceived as unfair
*Margaret C. Campbell is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Anderson
(e.g., Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986a, b; Martins and
Graduate School of Management, University of California at Los Angeles Monroe 1994; Urbany, Madden, and Dickson 1989).
(e-mail: meg.campbell@anderson.ucla.edu). Financial assistance from the Although there is some disagreement as to the duration of
UCLA Marketing Study Center and the UCLA Academic Senate is grate- the effect (i.e., whether it is short- or long-run), experimen-
fully acknowledged. The valuable comments of Hal Kassarjian, Bill
McKelvey, Donald Morrison, Atanu Sinha, Joel E. Urbany, Bernie Wiener,
tal data consistently indicate that consumers often resist
and seminar participants at the University of Washington, the University of price increases that are perceived as unfair. Thus, regardless
Illinois Pricing Camp, and the Marketing Science Institute Behavioral of the duration of the effect, consumer resistance can result
Pricing Conference are greatly appreciated. The author also thanks the edi- in lower overall profit to the firm (Franciosi et al. 1995;
tor and four anonymous JMR reviewers for useful suggestions during the Kachelmeier, Limberg, and Schadewald 1991). In addition,
review process. To interact with colleagues on specific articles in this issue,
see "Feedback" on the JMR Web site at www.ama.orglpubs/jmr. negative consumer reactions to perceived unfair prices can
result in consumer boycotts (e.g., Goldman 1994), civil

Journal of Marketing Research


187 Vol. XXXVI (May 1999), 187-199
188 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, MAY 1999

Figure 1 these scenarios follow (Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler


RELATIONS AMONG ANTECEDENTS AND CONSEQUENCES 1986b, pp. 732-33):
OF PERCEIVED UNFAIRNESS
Question 7. Suppose that, due to a transportation mix-
up, there is a local shortage of lettuce and
the wholesale price has increased. A local
grocerhas boughtthe usual quantity of let-
tuce at a price that is 30 cents per head
higher than normal. The grocer raises the
price of lettuce to customers by 30 cents
per head.
(N = lOl) Acceptable 79% Unfair21%
action (Kaufmann, Ortmeyer, and Smith 1991), or lower
Question 10. A grocery store has several months' sup-
sales (Grover 1994).
ply of peanutbutter in stock, which it has
Although research establishes the importance of con- on the shelves and in the storeroom. The
sumers' perceptions of price unfairness to marketers' pricing owner hears that the wholesale price of
decisions, the critical question of "what is fair?" has not peanut butter has increased and immedi-
been answered thoroughly. Much of the work to date does ately raises the priceon the current stock
not examine what causes a price to be perceived as fair or of peanutbutter.
unfair; there is not yet a complete understanding of factors
(N = 147)Acceptable 21% Unfair79%
that influence perceived unfairness (Franciosi et al. 1995;
Kalapurakal, Dickson, and Urbany 1990). Identifying The high degree of consistency among which scenarios
antecedents of price unfairness will aid marketing managers the surveyed consumers found to be fair and which were
in developing pricing strategy and is necessary for a more perceived as unfair indicates that there are existing commu-
comprehensive understanding of perceived price unfairness nity standards for setting fair prices. The overall pattern of
and a more general theory of price. findings led Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (l986b) to
The objective of this research is to identify factors that suggest that market behavior is affected by goals in addition
influence consumers' perceptions of price fairness. Drawing to the purely self-interested rational utility maximization
from the literature on fairness and attribution theory, I iden- assumed in neoclassical economic theory. Specifically,
tify two factors that directly affect the perceived fairness of Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1986b, p. 729) propose the
a price change: inferred relative profit and consumers' infer- "principle of dual entitlement," which suggests that per-
ences about the firm's motive for the price change. Further- ceived unfairness results when a price is increased (a viola-
more, I identify a factor that indirectly affects perceptions of tion of the reference price) such that a firm increases the
price fairness by influencing inferred motive. Specifically, profit (violating the reference profit), but that an increased
drawing from research on reputation effects, I propose that price is perceived as fair when it maintains the firm's exist-
the firm's prior reputation can affect inferred motive by ing level of profit.
moderating the impact of inferred relative profit on inferred The principle of dual entitlement indicates that consumers
motive. Study 1 examines the proposed effects of relative have a sense of a reference transaction (the price and other
profit and inferred motive, showing that both these factors conditions of the sale, often based on the status quo) and that
influence perceptions of price fairness, as predicted. The the perception of the fairness of a change from the reference
results indicate that a consumer perceives a price increase as price is judged relative to this. Kahneman, Knetsch, and
unfair when he or she infers that the firm has a negative Thaler (1986b) suggest that consumers perceive unfairness
motive (i.e., that the firm is trying to take advantage of or when they view a firm's pricing actions as violating the ref-
exploit consumers in one way or another) whether or not the erence price without the "excuse" of maintaining the firm's
price change increases the firm's profit. If, conversely, the reference profit (as in the peanut butter example, in which
consumer infers that the firm has some positive motive for the firm had not yet incurred any greater costs and, thus, an
the price change, perceptions of unfairness are attenuated. increased price was regarded as unfair). Price increases that
Study 2 examines the interaction between the firm's prior appear justified by increased costs to the firm, conversely,
reputation and inferred relative profit. The results demon- are perceived as fair (as in the lettuce example, in which the
strate an asymmetric effect of the firm's reputation on firm was perceived as passing on increased costs incurred
inferred motive. Reputation moderates the effect of inferred by the firm).
relative profit on inferences that are made about the firm's The principle of dual entitlement presents a parsimonious
motive, thereby indirectly influencing perceptions of price explanation for much of the data reported by Kahneman,
fairness. A schematic of the proposed effects appears in Fig- Knetsch, and Thaler (1986a, b), which suggests that con-
ure 1. sumers' inferences of relative profit (i.e., profit resulting
from the price change, relative to reference profit) is one
THE PRINCIPLE OF DUAL ENTITLEMENT factor in how consumers assess the fairness of a price
Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1986a, b) use both increase. Experimental research examining this issue pro-
experimental and survey research to identify situations that vides support for the role of inferred relative profit in per-
consumers perceived as fair or unfair. For example, con- ceptions of fairness; subjects find prices unfair when they
sumers were presented with a variety of scenarios in which are perceived to lead to increased profit for the firm but
a firm makes a pricing decision; consumers then provided more fair when they are not perceived to increase profit
evaluations of the fairness of the described prices. Two of (Franciosi et al. 1995; Kachelmeier, Limberg, and Schade-
Perceptions of Price Unfairness 189

wald 1991). However, it is not clear that the relative profit suggestion that fairness is considered when a price increase
effect suggested by the principle of dual entitlement fully violates the reference transaction.
captures all factors that lead to perceptions of price unfair- Attribution research finds that the specific attributions
ness. Evidence suggests that there may be justifications for made for an act or event, as well as the resulting affective
a price change, in addition to that of maintaining reference and cognitive responses, are influenced by the intentions or
profit, that mitigate perceptions of unfairness (Dickson and motives inferred (for a review, see Weiner 1992). For exam-
Kalapurakal 1994; Kalapurakal, Dickson, and Urbany ple, consider a situation in which Person A drops his papers
1990). and another person steps on them. Person A will make a dif-
The research presented here expands on the principle of ferent attribution and respond differently if he infers that the
dual entitlement and suggests an additional factor that leads other person stepped on his papers with the motive to keep
to perceptions of price unfairness, namely, inferred motive. them from blowing away than if he infers that the person's
The prediction is that consumers respond to more than just motive was to damage the papers (Graham, Hudley, and
the extent to which a price change is inferred to increase the Williams 1992). An act is perceived and evaluated nega-
firm's profit and make additional inferences about the firm's tively when it is inferred to arise from a negative motive on
motive. Specifically, this article presents and explores the the part of the actor. When negative motive is inferred, the
concept that, though consumers assume that firms are gen- perceived responsibility of the actor increases, and the
erally profit-seeking, they make richer inferences about the behavior may be perceived as aggressive or unfair (Betan-
marketer's particular motive or intention for a given price court and Blair 1992; Dodge and Coie 1987; Fincham and
increase (i.e., what moved or induced the firm to take the Jaspars 1980; Kidd and Utne 1978; Weiner 1995). This
price action) and that the inferred motive influences percep- attribution-based research demonstrates that inferences of
tions of unfairness. Some motives for a price will be per- negative motives lead to negative attributions and
ceived as positive or benevolent (e.g., desire to help a char- responses.
ity), whereas others will be perceived as negative or greedy Research also demonstrates that justifications or explana-
(e.g., desire to exploit sudden increased consumer demand), tions for an act influence perceptions offairness (Bies 1986,
depending on the extent to which the motive is perceived to 1987; Bies and Shapiro 1987; Brockner and Greenberg
take advantage of or exploit consumers. 1989; Fincham and Jaspers 1980; Greenberg 1988). For
If inferred motive has the predicted direct impact on per- example, when a justification for a negative outcome is pro-
ceptions of price fairness, factors that influence inferred vided, the outcome is perceived as more fair than when the
motive will affect perceived price fairness indirectly. The same outcome arises with no justification offered (Bies and
research presented here proposes that the firm's reputation is Shapiro 1988). Explanations perceived to demonstrate "neg-
one such factor. This research hypothesizes and tests ative" (e.g., insincere or manipulative) motives increase per-
whether the firm's reputation moderates the impact of ceived unfairness (Greenberg and Ornstein 1983). Overall,
inferred relative profit on inferred motive. When the firm "it is the point of these studies that accounts of mitigating
has a good reputation, the inferred relative profit will influ- circumstances discourage persons ... from attributing malev-
ence inferred motive, but this will not be the case when the olent motives to the decision-maker" (Greenberg 1990, p.
firm has a poor reputation. 130).
The research presented here contributes to the existing In summary, research from the attributional perspective
understanding of perceptions of price unfairness by propos- indicates that people make inferences about motives and that
ing that these perceptions are influenced by qualitative (i.e., whether the inferred motive is positive or negative influ-
motive), as well as quantitative (i.e., relative profit), infer- ences perceptions of the act. I extend this research and sug-
ences about the firm. This research identifies inferred gest that the factor of inferred motive is likely to provide
motive as an antecedent of perceived price unfairness while insight to when a price increase is likely to be perceived as
providing new support for the antecedent role of inferred fair or unfair. I propose that consumers sometimes will make
relative profit. This research further contributes to the liter- inferences about the specific motive a finn has for a price
ature by demonstrating that a contextual factor, namely, the increase. If the consumer sees an increase and attributes it to
firm's reputation, influences inferred motive, thereby affect- the finn's negative motive, such as a motive to take advan-
ing consumers' perceptions of price fairness. tage of a sudden increase in consumer need, the price will be
perceived as unfair. In contrast, if the price is attributed to a
TOWARD AN "INFERRED MOTIVE" THEORY OF positive or benevolent motive, such as to aid a good cause or
PERCEIVED PRICE UNFAIRNESS equitably distribute a scarce good, it will be perceived as fair.
Attribution theory and related streams of research provide As noted previously, the current literature on perceptions of
insight to the inferences that people make when they won- price fairness suggests that inferred relative profit is an
der why an event occurred. This research thus can assist in important factor that influences perceptions of price unfair-
understanding consumers' inferences about why a firm ness. I add to this literature by proposing that inferred motive
increased a price above the reference price. Attribution is another factor that influences perceptions of price fairness.
research indicates that people are likely to search for causal
HI: The violation of reference profit will influence perceived
explanations for an event when the event is surprising faimess such that, when the consumer infers that a price re-
and/or negative (Folkes 1988; Weiner 1985). An unexpected sults in more than normal profit, the price will be perceived
price increase is both surprising and negative for consumers as unfair relative to when the consumer infers that the prof-
and thus is likely to lead to consumer consideration of why it is no more than normal.
the firm raised the price. It should be noted that this idea is H2: The motive attributed to the firm will influence perceived
consistent with Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler's (1986a, b) fairness suchthat,whentheconsumer infers thatthefirm has
190 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, MAY 1999

a negative motive, the pricewill be perceived as unfairrela- doubt in terms of inferences of credibility, whereas a firm
tive to when the consumer does not infera negative motive. with a poor reputation is not (Goldberg and Hartwick 1990).
Following on this, I expect reputation to influence the
HI' following previous research, posits an effect of inferences of motive a consumer makes when exposed to a
inferred relative profit. H2 proposes an additional effect of price increase by moderating the impact of inferred profit on
inferred motive, such that the same price will be perceived inferred motive. When the pricing situation suggests the
as fair or unfair depending on the inferred motive of the possibility that the firm has a negative motive, the firm's
price setter. Similar to Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler's reputation will affect whether the inferred profit influences
(l986a, b), this conceptualization suggests that consumers inferred motives. Specifically, the goodwill value of a good
respond to the perceived reasons for the price and that one reputation is such that the consumer will use his or her infer-
"justifiable" reason for a price increase is to protect refer- ences of relative profit to infer the motive of the firm for
ence profit. Furthermore, this expands on previous work by raising the price. When consumers infer that the price
suggesting that there are many reasons, in addition to that of increase did not result in increased profit to the firm, they
needing to preserve reference profit, that can mitigate per- will give a firm with a good reputation the benefit of the
ceptions of unfairness. Not only do consumers care about doubt, inferring good motives for the firm's price increase,
the quantitative profit earned by the firm, but they also care even though the situation suggests the possibility of bad
about the qualitative character of the price setter's motives. motives. However, when consumers infer that relative profit
For example, consumers are likely to perceive an increased is high, inferred motive will be negative, even for the firm
price for bottled water following an earthquake as unfair; with a good reputation. A firm with a poor reputation will
they are likely to infer that the retailer is (l) making addi- not receive the same inferential leniency. That is, when a
tional profit and (2) motivated to take advantage of con- firm has a poor reputation, inferred profit will not affect
sumers' increase in demand. Information on both profit inferred motive.
(e.g., shipping costs to the retailer have increased because of
disruptions in distribution) and motive (e.g., the retailer is H3: When the pricing situation suggests a negative motive, the
raising the price to ration bottles of water to prevent a stock- firm's reputation will moderate the impact of inferred profit
out) are proposed to attenuate perceptions of unfairness. In on inferred motive. When the firm has a goodreputation, in-
short, in addition to inferred relative profit, a salient justifi- ferredrelative profit will affectinferred motive such that no
able or positive motive will mitigate the perceived unfair- increase in inferred profit will lead to a more favorable in-
ness of a price increase by reducing inferences of negative ferred motive compared with increased inferred profit.
motive. Whenthe firm has a poorreputation, inferred profitwill not
affect inferred motive.
REPUTATION AND INFERRED MOTIVE In summary, this suggests that there will be an asymmet-
An important implication of the presented framework is ric effect of reputation. A good reputation has goodwill
that understanding of perceived price fairness can be value that will cause consumers to take a more lenient view
increased by identifying factors that affect the motives that of the firm's motives when the pricing situation suggests a
consumers infer. Factors that influence the inferred motive negative motive but profit is inferred to be no more than nor-
will affect perceived price fairness indirectly. Specifically, mal. In this case, the firm will benefit from a good reputa-
factors that limit inferences of negative motives or increase tion because consumers will give the firm the benefit of the
inferences of positive motives will lead to perceptions of doubt when inferring motives for the price change. This
fairer prices. effect of good reputation on inferred motive will lead to per-
A firm's reputation is one factor that is likely to affect ceptions that the price increase is fair.
inferred motive. Reputation is based on the history of the
firm's past actions. Existing research indicates that con- THE EFFECT OF PERCEIVED UNFAIRNESS
sumers, as well as competitors, sometimes use the reputa- As noted previously, research demonstrates a negative
tion of a firm to make inferences about it (Herbig and effect of perceptions of price unfairness on a variety of out-
Milewicz 1993; Herbig, Milewicz, and Golden 1994; comes of importance to the firm. Research also indicates
Shapiro 1982). This research indicates that consumers that though consumers are willing to take on some costs to
believe they can infer current motives and predict future resist unfair prices, there is a limit to the costs that con-
actions of the firm by using their understanding of the firm's sumers will bear before accepting a price that is perceived as
past motives and behaviors, as indicated by the firm's repu- unfair (see Urbany, Madden, and Dickson 1989). Consumer
tation. Motives are inferred that seem to be consistent with resistance to an unfair price demands that consumers give
the firm's prior reputation. up something of value. Naturally, there are limits to what
An important aspect of reputation is that a good reputa- consumers are willing to sacrifice in any given situation.
tion is believed to have "goodwill" value (Shapiro 1982). However, overall it is expected that perceived price unfair-
That is, a good reputation is expected to gain greater ness will lead to some consumer resistance; further explo-
leniency from consumers and soften consumers' reactions to ration of the limits of this resistance is left to additional
firms' actions. Reputation thus is expected to moderate the research.
impact of other variables on consumers' inferences, percep- The primary purposes of the research presented here are
tions, and responses. For example, one study finds that rep- to examine inferred motive as an antecedent of perceptions
utation interacts with the extremity of advertising claim of unfairness and the influence of reputation on inferred
information; when an advertising claim is extreme, a firm motive. In addition, this work follows prior research by
with a good reputation appears to be given the benefit of the proposing that perceptions of price unfairness are likely to
Perceptions of Price Unfairness 191

affect consumers' willingness to conduct business with the the perceived unfairness ofthe price (H) and H 2) . This leads
price-setting firm negatively. This resistance is expected to to the suggestion that the firm's prior reputation will influ-
go beyond the particular product affected by the price ence inferred motive such that a firm with a good reputation
increase, more generally influencing consumers' willing- is given the benefit of the doubt in terms of an effect of
ness to purchase from the firm. inferred profit on inferred motive, but a firm with a poor
reputation is not (H3) . Reputation thereby will influence per-
H4: Perceived price unfairness will affect consumer likelihood ceived price unfairness indirectly. Perceived unfairness is
of shopping at a firm such that the likelihood of shopping expected to lower the likelihood that a consumer will
will be lower whena firm is perceived to haveset an unfair
patronize the firm (H4) .
pricethan whenthe priceis perceived as fair.
Two studies were conducted to test these hypotheses. In
To summarize, is it proposed that, in addition to inferred Study 1, inferred relative profit and motive were varied to
relative profit, inferred motive for a price change influences enable tests of H) and H 2 . The data also were used to exam-
ine H4 • In Study 2, reputation and inferred relative profit
Figure 2 were manipulated in the context of a pricing situation that
STUDY 1 SCENARIOS suggested a negative motive. This enabled examination of
H 2, H 3 , and H4 • Descriptions of these studies follow.
Scenario J: More than Normal Profit. Negative Motive
STUDY 1
This past winter, My Size Barbie was a very popular gift, so popular that
many stores sold out of the doll. One large retailer in Van Nuys sold out of Study 1 used a 2 x 2 between-subject design, crossing
My Size Barbie at the beginning of December and was sold out for almost motive (negative, positive) and relative profit (more than
three weeks. One week before Christmas, an employee discovered one My
Size Barbie in a storeroom. The managers of the store knew that many
usual, no more than usual). Participants were fully
customers would like to buy the doll. They decided to sell the doll by employed part-time MBA students. The average age of par-
auction and announced over the store's loudspeaker that they would sell the ticipants was 33.4 years, and there were 78 men and 30
doll to whichever customer offered to pay the highest price. women.
Fair: 20% Unfair: 70% Neither: 10%
Stimuli
Scenario 2: More than Normal Profit. Positive Motive The stimuli consisted of scenarios describing a retailer's
decision to increase a price. The experimental factors of
This past winter, My Size Barbie was a very popular gift, so popular that
many stores sold out of the doll. One large retailer in Van Nuys sold out of motive and relative profit were manipulated by including
My Size Barbie at the beginning of December and was sold out for almost different pieces of information in the basic scenario.
three weeks. One week before Christmas, an employee discovered one My Previous research has found that auctions can be perceived
Size Barbie in a storeroom. The managers of the store knew that many (I) to result in higher than normal profits and (2) as unfair
customers would like to buy the doll. They decided to sell the doll by
auction and announced over the store's loudspeaker that they would sell the
by everyday consumers (Holt 1995; Kahneman, Knetsch,
doll to whichever customer offered to pay the highest price. The profits and Thaler 1986a, b). In addition, a pretest suggested that
from the auction sale would go to help the company fund an on-site consumers sometimes perceive an auction as taking advan-
employee childcare facility. tage of consumer demand. Thus, the basic scenario
Fair: 65.5% Unfair: 27.5% Neither: 7% described an auction of a popular child's toy. When no addi-
tional information was provided, this auction was expected
Scenario 3: No More than Normal Profit. Negative Motive to create the negative motive (i.e., the firm is taking advan-
tage of consumers), higher profit (i.e., the retailer will have
This past winter, My Size Barbie was a very popular gift, so popular that
many stores sold out of the doll. One large retailer in Van Nuys sold out of higher net profitability by auctioning off the doll than by
My Size Barbie at the beginning of December and was sold out for almost selling it at the reference price) condition. Subjects were
three weeks. One week before Christmas, an employee discovered one My expected to infer that the firm was motivated to take advan-
Size Barbie in a storeroom. The managers of the store knew that many tage of high consumer demand to make more than normal
customers would like to buy the doll. They decided to sell the doll by
auction and announced over the store's loudspeaker that they would sell the
profit on the sale of the doll. This basic scenario was modi-
doll to whichever customer offered to pay the highest price. After one fied to change inferred motive from negative to positive, net
customer got very angry and complained, the managers said that profits profit to approximately the same as normal, or both. The
from the auction sale would go to Toys for Tots (a charitable foundation scenarios are presented in Figure 2.
that gives toys to poor children during the holidays). Inferred motive was manipulated by including informa-
Fair: 44.8% Unfair: 41.4% Neither: 13.8% tion that the firm would use the profit from the auction sale
to fund an on-site employee daycare center; this changed
Scenario 4: No More than Normal Profit. Positive Motive inferred motive without affecting inferred profit.' Although
This past winter, My Size Barbie was a very popular gift, so popular that the scenario suggests a salient, positive motive-the firm
many stores sold out of the doll. One large retailer in Van Nuys sold out of
My Size Barbie at the beginning of December and was sold out for almost
three weeks. One week before Christmas, an employee discovered one My 'This is only one of a variety of possible manipulations of inferred
Size Barbie in a storeroom. The managers of the store knew that many motive. Although previous research has demonstrated that consumers
customers would like to buy the doll. They decided to sell the doll by sometimes perceive auctions as unfair, it is my contention that this is
auction and announced over the store's loudspeaker that they would sell the because they infer negative motive to take advantage. If consumers infer a
doll to whichever customer offered to pay the highest price. The profits positive motive for an auction, they would perceive it as fair. For example,
from the auction sale would go to Toys for Tots (a charitable foundation information suggesting that the firm was using the auction as a way of allo-
that gives toys to poor children during the holidays). cating a scarce good probably would be perceived as fair; this also would
Fair: 80% Unfair: 10% Neither: 10% be likely to be an effective manipulation of "additional profit, good
motive."
192 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, MAY 1999

wants to use the money for a "good" thing-the firm itself effects as covariates, and they were dropped from further
is still making more than normal profit from the auction analysis.
sale. In other words, the firm's choice to use the profit for
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
good affects inferred motive but does not affect that the firm
makes, and keeps, additional money.- Manipulation Checks
The negative motive, no increased profit condition was The same 2 (motive) x 2 (relative profit) ANOVA model
created with information that the firm gives the profit from was used to analyze all variables. First, manipulation check
the sale to a charity (and so does not itself profit from the measures were analyzed to verify that the experimental fac-
auction), but that the decision to donate the profit is made tors varied, as intended. Analysis of participants' ratings of
only after a customer complains. Thus, the inference that t~e net financial profit revealed that inferred relative profit var-
motive was to take advantage is not attenuated by the deci- ied by profit condition as intended (F(l,102) = 41.38, .p <
sion to donate because that decision apparently was made .001). Profit was manipulated successfully to be perceived
only in response to customer criticism. as higher than normal (mean =5.75) in the increased profit
Information that the firm's initial plan is to donate the conditions and approximately normal (mean = 3.75; note
profit from the sale to the charity manipulated both pro~t that 4 is labeled as "about the same") in the no increased
and motive. As described previously, the firm does not gam profit conditions. No other effects were significant (see
increased profit because it gives the proceeds away. In addi- Table 1 for individual cell means).
tion, this suggests a positive motive, namely, to aid a charity. Analysis with the two-item scale of inferred motive as the
Dependent Measures dependent variable found a significant main effect of moti~e
information (F(l,102) = 54.81, P ~ .?01), such t~~t the P~SI­
The study used a between-subjects design; each partici- tive motive conditions resulted 10 inferred posiuve motive
pant read only one scenario. After reading through a sce- (mean = 5.33) relative to the negative conditions (mean =
nario, participants provided fairness evaluations on a scale 3.28), regardless of relative profit made. This analysis also
from 1 ("very fair") to 7 ("very unfair"). Ratings of 1 to 3
revealed a significant effect of the profit condition (F(l,102)
are described as "fair," ratings of 5 to 7 are described as
"unfair," and ratings of 4, the midpoint of the scale, are
=4.13, p < .05) qualified by a significant interaction (F(l,102)
= 4.63, P < .05). Examination of the means reveals that these
described as "neither." The percentages of participants in results were due to the no increased profit, positive motive
each category are shown in Figure 2. A small space was pro-
cell. Not making any profit apparently makes the motive of
vided for thoughts and feelings about the pricing decision,
the retailer seem especially good; the participants were
and then participants indicated on a seven-point scale how
strongly of the opinion that there was no motive to take
the scenario affected the likelihood that they would shop at
advantage in this condition.3 Whereas the inferred motive in
the retailer if shopping for toys (1 ="a lot less likely to shop
this cell (6.05) was significantly more positive than in the
at this store" and 7 = "a lot more likely to shop at this
increased profit, positive motive cell (mean = 4.83; F(l,102)
store").
= 7.95, P < .01), there was no effect of profit when the
Manipulation Checks inferred motive was negative (mean(profit) = 3.3, mean(no
Next, participants completed manipulation checks. First, profit) = 3.3; F < 1). T?us, .though.th~re was some effect of
profit on inferred motive, It was limited to one cell and the
participants evaluated the store managers' motives on a two-
item scale. Two seven-point scales were anchored by "bad effects of the two factors on the dependent variables still can
intentions"l"good intentions," and "intended to take advan- be examined.
These two analyses revealed that the experimental factors
tage of customers"/"did not intend to take advantage of cus-
were manipulated successfully. In addition, analysis of the
tomers" (r = .78, p < .0001). Next, participants indicated
(1) the store's net financial profit from the sale of the single price that participants believed the consumer paid f~r. the
doll relative to the normal profit and (2) the price paid for doll indicated no significant differences across conditions
the doll relative to the normal price. The perceived profit (F < 1). This verified that (1) the price was regarded as uni-
and price both were measured on seven-point scales labeled formly higher than normal, such that the reference price was
"a lot less than normal" (1), "about the same" (4), and "a lot violated, and (2) the experimental factors did not influence
more than normal" (7). Although the price paid was not the price that the consumer was perceived to have paid for
the doll, eliminating level of price violation as a possible
manipulated, measuring participants' perceptions of price
allowed for verification that the scenarios violated the refer- confounding factor (see Table 1 for means).
ence price, as expected. Dependent Variables
Covariates As predicted, analysis of the perceived fairness of the
Participants' ages, gender, number of children in family price increase revealed two significant main effects and no
(because the experimental product was a child's toy), and interaction (see Figure 3).4 Both the inferred relative profit
involvement with charity were collected as possible covari- made by the firm and the inferred motive of the firm
ates. Analyses indicated that none of these factors had any
3Altematively, helping a charity may he a subjectively "better" motive
2As discussed in the "Results and Discussion" section, the participants' than building an employee daycare center.
responses to the question of how much profit the firm makes from the sale 41t is important to note that the two main effects of the experimental fac-
supports the intended manipulation. Participants rated the firm as making tors are not the same as the main effect plus interaction found on the
more than normal profit in this condition. Relative profit was rated as sig- inferred motive manipulation check. Thus, the effects cannot be attributed
nificantly higher than in the two no additional profit conditions and the to just the inferred motive factor; both profit and motive are shown to have
same as in the base, higher profit condition. See Table I for the cell means. separate effects.
Perceptions of Price Unfairness 193

Table 1
STUDY 1: MEANS (STANDARD DEVIATIONS) OF DEPENDENT MEASURES

Profit
Motives
More than No More
Negative Positive Normal than Normal
Inferred motives 3.28 (1.6) 5.33 (1.4) 4.06 (1.7) 4.40(2.0)
Inferred relative profit 4.91 (1.9) 4.75 (1.9) 5.75 (1.5) 3.75 (1.8)
Price 6.43 (.78) 6.33 (.97) 6.33 (.89) 6.45 (.84)
Perceived unfairness 4.48 (2.3) 2.98 (1.9) 4.39 (2.2) 3.08 (2.0)
Shopping intentions 2.76 (1.6) 3.74(1.2) 2.85 (1.4) 3.63 (1.6)

Negative Motives Positive Motives


More Profit No More Profit More Profit No More Profit
Inferred relative profit 5.86 (1.6) 4.00(1.9) 5.66 (1.4) 3.37 (1..6)
Price 6.41 (.73) 6.45 (.83) 6.24 (1.0) 6.45 (.89)
Inferred motive 3.29 (1.5) 3.26 (1.7) 4.83 (1.5) 6.05(1.0)
Perceived unfairness 5.23 (2.2) 3.69 (2.1) 3.52 (1.9) 2.20(1.5)
Shopping intentions • 2.37 (1.5) 3.17 (1.6) 3.35 (1.1) 4.30 ( 1.2)
Note: All ratings were onseven-point bipolar scales: 7 = more profit, higher price, more positive motives, greater perceived unfairness (less fair), andmore
positive shopping intentions.

Figure 3 cated that they would be less likely to shop for toys at the
STUDY 1: MEANS OF PERCEIVED UNFAIRNESS BY retailer when profit was higher than normal (mean = 2.85)
EXPERIMENTAL CONDITION than when profit was normal (mean = 3.63; F(l,loz) = 10.81,
P < .001). Likewise, participants described themselves as
less likely to shop at the store when they had inferred nega-
6
tive motive to take advantage (mean =2.76) than when they
inferred a positive motive (mean = 3.74; F(l,lOZ) = 15.46, P
< .001).
This work suggests that relative profit and inferred
-+-Morc Profits motive influence perceived fairness, which in turn influ-
.........NoMore Profits ences shopping intentions. Thus, a mediation analysis was
conducted. As recommended by Baron and Kenny (1986), a
series of three regression equations was estimated to test the
mediation. First, the mediator, perceived unfairness, was
regressed on the independent variables, inferred relative
profit and inferred motive; this showed significant effects.
Second, the dependent variable, shopping intentions, was
regressed on the independent variables; this also showed
Negative Positive significant effects of inferred relative profit and inferred
motive. Third, the dependent variable of shopping intentions
was regressed on both the independent variables, inferred
affected perceived fairness. As suggested by the principle of relative profit and inferred motive, and on the mediator, per-
dual entitlement and predicted in HI' the pricing action was ceived unfairness (see Table 2 for regression coefficients).
perceived as more unfair when the firm was inferred to The third equation demonstrated that when perceived
make increased profit from the violation of the reference unfairness was included with the two experimental variables
price (mean = 4.39) and more fair when the firm was not in the regression analysis, perceived unfairness was highly
making increased profit (mean = 3.08; F(I,lOZ) = 13.50, p < significant (~motive = .30, p > .15; ~profit = .21, P > .30; ~unfair
.001). In support of Hz, the price was perceived as more = -.46, p < .001), but the initially highly significant predic-
unfair when the firm was inferred to have a negative motive tive ability of the experimental variables was eliminated.
(mean = 4.48) but more fair when inferences were that the Thus, the perceived unfairness of the pricing decision medi-
firm's motive was positive (mean = 2.98; F(I,lOZ) = 16.95, P ated the effects of inferred relative profit and inferred
< .001).5 Both HI and Hz were supported. motive on whether participants were likely to shop at the
Analysis of the shopping intentions measure revealed store.
main effects of relative profit and motive, with no signifi-
cant interaction between the two factors. Participants indi- Discussion
Study I extends existing research by demonstrating that
5The main effects of profit andinferred motive on perceived unfairness the motive attributed to the firm has an influence on per-
also were found to be significant when examined with nonparametric tests
(profit: Cochran-Mantel-Haenszel statistic = 15.4, P < .001; inferred ceived price fairness beyond that of the firm's violation of
motive: Cochran-Mantel-Haenszel statistic = 14.2, P < .001). reference profit. The data show that both the inferred rela-
194 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, MAY 1999

Table 2
STUDY 1: MEDIATION ANALYSIS-MODEL ESTIMATES

Perceived Unfairness Shopping Intentions Shopping Intentions


Variable Coefficient t-value p Coefficient t-value p Coefficient t-value p
Intercept 8.24 9.7 .0001 .42 .7 .48 4.20 7.0 .0001
Relative profit -1.44 -3.8 .001 .87 3.3 .001 .21 1.0 .32
Inferred motive -1.62 -4.2 .0001 1.05 3.9 .0001 .30 1.4 .16
Perceived unfairness -.46 -9.14 .0001

tive profit and the inferred motive are related causally to the Figure 4
perceived fairness of a price. STUDY 2: REPUTATION CONDITIONS
As discussed previously, one important implication of the
finding that inferred motive influences perceived fairness is Good Reputation
that factors that influence the motive consumers infer for a
Store X is a large retailer that has been established for many years and is
firm thereby will affect the perceived fairness of a price set highly regarded in the community. This retailer seems to treat both its
by the firm. The firm's prior reputation is expected to be one customers and its employees with respect. Employees feel that the store
such factor. As encapsulated in H3, reputation is expected to tries to be equitable in its interactions and negotiations. Consumers state
influence the extent to which inferred relative profit influ- that the store seems to have a philosophy of offering good service.
ences inferred motive. Thus, a second study was conducted Store X participates in a variety of community activities and recently began
to examine H 3 and provide insight to the influence of the supporting both a receipt-exchange program, in which they give a portion
firm's reputation on inferred motive. of saved receipts to buy computers for the local elementary school, and a
"day on the job" program for at-risk youths. This store seems to have a
STUDY 2 good reputation with its customers, employees, and the community at large.

Methodology Poor Reputation


Eighty-six students and staff at a major West Coast uni- Store X is a large retailer that has been established for many years but is not
versity volunteered for a study on pricing; participation was highly regarded in the community. This retailer does not seem to treat either
motivated by a $3.00 incentive. The participants, 41 women its customers or its employees with respect. Employees feel that the store
and 45 men with an average age of 24.1 years, were does not try to be equitable in its interactions and negotiations. Consumers
state that the store seems to have a philosophy of offering little service.
assigned randomly to the cells of a between-subject study.
Two levels of profit (more than normal, no more than nor- Store X does not typically participate in community activities and recently
mal) were crossed with two levels of reputation (good, declined to support both a receipt-exchange program, in which they would
give a portion of saved receipts to buy computers for the local elementary
poor). In all cases, the pricing scenario suggested negative school, and a "day on the job" program for at-risk youths. This store seems
motive. to have a bad reputation with its customers, employees, and the community
at large.
Stimuli
Participants first read through two paragraphs that pre-
sented the firm as having either a good or a poor reputation attenuates negative inferences of motive when there is some
within the community. A pretest was conducted in which 25 favorable information that the firm did not increase profit.
participants were assigned randomly to read one of two That is, when the firm has a good reputation and the infor-
descriptions of "Store X," intended to manipulate perceived mation suggests the possibility of negative intent to take
reputation. Evaluations on a reliable five-item scale advantage but the firm does not profit, does a prior good
(Cronbach's alpha = .95) showed a significant effect of the reputation limit inferences of negative intent, such that the
reputation manipulation on perceived reputation (F(I, 14) =
action is perceived as more fair?
83.4, p < .0001). The description of the firm presenting a
good reputation resulted in much more positive evaluations Measures
of the store's reputation (mean = 5.75, where 7 indicates a
good reputation) than the poor reputation description (mean After reading the reputation and pricing information, par-
= 2.06). The reputation descriptions were slightly modified, ticipants evaluated the perceived fairness of the pricing
and the revised descriptions were used in the main study decision on two items. Perceived fairness was rated on the
(see Figure 4). same bipolar adjective scale anchored by 1 = "very fair" and
Next, participants read either Scenario 1 or Scenario 3 7 = "very unfair" that was used in Study 1 and also using a
from Study 1 (see Figure 2).6 As found in Study I, both statement of "this price is not fair" for which 1 = strongly
these scenarios suggested negative motives for the firm's agree and 7 = strongly disagree. The second item was
pricing decision. However, the two scenarios differed in reverse scored, and the two were averaged for a reliable
that, in one, the firm made additional profit and in the other scale of perceived fairness (r = .84, p < .0001). After
the firm did not make additional profit. Thus, the two sce- responding to the questions of perceived fairness, partici-
narios allow for examination of whether a good reputation pants indicated on seven-point bipolar scales how likely
they would be to shop at the described store if shopping for
6The name of the doll was changed to "Sing 'N Snore Ernie," which is toys (I = "a lot less likely" and 7 = "a lot more likely") and
the name of a doll that was in short supply at the time of the study. whether they would bid on the doll if they were shopping at
Perceptions of Price Unfairness 195

the store at the time of the auction (1 = "definitely not" and Analysis of variance revealed a significant effect of the rep-
7 = "definitely would"). utation condition on the reliable (Cronbach's alpha = .95)
Participants then indicated their inferences about the measure of the firm's reputation (F(I, 82) =98.2, P < .0001)
store's motive on two seven-point, bipolar items anchored and no other significant effects. Participants perceived that
by "bad motives"/"good motives" and "antisocial"/"proso- the firm had a good reputation (mean = 4.9) in the good rep-
cial" (r = .64, p < .0001). Participants next completed seven- utation condition relative to the poor reputation condition
point scales evaluating (1) the relative profit made by the (mean =2.1). Finally, the price the consumer who purchased
store from the sale and (2) the price the consumer paid for the doll was believed to have paid also was analyzed; in all
the doll (both were answered on seven-point bipolar scales conditions, the price was perceived to be higher than normal
anchored by "a lot less than normal"/"a lot more than nor- (mean =6.3), and there were no effects of the experimental
mal"). These measures were followed by a five-item mea- factors on price paid (F(3,82) < 1, n.s.). Thus, the manipula-
sure of reputation composed of three bipolar adjective scales tions of inferred profit and reputation were successful, and
anchored by "bad"l"good," "negative"/"positive," and there were no unexpected effects on price.
"poor"l"excellent" and two statements on the store's reputa- Results of the analysis of the inferred motive measure are
tion with 1 = "strongly agree" and 7 = "strongly disagree." depicted graphically in Figure 5. The analysis revealed a
Items were reverse scored as appropriate, achieving a reli- significant main effect of the firm's reputation (F(I, 82) =
able scale of reputation (Cronbach's alpha = .95). These 21.9, P < .001) and a significant effect of inferred profit (F(I,
measures were followed by individual difference measures 82) = 4.9, P < .05). These main effects were qualified by a
of gender, age, and number of children. significant interaction between reputation and inferred profit
(F(I, 82) = 10.7, P < .001). In support of H3, simple effects
Results and Discussion analyses revealed that, whereas the inferred profit did not
The dependent variables were first analyzed with a 2 (rel- affect the inferred motive when the firm had a poor reputa-
ative profit) x 2 (reputation) ANCOVA including gender, tion (F(I,41) < 1), the profit did influence the inferred motive
number of children, and age. The covariates did not signifi- for a firm with a good reputation (F(l, 41) = 15.0, P < .001).
cantly affect any of the analyses and thus were dropped from Participants inferred a much more positive, prosocial motive
analysis. when the firm with a good prior reputation did not profit
The basic 2 x 2 ANOVA model was used to analyze all (mean =5.1) than when the firm did profit from the pricing
dependent variables. Means appear in Table 3. First, the action (mean = 3.4).
inferred relative profit made by the firm on the sale was ana- Analysis of perceived price unfairness revealed the same
lyzed to verify that inferred profit differed as intended. As pattern of effects as did inferred motive (though, as
expected, profit information had a significant impact on par- expected, the means were in the opposite direction). There
ticipants' profit ratings (F(I, 82) = 19.8, P < .0001). Partici- was a significant main effect of reputation (F(I,82) = 12.64,
pants believed that the firm made significantly more profit P < .001), a significant main effect of inferred profit (F(I,
in the additional profit condition (mean = 6.2) than in the no 82) = 5.2, p < .05), and a significant interaction effect (F(I,
additional profit condition (mean = 4.8). There were no 82) = 4.1, P < .05). Follow-up simple effects analyses
other significant effects. Thus, the experimental manipula- revealed that the main effects were qualified by the interac-
tion of inferred relative profit was effective. Next, partici- tion. The inferred relative profit did not significantly affect
pants' perceptions of the firm's reputation were analyzed to perceived price unfairness when the store had a poor repu-
confirm that prior reputation was manipulated successfully. tation (F < 1) but modified perceived unfairness when the

Table 3
STUDY 2: MEANS (STANDARD DEVIATIONS) OF DEPENDENT MEASURES

Reputation Profit
Good Poor More Profit No More Profit
Inferred relative profit 5.69(1.4) 5.41 (1.7) 6.21 (1.00) 4.84 (1.7)
Price 6.12 (1.5) 6.41 (.90) 6.30 (1.2) 6.20 (1.3)
Inferred motive 4.22(1.7) 2.83 (1.4) 3.23 (1.4) 3.81 (1.9)
Perceived unfairness 3.85(2.2) 5.24 (1.8) 4.97 (1.9) 4.1 (2.2)
Shopping intentions 3.98(1.8) 2.16 (1.2) 2.81 (1.5) 3.32 (1.9)
Intention to bid 3.26(2.2) 2.35 (1.5) 2.74 (1.8) 2.86 (2.0)

Good Reputation Poor Reputation


More Profit No More Profit More Profit No More Profit
Relative profit 6.35 (.90) 4.89 (1.4) 6.00 (1.1) 4.91 (1.9)
Price 6.13( 1.5) 6.11(1.5) 6.47 (.70) 6.36 (1.1)
Inferred motive 3.43 (1.6) 5.13(1.3) 3.00 (1.1) 2.67 (1.5)
Perceived unfairness 4.67(1.9) 2.90 (2.0) 5.30 (1.7) 5.20(1.9)
Shopping intentions 3.35(1.7) 4.70 (1.6) 2.20 (1.0) 2.13 (1.4)
Intention to bid 2.96(2.0) 3.60 (2.3) 2.50 (1.4) 2.22 (1.5)
Note: All ratings were on seven-point bipolar scales: 7 = more profit, higher price, more positive motives, greater perceived unfairness (less fair), more pos-
itive shopping intentions, and greater probability of bidding on the doll.
196 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, MAY 1999

Figure 5 motive and perceived unfairness. There was a significant


STUDY 2: MEANS OF RATINGS OF INFERRED MOTIVE BY effect of reputation (F(l, 82) = 35.4, P < .001), a main effect
EXPERIMENTAL CONDITION of inferred profit (F(l, 82) =4.2, p < .05), and an interaction
effect (F(l, 82) = 5.2, P < .05). Simple effects analyses
revealed that the relatively low likelihood of shopping at the
6 store with a poor reputation was not influenced by the
inferred profit (F < 1), whereas participants were more

/-------.
c:
~
5
likely to shop at the store with a good reputation when the
store gave away the profit after the angry customer com-
S plained (mean = 4.7) than they were when the store was
::s 4
-+-0000 Reputation
inferred to keep the profit (mean = 3.4; F(l, 42) = 9.4, p <
Q ___Poor Reputation
~ .01). Examination of the contrasts revealed a significant
~
~ main effect of reputation in addition to the interaction effect.
3
~ Even when the store kept the profit from the sale, partici-
~ pants were more likely to shop at a store with a good repu-
2 tation (mean = 3.4) than at a store with a poor reputation
More Profit No More (mean =2.2).
Profit The same analyses were conducted with the probability
PROFTI that the participants would bid on the doll as the dependent
variable. The patterns of results for this measure were quite
different from the preceding variables. The only significant
store had a good reputation (F(l, 42) =9.3, p < .01). When the effect on probability of bidding for the doll was a main
store had a good reputation, the store not profiting from the effect of reputation. Participants were more likely to bid on
pricing action but instead giving the profit to a charity the doll when the store had a good reputation (mean = 3.3)
decreased the perceived price unfairness, such that the price than when the store had a poor reputation (mean = 2.4; F(l,
was perceived as significantly less unfair (mean =2.9) rela- 82) =5.2, P < .05). However, participants indicated that they
tive to when the firm profited from the price change (mean = were never very likely to make a bid; in every condition, the
4.7, where 7 =unfair). average likelihood of bidding on the doll was lower than the
The analyses of inferred motive and perceived unfairness midpoint of the scale (see Table 3 for cell means). The dif-
are consistent with the hypothesis that reputation influences ference in the patterns of results for the two different mea-
inferred motive, which then influences perceived price sures of purchase intentions is interesting and might provide
unfairness. This mediation was tested specifically by the insight to limitations of consumers' willingness to take on
method recommended by Baron and Kenny (1986) and costs to "punish" unfair firms. In the case in which the con-
described in Study 1. Three regression analyses were con- sumer already has absorbed transportation costs and the
ducted to explore whether the inferred motive mediated the costs of not buying the doll from that particular store are
effect of the reputation and profit conditions on perceived high because of the doll's rarity, consumers' intentions to
unfairness (see Table 4). The first two regression equations purchase are not affected by perceived unfairness, whereas
showed the impact of the experimental variables, reputation, intentions for future shopping behavior are.
relative profit, and the interaction on inferred motives and To test the extent to which the effects of the experimental
perceived unfairness. In a third analysis, perceived unfair- variables on shopping intentions were mediated by per-
ness was regressed on the experimental variables as well as ceived unfairness, a mediation analysis was conducted, fol-
on the inferred motive scale. All the effects of the experi- lowing the method suggested by Baron and Kenny (1986)
mental variables were diminished, whereas the effect of and described previously. The first two regression analyses
inferred motive was highly significant. This shows that replicated the results of the ANOVAs; these equations
inferred motive mediates the effects of the experimental showed significant effects of reputation and the interaction
variables on perceptions of price fairness, providing support of reputation and profit in predicting (1) perceived unfair-
for the overall conceptualization of this work. ness (~Rep =-2.30, t = -4.0, p < .00I; ~Rep x Profit = 1.67, t =
Analysis of participants' likelihood of shopping at the 2.0, P < .05) and (2) shopping intentions (~Rep = 2.57, t =
retailer followed the same pattern revealed for inferred 5.8, p < .0001; ~Rep x Profit = -1.42, t =-2.3, P < .05). The

Table 4
STUDY 2: ANALYSIS OF INFERRED MOTIVE AS MEDIATOR OF EXPERIMENTAL FACTORS ON PERCEIVED UNFAIRNESS-MODEL
ESTIMATES

Inferred Motive Perceived Unfairness Perceived Unfairness


Variable Coefficient t-value p Coefficient t-value p Coefficient t-value p
Intercept 2.75 9.1 .0001 5.20 13.1 .0001 7.83 20.7 .0001
Reputation 2.28 5.1 .0001 -2.30 -4.0 .0001 .12 .26 .80
Relative profit .22 .5 .62 .10 .2 .86 .43 l.l .28
Reputation x profit -1.82 -2.9 .01 1.67 2.03 .05 -.32 -.54 .59
Inferred motive -.99 -9.9 .0001
Perceptions of Price Unfairness 197

third equation, in which likelihood of shopping was insight provided by the principle of dual entitlement and
regressed on perceived unfairness in addition to the experi- demonstrates that motive attributed to the firm modifies the
mental factors, showed that though perceived unfairness perceived unfairness of the price, regardless of whether the
was highly significant (p = -.56, t = -9.72, p < .0001), the pricing decision leads to increased profit for the firm.
interaction of reputation and profit was no longer significant Study 2 examined the effect of reputation on inferred
(p = -.49, t = -1.1, p < .27). These results indicate that the motive. As predicted, reputation interacted with inferred rel-
interaction effect was mediated by inferred motive. The rep- ative profit to influence inferred motive. Inferred motive
utation effect remained highly significant in this model (P = was not affected by inferred relative profit when the firm
1.29, t = 3.91, p < .00(1), though the coefficient was had a poor reputation but was more positive when the firm
smaller. This suggests that, not surprisingly, there was a did not profit and the firm had a good reputation, which sug-
direct effect of reputation on shopping intentions beyond the gests an important way in which a good reputation can be
effect mediated by perceived unfairness. beneficial to a firm. Consumers are more willing to give a
This study demonstrates that reputation and inferred rela- firm with a good prior reputation the benefit of the doubt
tive profit influence inferences of motive, thereby influenc- when making inferences about underlying motive.
ing perceived price fairness and intentions to patronize the
retailer. The significant interaction between reputation and Limitations and Further Research
relative profit is important in that it bolsters the contention As always, the use of experiments suggests some limita-
of this research that reputation moderates the impact of tions to the research. Although experiments enabled close,
inferred relative profit on inferred motive. When a firm has careful examination of the factors of interest, they also
a good reputation, a consumer is likely to give the firm the involved some artificiality. For example, the information on
benefit of the doubt. Even when the pricing scenario sug- firm reputation was provided to participants in a short, writ-
gests negative motive, if the firm does not appear to make ten format. In reality, a firm develops a reputation over time
additional profit, consumers infer a more positive motive. A through a variety of actions. Although the reputation infor-
firm with a poor reputation, however, does not receive this mation included several different types of information that
benefit; in this case, a consumer is just as likely to infer neg- are part of overall reputation (Herbig and Milewicz 1993),
ative motive when relative profit appears higher than when this short paragraph is likely to provide less information
the firm does not increase profit from the pricing action. than consumers often have about firms, and thus, the effects
These results show that inferred motive is a critical factor in of reputation may be underrepresented by this manipulation.
perceptions of price fairness. In contrast, participants read the reputation information
immediately prior to reading about the price increase, which
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS may have made the firm's reputation more salient than
Drawing on psychological and economic theories, this usual. Finally, the information on reputation may have been
research suggests that the inferred motive of the firm in set- more consistent than is common. For example, in the case of
ting a price is a factor in consumers' perceptions of price the poor reputation, all information was fairly negative,
unfairness. Two studies provide empirical support for the whereas in many real world cases, there is a combination of
proposed concept that when a consumer infers that the firm negative, neutral, and positive information about a firm.
has a negative motive to take advantage of consumers, a Thus, care must be taken in generalizing these results to
pricing decision is perceived as unfair, compared with when everyday situations.
the consumer does not attribute such a motive to the firm. Another shortcoming of this work may be that the situa-
This research shows that inferred motive for the price tion in both studies involved an auction of an extremely lim-
increase is a factor in perceived price fairness, in addition to ited product. The desirable holiday doll scenarios are such
the relative profit presumed to be made by the firm as a that there is significantly greater demand for than supply of
result of the increase. This research bolsters the argument the product at the posted price, and consumers face a tight
for the importance of the influence of inferred motive on time constraint. Although there is always scarcity involved
perceived price fairness by demonstrating that firm reputa- with products, it is not always the case that there is a tem-
tion affects perceptions of price fairness by moderating porary shortage of a product that is highlighted to the same
inferences of motive. Finally, this also provides empirical extent as in these scenarios. It would be useful to explore the
support for the finding that consumers are less likely to con- extent to which consumers make inferences about firms'
duct business with a firm that is perceived to have estab- motives in situations in which a firm increases a price for a
lished unfair prices, by demonstrating that consumers' atti- product that is not in immediate short supply. One possibil-
tudes and behavioral intentions toward the firm are lower ity is that consumers are less likely to take motive into con-
when the firm has set a price that is perceived as unfair. sideration in such situations because they may assume that
Taken together, the results of these two studies provide the firm would not have raised the price unless the increase
strong evidence for the overall model presented in Figure 1. was supported by market forces.
Study I manipulated the inferred motive and relative Similarly, additional research should explore the extent to
profit attributed to a firm in pricing a doll in the preholiday which the results found here extend beyond auctions. One
season. The results support the conceptual development, interesting question is how consumers would respond if a
showing that inferred motive to take advantage of con- firm increased overall prices to support a charity. This
sumers contributed significantly to perceptions of unfair- research suggests that, because of the positive motive, con-
ness. This study extended previous work by showing that sumers would perceive this as fair. However, it is possible
both inferred motive and inferred relative profit signifi- that, even if the price decision were perceived as fair, some
cantly affect perceptions of unfairness. This adds to the consumers would choose to conduct business elsewhere. It
198 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, MAY 1999

would be useful to gain further understanding of consumers' pricing. A benefit of going beyond the principle of dual enti-
inferences about pricing and other market actions, as well as tlement and identifying inferred motive as a component of
factors that moderate the relation between fairness and atti- perceived fairness is that inferred motive may influence
tudes and intentions. consumers' perceptions of fairness for marketplace actions
In Study 1, inferred motive was unexpectedly affected by that are not linked clearly to reference profit. For example,
inferred profit. Although the effect was limited to one con- imagine that a consumer sees an advertisement for a piece of
dition, this effect indicates that the construct of inferred stereo equipment at a good price. However, when she visits
motive and the relation between inferred motive and profit the advertising retailer, she is told that the store does not
are in need of further development. The results of both have that equipment after all, but that they have a higher
Study I and Study 2 suggest that profit can affect inferred priced piece available. If the consumer infers that the store
motive in some conditions; in both studies, inferred profit management ran the advertisement with the negative motive
appeared to be used sometimes by participants to provide of taking advantage of consumers by getting them into the
insight to the firm's underlying motive. Further research store under false pretenses (i.e., "bait and switch"), she is
should explore the antecedents of inferred motive and the likely to perceive the advertisement as unfair. However, if
role of inferred profit in greater detail. the consumer infers that the store management ran the
Finally, the studies presented here examine only one type advertisement because they believed that they were going to
of product and one type of pricing situation. It is probable get a large shipment of the stereo equipment but then did
that several unexplored variables likewise affect perceived not, she may be more likely to perceive the same advertise-
price fairness. For example, though the doll in the scenarios ment as fair. It remains for additional research to develop
is a nonessential product, it is one that consumers from a further how inferred motive affects perceived unfairness for
variety of walks of life purchase, and the situation is one nonprice marketplace actions.
with which many consumers can sympathize. It would be
interesting to explore whether the process by which percep- REFERENCES
tions of unfairness arise is different when the product under Baron, Reuben M. and David A. Kenny (1986), "The Modera-
consideration is a "true" luxury good, such as a yacht or an tor-Mediator Variable Distinction in Social Psychological
expensive automobile. Another possibility is that there are Research: Conceptual, Strategic and Statistical Considerations,"
individual difference variables that affect perceptions of Journal of Personality and Social Psychology; 51 (6), 1173-82.
fairness and/or motive. Some consumers may believe that Betancourt, Hector and Irene Blair (1992), "A Cognition (Attribu-
fairness is not applicable to auctions in particular, or the tion)-Emotion Model of Violence in Conflict Situations," Per-
marketplace in general, whereas others may believe that sonality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 18 (June), 343-50.
fairness is relevant and important and, therefore, be more Bies, R.I. (1986), "Identifying Principles of Interactional Justice:
likely to consider fairness and motive. The Case of Corporate Recruiting," in Moving Beyond Equity
Theory: New Directions on Organizational Justice, R.I. Bies,
Conclusions chair. Symposium presented at the meeting of the Academy of
Management, Chicago.
Both the studies previously discussed show that what - - - (1987), "The Predicament of Injustice: The Management
consumers learn about firms and what firms say about their of Moral Outrage," in Research in Organizational Behavior,
motives influence perceptions of unfairness. These findings Vol. 9, L.L. Cummings and B.M.Staw, eds. Greenwich, CT:JAI
thus have important implications for the ways in which Press, 289-319.
firms manage their marketing communications, as well as - - - and DL Shapiro (1987), "International Fairness Judg-
their prices. These results indicate that marketing communi- ments: The Influence of Causal Accounts," Social Justice
cations can be used to manage consumers' inferences of Research, 1, 199-218.
motive and, thus, their perceptions of fairness or unfairness, - - - and - - - (1988), "Voice and Justification: Their Influ-
particularly by a reputable firm. For example, firms should ence on Procedural Fairness and Judgments," Academy of Man-
consider using marketing communications, such as adver- agement Journal, 31 (3),676-85.
tisements or point-of-purchase materials, to provide justifi- Brockner, J. and JeraldGreenberg (1989), "The Impact of Layoffs
cations for price increases. Pricing decisions should be on Survivors: An Organizational Justice Perspective," in
Advances in Applied Social Psychology: Business Settings, J.
made with consideration given to the need to communicate Carroll,ed. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, 45-75.
the price and the reasons behind it. This research points to Campbell, Margaret, C. (1995), "When Attention-Getting Adver-
the wisdom of integrating pricing and communications tising Tactics Elicit Consumer Inferences of Manipulative
decisions. Intent: The Importance of Balancing Benefits and Investments,"
The notion that people look behind the price to the firm's Journal of Consumer Psychology; 4 (3), 225-54.
motive fits well with a current stream of research in con- Dickson, Peter R. and Rosemary Kalapurakal (1994), "The Use
sumer behavior. Recent work suggests that a consumer's and Perceived Fairness of Price-Setting Rules in the Bulk Elec-
response to marketing can be influenced by inferences about tricity Market," Journal of Economic Psychology, 15 (3),
the marketer's motive for taking a particular action (Camp- 427-48.
bell 1995; Friestad and Wright 1994; Kirmani 1990; Kir- Dodge, Kenneth A. andJohnD. Coie (1987), "Social-Information-
mani and Wright 1989). The finding that consumers respond Processing Factors in Reactive and Proactive Aggression in
Children'sPeerGroups," Journal ofPersonality and Social Psy-
to inferred motives in evaluating fairness provides another chology, 53 (6), 1146-58.
example that consumers sometimes construe the reasons for Etzioni, Amitai (1988), The Moral Dimension: Toward a New Eco-
a marketer's actions and that these interpretations can influ- nomics. New York: The Free Press.
ence consumers' responses to marketplace behavior. Fincham, Frank D. and Joseph M. Jaspers (1980), "Attribution of
The research presented here may provide insight to per- Responsibility: From Man the Scientist to Man as Lawyer,"
ceptions of unfairness for marketplace actions other than Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 13, 81-138.
Perceptions of Price Unfairness 199

Folkes, Valerie S. (1988), "Recent Attribution Research in Con- ics, John J. Kagel and Alvin E. Roth, eds. Princeton, NJ: Prince-
sumer Behavior: A Review and New Directions," Journal of ton University Press, 349-443.
Consumer Research, 14 (March), 548-65. Kachelmeier, Steven 1., Stephen T. Limberg, and Michael S.
- - , Susan Koletsky, and John Graham (1987), "A Field Study Schadewald (1991), "A Laboratory Market Examination of the
of Causal Inferences and Consumer Reaction: The View from Consumer Price Response to Information About Producers'
the Airport," Journal of Consumer Research, 13 (March), Costs and Profits," The Accounting Review, 66 (October),
534-39. 694-717.
Franciosi, Robert, Praveen Kugal, Roland Michelitsch, Vernon Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard Thaler (l986a),
Smith, and Gang Deng (1995), "Fairness: Effect on Temporary "Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the
and Equilibrium Prices in Posted-Offer Markets," The Economic Market," The American Economic Review, 76 (4), 728-41.
Journal, 105 (July), 938-50. - - - , - - - , and - - - (I 986b ), "Fairness and the Assump-
Friestad, Marian and Peter Wright (1994), ''The Persuasion Knowl- tions of Economics," Journal of Business, 59 (4), S285-300.
edge Model: How People Cope with Persuasion Attempts," Kalapurakal, Rosemary, Peter Dickson, and Joel Urbany (1990),
Journal of Consumer Research, 21 (June), 1-31. "Perceived Price Fairness and Dual Entitlement," in Advances in
Goldberg, Marvin E. and Jon Hartwick (1990), ''The Effects of Consumer Research, Vol. 18, Rebecca Holman and Michael
Advertiser Reputation and Extremity of Advertising Claim on Solomon, eds. Provo, UT: Association for Consumer Research,
Advertising Effectiveness," Journal of Consumer Research, 17 788-93.
(September), 172-79. Kamen, J. and R. Toman (1970), "Psychophysics of Prices," Jour-
Goldman, Abigail (1994), "Activists Visit Four Suspected Price nal of Marketing Research, 7 (February), 27-35.
Gougers," Los Angeles Times, (January 30), 6. Kaufmann, Patrick J., Gwen Ortmeyer, and N. Craig Smith (1991),
Graham, Sandra, Cynthia Hudley, and Estella Williams (1992), "Fairness in Consumer Pricing," Journal of Consumer Policy,
"Attributional and Emotional Determinants of Agression Among 14, 117-40.
African-American and Latino Young Adolescents," Develop- Kidd, R.F., and M.K. Utne (1978), "Reactions to Inequity: A
mental Psychology, 28 (4), 731-40. Prospective on the Role of Attributions," Law and Human
Greenberg, Jerald (1988), "Using Social Accounts to Manage Behavior, 2 (4), 301-12.
Impressions of Performance Appraisal Fairness," in Communi- Kirmani, Amna (1990), ''The Effect of Perceived Advertising
cating Fairness in Organizations, 1. Greenberg and R.J. Bies, Costs on Brand Perceptions," Journal ofConsumer Research, 17
cochairs. Symposium presented at the Academy of Manage- (September), 160-71.
ment, Anaheim, CA. - - - and Peter Wright (1989), "Money Talks: Perceived Adver-
- - - (1990), "Looking Fair vs. Being Fair: Managing Impres- tising Expense and Expected Product Quality," Journal of Con-
sions of Organizational Justice," in Research in Organizational sumer Research, 16 (December), 344-53.
Behavior, Barry M. Staw and L.L. Cummings, eds. Greenwich, Martins, Marielza and Kent B. Monroe (1994), "Perceived Price
CT: JAI Press, 111-57. Fairness: A New Look at an Old Construct," in Advances in
- - - and Suzyn Ornstein (1983), "High Status Job Title as Com- Consumer Research, Vol. 21, Chris T. Allen and Deborah Roed-
pensation for Underpayment: A Test of Equity Theory," Journal der John, eds. Provo, UT: Association for Consumer Research,
ofApplied Psychology, 68 (2), 285-97. 75-78.
Greenberg, M. and David Frisch (1972), "Effect of Intentionality Monroe, Kent B. (1973), "Buyers' Subjective Perceptions of
on Willingness to Reciprocate a Favor," Journal of Experimen- Price," Journal of Marketing Research, 10 (February), 70-80.
tal Social Psychology, 8 (2), 99-111. Shapiro, Carl (1982), "Consumer Information, Product Quality, and
Grover, Ronald (1994), "$10 for Water! What's the Catch?" Busi- Seller Reputation," Bell Journal ofEconomics, 13 (I), 20-35.
ness Week, (February 7), 6. Urbany, Joel E., Thomas J. Madden, and Peter R. Dickson (1989),
Herbig, Paul and John Milewicz (1993), "The Relationship of Rep- "All's Not Fair in Pricing: An Initial Look at the Dual Entitle-
utation and Credibility to Brand Success," Journal of Consumer ment Principle," Marketing Letters, I (I), 17-25.
Marketing, 10 (3), 18-24. Weiner, Bernard (1985), "Spontaneous Causal Thinking," Psycho-
- - - , - - - , and Jim Golden (1994), "A Model of Reputation logical Bulletin, 97 (January), 74-84.
Building and Destruction," Journal of Business Research, 31 - - - (1992), Human Motivation: Metaphors, Theories, and
(1),23-31. Research. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.
Holt, Charles A. (1995) "Industrial Organization: A Survey of Lab- - - - (1995), Judgments of Responsibility: A Foundation for a
oratory Research," in The Handbook of Experimental Econom- Theory of Social Conduct. New York: Guilford Press.

You might also like