You are on page 1of 12

Vol.

3, No 2, 2015
ISSN 2303-5005

SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL


AND GAS PRODUCING COUNTRY’S ECONOMY

Viacheslav Alexandrovich Perepelkin; Elena Viacheslavovna Perepelkina


Samara State University of Economics, Russia

DOI 1515/eoik-2015-0017, UDK 339.923:656.2(497) Original scientific paper

ABSTRACT The model of structural development, under


which the impact of material component of eco-
In this paper, we consider identifying features nomic growth is consistently reducing, is based
of sectoral structuring within the national econ- on the economy’s division into primary, second-
omy that has definite foreign trade product spe- ary and tertiary sectors (P-S-T model) proposed
cialization. Examination of the sector-specific by Fisсher (1939;1952), Fourastie (1949), Clark
division methodology enabled identification of (1940) and Wolfe (1955). Playing a major role
its strong association with certain sector dom- in explanation of empirically observed shift
inance in the economy. It is against this back- to post-industrial society (Dietrich & Krüger,
ground that we offer an explanation for the delay 2010), this three-sectoral model differs from
in transferring from the post-Soviet to the appli- dividing the economy into agriculture, indus-
cable international classification of economic try and services developed by Kuznets (1971)
structure elements in Russia and Belarus. We (A-I-S model) – primarily by separation of sub-
perform analysis of the three-component P-S-T soil assets extraction from industry and includ-
model (primary, secondary, tertiary sector) us- ing it into the primary sector. Commitment of
ing statistical and econometric methods and de- some Eastern European statistical agencies to S.
fine properties of the sectoral shares dynamics Kuznets model – still existing a few years ago
in national economies of oil and gas producing – was determined to a high extent by the wish
countries. Analysis of the Russian and Norwe- to present economies of those countries less re-
gian economies’ intersectoral changes suggests source based and more industrial.
that it is necessary for the government to devel- Chenery and Taylor (1968) in their sector
op and implement selective structural policy to growth analysis function relate mining to the
overcome the existing structural disproportions. primary sector. They explained the possibility of
typologization of the economy’s structural trans-
Keywords: sector, intersectoral shift, minerals formation process for different groups of coun-
extraction, deindustrialization, tertiarization. tries by universal and specific factors influence.
Indicators of raw materials extraction and export
INTRODUCTION along with characteristics of production condi-
tions, aggregate demand, and investment activ-
Driven by traditional resources scarcity, re- ity belong to the indicators of universal factors
placement of material production factors by hu- influence in Chenery’s hypothesis.
man capital and consumption shift to non-materi-
Pasinetti (1981; 1993) considered learning by
al goods, global structural transformation requires
doing – which takes place through observation,
from developed national economies achievement
experimentation, action, mutual knowledge ex-
of new economic growth quality corresponding
change as well as learning new behavior patterns
to the post-industrial society. It may be that one
– as the major reason for growth and change in the
of the obstacles to that is the natural resources ex-
economy structure (Arrow, 1962; Romer, 1986;
ploitation-oriented sector, if it causes an outflow
of significant economic resources volume from
Young, 1993). New sectors appearance and old
other sectors due to its financial attractiveness and sectors disappearance in his theory is caused by
high capital intensiveness. innovations − production innovations in particu-

© Oikos institut Bijeljina 7


V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

lar that are supported by change of consumption in shifting from the first to the second one by de-
structure due to real incomes growth stimulated velopment of classificators of structural elements
by technological innovations. Over time, techno- in economies of Russia and Belarus. Section 3
logical innovations transfer to different sectors and ‘Analysis of consequences of introduction of clas-
branches, whereas production innovations stay sificators of economic activity types in Russia and
where they originated. Transiting from positive to Belarus’ discusses consequences of introducing
normative analysis, Pasinetti paid attention to the Russian and Belorussian types of economic ac-
problem of structural shifts combination and equi- tivity classificators. Section 4 ‘Changes in sectoral
librium establishment. From the perspective of the structure of the Russian and Norwegian econo-
economy theory development, it is important that mies in the 2000s’ evaluates changes occurred
the constantly occurring structural changes may in Russia in the 2000s on the basis of its sectoral
not be construed as an obstacle to harmonious pro- structure data, then follows a correlation with the
cess of growth and adjustment to equilibrium. Norwegian economy analogous data. In section 5
Explanation concerning deviations from the ‘Econometric model of intersectoral shifts in the
post-industrial trend of tertiarization sectoral economies of Russia and Norway’, we present
development is often given in terms of Tadeush econometric model of sectoral shifts in the econ-
M. Rybczynski’s theorem (Rybczynski, 1955), omies under consideration and interpret its results.
according to which there is a direct interrelation
between the production factors growth in some MODELS OF DIVISION OF ECONOMY
parts of economy and depression and even reces- INTO SECTORS AND THEIR USAGE IN
sion in others – due to limited resources. The case CLASSIFICATORS OF STRUCTURAL
when positive results from production expansion
ELEMENTS OF ECONOMY
and increase in export in one sector or branch are
less significant than negative consequences for
First versions of ISIC and NACE introduced in
the economy itself (in particular, deindustriali-
1960-1970s were generally in line with the sec-
zation begins) was termed immiserizing growth
toral division of the economy into agriculture, in-
(Bhagwati, 1958). Description of partial dein-
dustry and services formulated by Kuznets (1971).
dustrialization of the Netherlands economy with
At the same time, the problem of noncontradictory
the increase in natural gas extraction was made
description of economy’s sectoral structuring cri-
in 1981 by Ellman (1981) as well as other au-
teria emerged. The necessity of solving this prob-
thors and was later referred to in the literature as
lem is still noted: ‘The division into components
‘Dutch Disease’ (Dülger, Lopcu, Burgaç & Balli,
must have an analytical basis; ‘sectors’ must differ
2013; Cherif, 2013). The goal of Resource Curse
significantly from each other. With new technolo-
elimination remains crucial for a wide range of
gies much of what used to be ‘services’ is becom-
countries and scientists (Cheng, Sachs, & Yang,
ing part of what used to be ‘manufacturing’, and
2004; Bjorvatn, Farzanegan & Schneider, 2012)
much of employment growth in services reflects
actively discussing the related challenges. The
contracting out (outsourcing) of work previously
central problem of conducted research is sub-
done by manufacturing’ (Syrquin, 2010). Una-
stantiation of necessity of governmental selective
vailability of accurate differentiation between the
structural policy directed at overcoming depend-
sector based on natural resources exploitation and
ence on raw materials export for countries with
the sector of raw materials processing manifested
different levels of socioeconomic development.
itself firstly in attributing the whole output of min-
This paper consists of the following parts. Sec- erals to industry, which was justified by absence
tion 2 ‘Models of division of economy into sec- of seasonality in operation of mining enterprises
tors and their usage in classificators of structural as well as their similarity to industrial enterprises
elements of economy’ briefly describes models of concerning organization of manufacturing.
economy structuring in the industrial and post-in-
Expansion of the industry sphere by breaking
dustrial society as well as explains reasons of delay
down the national economy into sectors in accord-

8
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

ance with the A-I-S (agriculture-industry-services) so-called ‘primary industry’. Major channels of
model slightly improves the inter- and intrasec- such transfers’ receipt in Russia are energy pric-
toral picture of underdeveloped and developing es (being significantly lower vs. world prices),
countries. This model of sectoral structure looks non-market trade barter agreements, price-freeze
particularly appealing to governments of coun- agreements, and agreements on mutual direct
tries that are rich in fossil fuels and exploit them deliveries at underestimated prices.
actively. The classification of branches system by Introduced in January 2008, All-Russian Clas-
subject of their activity (OKONH) – introduced sifier of Types of Economic Activity (ОКVED)
by the USSR Gosstandart (State Committee for (Rosstat, 2012) and in January 2011 All-State
Standardization) in November 1975 – was not Classification of Economic Activity (ОКED)
accidentally similar to the A-I-S model. After the (Belstat, 2012) should serve – along with the state
USSR disintegration, it was applied without any statistical observation of economic processes de-
major modifications to statistical systems of al- velopment – the purpose of preparing statistical
most all the CIS (Commonwealth of Independent facts and figures for comparisons at the interna-
States) countries, in Russia and Belarus – under the tional level. Therefore, these classificators were
same abbreviation. In accordance with OKONH developed ‘on the basis of bringing to conform-
methodology, economy was divided into (i) ma- ity with the official Russian version of NACE
terial production sphere, where national product Rev. 1.1 (Rosstat, 2012) by including the last into
(production of goods and services of industrial ОКVED 2007 and ОКED. Since 2008 howev-
use) was created, and (ii) non-production sphere, er, statistical agencies of the EU countries passed
which, as it was supposed, created neither national to NACE Rev. 2 (Eurostat, 2013). It prevented
product nor national income. The non-production Russian and Belorussian classificators from
sphere incorporated other branches of the service achieving desired identity with the European
sector. Natural resources extraction was included classification. Furthermore, ОКVED and ОКED
into industry. For instance, processing and extrac- reflect features of Russian and Belorussian econ-
tion of ore were parts of the ferrous and non-fer- omies by using lower levels groupings absent in
rous metallurgy. the European classification (Table 1): in ОКVED
Because of using a broad definition of the these are five-unit codes subgroups making up
industrial sphere branches composition, statis- the fifth level as well as making up the sixth level
tical agencies and state administration bodies and having six-unit codes types; in ОКED these
had to deal with a huge heterogeneous aggre- are subclasses representing the fifth level and be-
gate called ‘industry’. It was difficult to control, ing numerated by five-unit codes. Though num-
though simple to conceal insufficient effective- bers of subgroups in OKVED and subclasses in
ness and competitiveness of processing indus- OKED at the fifth level are equal, the structure of
tries with explicit and implicit transfers from the their distribution by economy sectors is different.
Table 1
Distribution of number of subclasses in ОКED, subgroups and types in ОКVED by economic sectors

Classificator,
fifth level groupings
Sector ОКED ОКVED
subclass subgroup type
Primary 48 55 38
Secondary 396 334 113
Tertiary 324 379 241
Total number 768 768 392

Source: Belstat (2012); Rosstat (2012)

9
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

Differences in distribution by sectors of the the general direction of structural economic de-
same level subgroups in ОКVED and subclass- velopment in the future.
es in ОКED are apparently linked to dissimilar
sectoral structures of the Russian and Belorus- ANALYSIS OF CONSEQUENCES OF
sian economies. Leading role of minerals extrac- INTRODUCTION OF CLASSIFICATORS OF
tion in the Russian economy predetermined the ECONOMIC ACTIVITY TYPES IN
fact that the number of subgroups exceeds the
RUSSIA AND BELARUS
number of subclasses by 7 in the primary sector.
Greater share of processing industries in the GDP Transition from OKONH (pursuant to which
and employment structure of the Belorussian an enterprise is the target of branch affiliation
economy resulted in the number of subclasses definition and the object of administration) to
exceeding the number of subgroups by 62 in the ОКVED (based on standards adopted from the
secondary sector. In the tertiary sector, the num- developed market system) implies changes
ber of subclasses is by 55 less than the number of in the state economy regulation: influencing
subgroups, which is an evidence of retardation of conditions of performing a certain economic
the Belorussian economy in progress on the ter- activity type ministry or office is entitled to
tiarization path. apply a regulatory function with regard to the
The abovementioned differences in distributing whole range of enterprises carrying out this
statistical positions number by economic sectors activity (not to each of these enterprises sepa-
in Russia and Belarus reflect an unusual situation, rately though). An example of Belarus, where
in which a country with much smaller economy substitution of OKONH for ОКED occurred
uses more profound detalization of statistical data with considerable delay compared to Russia,
within such a big sector as the secondary one. gives evidence of difficulty in truly successful
This feature of statistical methodology applicable problem solution in respect of statistics reform
in Belarus can be considered as a consequence of under conditions, when even official data sug-
the As-Is State of the economy’s sectoral struc- gest that the private enterprises share does not
ture and the country’s government perception of exceed 40%.

Table 2
Average annual structure of GDP and gross value added by sectors of the Russian economy over
2002–2004, %

In accordance with structure of In accordance with structure of types of economic activity by


economy sectors by OKONH ОКVED
A-I-S model P-S-T model
Average annual
Sector share of sector Average annual Average annual
in GDP Sector share of sector in Sector share of sector in
gross value added gross value added
Agriculture 5.38 Agrarian 6.55 Primary 14.26
Manufacturing,
construction and
35.31 Industrial 34.81 Secondary 27.10
other production
output
Services production 59.31 Service 58.64 Tertiary 58.64

Source: Rosstat (2013; 2014),

The relative service sector value in Table differs from the sectoral structure of gross
2 is everywhere almost the same and equals value added calculated in accordance with
approximately 59%. The GDP sectoral struc- ОКVED and the A-I-S model: relative share
ture definition based on OKONH slightly of agriculture is by 1.17% less than the agrari-

10
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

an one; the share of manufacturing, construc- omy structure calculated in accordance with
tion and other production output is by 0.5% the P-S-T model, remaining as service-inten-
bigger than the industrial sector share; the sive as previously, is more reliant on natural
services production share exceeds the service resources exploitation, but less overburdened
sector share by 0.67%. Greater differences with their processing.
are observed in the P-S-T model concern-
ing the first two sectors’ relative shares: the CHANGES IN SECTORAL STRUCTURE
primary sector share is 2.18 times bigger vs. OF THE RUSSIAN AND NORWEGIAN
the agrarian sector and 2.65 times vs. agri- ECONOMIES IN THE 2000s
culture; the secondary sector share appeared
to be by 7.71% smaller than the industrial Strong structure-forming impact of minerals
sector share and by 8.21% smaller than the extraction on the Russian economy by usage of
share of manufacturing, construction and sectoral division as to the P-S-T model consists
other production output. The Russian econ- in growth of the primary sector relative value.

Table 3
Sectoral structure of gross value added in Russia in the 21st century, %

Sector 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
P 13,05 13,68 12,95 12,88 15,12 16,11 15,44 14,46 13,74 13,21 13,46 15,08 14,93 14,39 14,49
S 28,3 26,79 26,19 25,95 26,83 26,93 26,31 26,38 26,78 25,11 25,1 26,72 25,98 25,59 25,5
T 58,65 59,53 60,86 61,17 58,05 56,96 58,25 59,16 59,48 61,68 61,44 58,2 59,09 60,02 60,01

Source: Rosstat (2005; 2015)

Strong structure-forming impact of min- covery did not affect the Russian economy
erals extraction on the Russian economy structural transformation: in 2008-2014, the
by usage of sectoral division as to the primary sector share increased by 0.75%; the
P-S-T model consists in growth of the pri- secondary sector share decreased by 1.28%;
mary sector relative value. In contrast to the tertiary sector share growth was 0.53%.
the picture of structural shifts described in During the whole period from 2000 to 2014,
the three sectors concept – where the pri- it was observed an expansion of the primary
mary sector is reduced to the utmost, the sector by 1.44%, while tertiary sector share
secondary sector displays the least reduc- grew by 1.36% and secondary sector share
tion, while the tertiary sector grows – in the decreased by 2.8%. Thus, expansion of the
Russian economy in 2002-2007 the prima- economic activity types associated with
ry sector share grew by 1.41%, the tertiary mining minerals remains the major driving
sector share – by 0.51%, while the sec- force of sectoral shifts in the XXI c. Russian
ondary sector share decreased by 1.92%. economy determining its basic structural
Therefore, in years of comparatively fast characteristics in statics and dynamics. In the
economic growth a danger of deindustri- light of the above, in 2000-2014 the econo-
alization of Russian economy did not arise my sectors’ average shares were as follows:
from the service sector, as many believed. the primary sector – 14.2%, the secondary
It was caused by the primary sector expan- sector – 26.3%, the tertiary sector – 59.5%.
sion in its part associated with fossil fuels Graph 1-3 show that secondary sector
extraction. share tended to decline unlike primary and
In this respect, the economic crisis in tertiary sector shares demonstrating a weak
2008-2009 and the following period of re- growth tendency.

11
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

17

16

15

14
y=0,073x+13,61
13

12

11
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

P Linear (P)
Graph 1. Trend of the Russian economy primary sector share

29
28,5
28
27,5
27
26,5
26
y=-0,118x+27,24
25,5
25
24,5
24
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

S Linear (S)
Graph 2. Trend of the Russian economy secondary sector share

62

61

60 y=0,044x+59,14

59

58

57

56
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

T Linear (T)
Graph 3. Trend of the Russian economy tertiary sector share

12
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

Table 4
Sectoral structure of gross value added in Norway in the 21st century, %

Sector 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
P 26,83 24,05 20,61 26,61 22,94 26,61 28,32 25,32 28,99 21,08 22,95 24,02 25,08 23,57 21,87
S 15,78 17,3 17,84 16,26 16,65 16,26 17,06 17,32 16,95 16,05 15,98 15,65 15,17 15,39 15,59
T 57,39 58,65 61,55 57,13 60,41 57,13 54,62 57,36 54,06 62,87 61,07 60,33 59,75 61,04 62,54

Source: Statistics Norway (2005; 2009; 2011; 2013; 2014)

The process of the Norwegian economy sec- ed that share in the Russian economy showing
toral structure change over the reviewed period stronger dependence on natural resources ex-
occurred intensively (Table 4). Over 14 years, ploitation. Like the Russian tertiary sector, the
only the tertiary sector share in gross value Norwegian one had the greatest relative share
added of the country increased by 5.15% (3.8 in the economy (mean value – 59.06%, or by
times much than increase in the Russian econo- 0,44% less than the Russian one), and its fluctu-
my). At the same time, the primary sector share ations were stronger. The primary sector share
decreased by 4.96% and the secondary – by mean value was 24.59%, which by 10.39% ex-
0.19%. Furthermore, the primary sector share ceeded the Russian one. The secondary sector
in the Norwegian economy 1.5 times exceed- mean share equaled 16.35% (by 9.95% less).
31

29

27

25

23 y=-0,128x+25,61

21

19

17
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
P Linear (P)

Graph 4. Trend of the Norwegian economy primary sector share

18

17,5

17

16,5

16 y=-0,111x+17,23

15,5

15
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
S Linear (S)

Graph 5. Trend of the Norwegian economy secondary sector share

13
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

64

62

60 y=0,239x+57,14

58

56

54

52
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
T Linear (T)
Graph 6. Trend of the Norwegian economy tertiary sector share

Graph 4-6 suggest that the secondary and on international markets services are created
tertiary sectors of the Russian and Norwegian in tertiary sector. Consequently, the services
economies have the same dynamics of their prices are mainly determined by the domes-
shares although deviations from the average tic market situation, where excessive demand
in the Norwegian economy were more explic- for them derives from the oil and gas incomes
it than in the Russian one. increase. In this respect, it is logical to expect
Introduction of measures applicable in the partial moving of resources from the primary
institutional and economic policy just slightly and secondary sectors (where mainly tradable
affected the negative intersectoral develop- goods are produced) into the tertiary sector
ments in the Scandinavian country’ economy, producing goods with high income-related
demonstrating in this respect worse parame- demand elasticity.
ters of structural transformation comparing Special procedures of managing state in-
to Russia – both in dynamics and in statics. come from oil export in Russia and Norway
An example of an oil and gas producing are adjusting the intersectoral shifts process.
OECD-member country developed market Artificial reduction of aggregate demand by
economy allows suggesting that without de- ‘sterilization’ of excessive export revenue
velopment and implementation of govern- in stabilization funds is considered a proven
mental selective structural policy possible fu- method of preventing inflation and national
ture liberal economic reforms in Russia might economy’s dependence on conjuncture fluc-
not liberate the country from dominance of tuations in the international raw material mar-
interests of faction in power associated with kets. However, domestic investment and state
hydrocarbon raw materials exploitation. expenditures limitation in case of non-mon-
The described sectoral growth asymmetry is etary inflation nature may be ineffective and
evident from nonoptimal resource allocation cause stagnation in the secondary and ter-
as well as from income distribution inequali- tiary sectors. If structure of economic growth
ty. The flow of ‘petrodollars’ from abroad, in- seems to be weak and of low quality it might
creasing positive income elasticity of demand be more rational to use a part of accumulat-
for non-tradable goods, leads to growth of the ed in stabilization funds ‘petrodollars’ to buy
prices for them. As in regard of most services promising national companies’ shares, capi-
applies uno-actu-prinzip (principle of coin- talization of which negatively correlates with
cidence of time and place of production and the carbohydrates prices dynamics, instead of
consumption of a service), many non-tradable purchasing highly reliable securities of for-

14
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

eign issuers. Finding and supporting the force served in the Russian economy between the
that opposes continuing structural degrada- primary and secondary sector shares. Such
tion, such as potentially competitive modern connection was not detected in Norway as
industries (not technologically integrated into well (0.07). The reason for this difference may
the oil and gas production and export com- consist in combination of the Russian indus-
plex, yet subsidized in the medium-term by trial production high energy intensity with its
its revenues), is a task of the utmost impor- latent subsidizing from the fuel-and-energy
tance for the Russian and Norwegian econo- complex by purchasing energy at underesti-
mies. This being so, without developing the mated domestic prices (against the internation-
mechanisms of incomes distribution and cap- al background). The world oil and gas prices
ital flow, natural resources-related rental pay- growth beneficially influences the widespread
ments and taxes will not ensure sustainable, in Russia manufacturing enterprises involved
economically positive structure effect. in the first cycle raw materials’ treatment in-
creasing their global competitiveness due to
ECONOMETRIC MODEL OF rising subsidies. Negative correlation was also
observed between the secondary and tertiary
INTERSECTORAL SHIFTS IN THE
sector shares changes in Russia (rII,III=-0,69,
ECONOMIES OF RUSSIA AND NORWAY relatively strong connection) and Norway (rII,I-
II
=-0,36, weak connection). We suppose this
The following equations of secondary sector is a consequence of the previously described
share dynamics in the Russian (y=-0.118x+27.24) features, as services are mainly non-tradable
and Norwegian (y=-0.111x+17.23) economies at international markets, and oil & gas prices
have almost identical angular coefficients de- growth has a negative effect on the tertiary sec-
scribing slope of trend line (they are -0.118 and tor industries. In order to describe connections
-0.111, respectively), while the slope angle itself between sector shares we use linear standard-
is small thus evidencing slow deindustrializa- ized regression equation ,
tion process. Dynamics of the primary and ter- where – standardized primary sector share,
tiary sector shares in both economies had slight- and – standardized sectoral coefficients
ly rising linear trend with little differing slopes, of multiple linear regression equation, and
which suggests low growth rates of mentioned – standardized shares of secondary and
sectoral shares. Growth rates are similar across tertiary sectors, respectively. For instance, co-
analogous sectors of both national economies as efficient of shows average change in
well as (to a lesser degree) across the primary primary sector share by tertiary sector share
and tertiary sectors of each country’s economies. changing by one standard deviation (δ) and
Statistical review of mutual connections be- secondary sector share average remaining
tween time series of sector shares in the Rus- constant. Equation for Russia will have the fol-
sian and Norwegian economies produced the lowing form: . As rI,III
following results. Strong negative connection is more than rI,II, absolute coefficient of in
was identified between the primary and ter- the equation exceeds absolute coefficient of
tiary sectors changes: correlation coefficient ; as a result, increase of tertiary sector share by
of these sectors’ shares (rI,III) equaled -0.8 in 1 standard deviation (δIII) will cause decrease
Russia and -0.96 in Norway. Negative value in primary sector share by 1.37δI on average
of rI,III means that the primary sector share in- (by constancy of average secondary sector
crease causes highly probable decrease in the share). In case of Norway, an equation takes
tertiary sector and vice versa. The correlation the following form:
is strong, which enables assessment of this Here correlation between the primary and ter-
connection as substantial for the intersectoral tiary sectors is much stronger than between
shifts process. No correlation (0.12) was ob- the primary and secondary ones, so increase

15
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

of tertiary sector share by 1 standard deviation shifts determining their ‘primarization’ and
(δIII) leads to mean reduction of primary sec- tertiarization with further deindustrialization
tor share by 1.07δI (while the secondary sector (however, the trend of Norwegian primary
share does not change). sector share is slightly declining). In Norway,
Less evident (as compared to the Russian correlation coefficients of the primary and
economy) reaction on the tertiary sector share secondary as well as secondary and tertiary
change of the primary sector share in the Nor- sector shares dynamics are so small that it
wegian economy can be explained by a larger is likely there is no connection between the
share of the primary sector in Norway, which mentioned sector shares change. The same
reduces coefficient . Impact of the second- coefficients in case of Russia are big enough
ary sector share changes on the primary sector to consider connections represented by them
share is negligible. in the intersectoral changes analysis.
As a reason for this distinction between
CONCLUSIONS economies, we consider Russian state policy
of lowered prices establishment at the energy
Practical aspects of using the model of na- domestic market. Modeling of transformation
tional economy division into primary, second- of the Russian and Norwegian economies sec-
ary and tertiary sectors presented in the paper toral structure brought us to the conclusion on
show contradictory nature of the post-indus- necessity of development and implementation
trial society development. The intention to of special policy that would help overcome
maintain the economy’s structure inherent in dependency on raw materials export. A gener-
industrial society and to partially adjust down al direction of suggested policy may become
the high degree of dependence on natural re- governmental aid for the tertiary sector indus-
sources exploitation resulted in considerable tries that are marked by creation of products
delay in development and introduction of with high value added and possess economi-
complying with international standards clas- cally significant positive synergetic effect.
sificators of economic activity types in some
Eastern European countries. With the aim of LITERATURE
determining common and specific elements in
Arrow, K. (1962). The Economic Implications
sectoral structural development of possessing
of Learning-by-doing. Review of Economic
significant industrial potential oil and gas pro-
Studies, 80, 155-174.
ducing countries of different degrees of mar-
ket relations maturity we studied the match- Belstat. (2012). National Statistical Committee
ing process in Russia and Norway. of the Republic of Belarus, All-State
Classification of Economic Activity
Correlation-regression analysis and devel- (ОКED). Retrived October, 21, 2015,
opment of linear model explaining intercon- from http://www.belstat.gov.ru/homep/ru/
nection of changes in sector shares of Rus- klassificator.
sian and Norwegian economies in 2000-2014
Bhagwati, J. (1958). Immiserizing Growth:
disclosed presence of consequences of the
A Geometrical Note. Review of Economic
‘Dutch Disease’. We identified most strong
Studies 25, 201-205.
connection in intersectoral development of
economy of Norway, which reveals an in- Bjorvatn, K., Farzanegan, M. R. & Schneider, F.
verse relationship between the primary and (2012). Resource Curse and Power Balance:
tertiary sector shares. At the same time, Rus- Evidence from Oil-Rich Countries. World
sian economy demonstrates an inverse rela- Development, 40, 1308-1316.
tionship between the secondary and tertiary Chenery, H. B. & Taylor, L. J. (1968).
sector shares. Both national economies have Development patterns: Among Countries
two feebly pronounced trends of structural and Over Time. The Review of Economics
and Statistics, 50, 391-416.

16
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

Chenery, H. B., Robinson, S. & Syrquin, M. Heil, H. & Steinbach, A. (2011). Damit
(1986). Industrialization and Growth: A Deutschland vorankommt: Kompass für
Comparative Study. New York: Oxford eine progressive Wirtschaftspolitik. Berlin:
University Press. Vorwärtsbuch.
Cheng, W. L., Sachs, J. & Yang, X. (2004). Klodt, H. (2000). Structural Change Towards
An extended Heckscher-Ohlin model Services: the German Experience.
with transaction costs and technological University of Birmingham.
comparative advantage. Economic Theory, Kuznets, S. (1971). Economic Growth of
23, 671-688. Nations: Total Output and Production
Cherif, R. (2013). The Dutch disease and the Structure. Harvard University Press.
technological gap. Journal of Development Kuznets, S. (1973). Modern economic growth:
Economics, 101, 248-255. findings and reflections. The American
Clark, C. G. (1940). The Conditions of Economic Economic Review, 63, 247-258.
Progress. London: Macmilla. Ngai, L. R. & Pissarides, C. A. (2007). Structural
Dietrich, A. & Krüger, J. J. (2010). Long-run change in a multi-sector model of growth. The
sectoral development: Time-series evidence American Economic Review, 97, 429-443.
for the German economy. Structural Change Opp, M. M., Sonnenschein, H. F. & Tombazos, C. G.
and Economic Dynamics, 21, 111-122. (2009). Rybczynski’s Theorem in the Heckscher-
Dülger, F., Lopcu, K., Burgaç, A. & Balli, E. Ohlin World – Anything Goes. Journal of
(2013). Is Russia suffering from Dutch International Economics, 79, 137-142.
Disease? Cointegration with structural Pasinetti, L. L. (1981). Structural Change
break. Resources Policy, 38, 605-612. and Economic Growth. Theoretical Essay
Echevarria, C. (1997). Changes in sectoral on the Dynamics of the Wealth of Nations.
composition associated with economic Cambridge University Press.
growth. International Economic Review, Pasinetti, L. L. (1993). Structural Economic
38, 431-452. Dynamics. A Theory of the Economic
Ellman, M. (1981). Natural Gas, Restructuring Consequences of Human Learning.
and Re-Industrialization: The Dutch Cambridge University Press.
Experience of Industrial Policy. In Barker, Pelzer, G., 2009. Deindustrialisierung in
T. & Brailovsky V. (Eds.). Oil or Industry? Deutschland. Hamburg: Verlag Dr. Kovač.
(pp. 27-29). London: Academic Press.
Peneder, M., Kaniovski, S. & Dachs, B. (2000).
Eurostat. (2013). Statistical Offices of the What follows tertiarisation? Structural change
European Union, NACE Ред.2 – Structure and the role of knowledge-based services. The
and explanatory. Retrived October, 21, Service Industries Journal, 23, 47-66.
2015, from http://www.circa.europa.eu/irc/
Romer, P. (1986). Increasing returns and long-
dsis/nacecpacon/info /data/en/NACE%20
run growth. Journal of Political Economy,
Rev%202%20-structure%20+%20
94, 1002-1037.
explanatory%20notes%20-%20RU.pdf.
Rosstat. (2005). Russian Statistical Yearbook,
Fisher, A. G. B. (1939). Production, primary,
Gross value added by branches and sectors
secondary and tertiary. Economic Record,
in 2000. Retrived October, 21, 2015,
15, 24-38.
from http://www.gks.ru/bgd/regl/b05_13/
Fisher, A. G. B. (1952). A note on tertiary IssWWW.exe/Stg/11-08.htm.
production. Economic Journal, 62, 820-834.
Rosstat. (2011). Russian Statistical Yearbook,
Fourastie, J. (1949). Le Grand Espoir du Gross value added by branches and sectors
XXe Siècle: Progrès Technique, Progr‘s in 2001. Retrived October, 21, 2015,
Économique, Progr‘s Social. Paris: Presses from http://www.gks.ru/bgd/regl/b05_13/
Universitaires de France. IssWWW.exe/Stg/11-09.htm.

17
V.A. Perepelkin; E.V. Perepelkina: SECTORAL STRUCTURE CHANGE MODELING OF EUROPEAN OIL...

Rosstat. (2012). Russian Federal State Statistics Statistics Norway. (2007). Statistical Yearbook
Service, All-Russian Classifier of Types of Norway. Oslo: Autor.
of Economic Activity (ОКVED). Retrived Statistics Norway. (2008). Statistical Yearbook
October, 21, 2015, from http://www.gks.ru/ of Norway. Oslo: Autor.
bgd/free/b02_60/Main.htm.
Statistics Norway. (2009). Statistical Yearbook
Rosstat. (2013). Russian Federal State of Norway. Oslo: Autor.
Statistics Service, Nominal volume of
Statistics Norway. (2011). Statistical Yearbook
gross domestic product produced. Retrived
of Norway. Oslo: Autor.
October, 21, 2015, from http://www.gks.ru/
bgd/free/b.01_19/IssWWW.exe/Stg/d000/ Statistics Norway. (2013). Statistical Yearbook
i000010r.htm. of Norway. Oslo: Autor.
Rosstat. (2015). Russian Federal State Statistics Statistics Norway. (2015). Annual national
Service, Gross domestic product and gross accounts, 2014. Retrived October,
value added by kind of economic activity. 21, 2015, from http://www.ssb.no/en/
Retrived October, 21, 2015, from http:// nasjonalregnskap-og-konjunkturer/
www.gks.ru/wps/wcn/connect/rosstat_ statistikker/nr/aar/2015-05-20?fane=tabel&
main/rosstat/ru/statistics/accounts/#. sort=nummer8tabel=228320#tab-tabel.
Rybczynski, T. M. (1955). Factor Endowments Syrquin, M. (2010). Kuznets and Pasinetti on the
and Relative Commodity Prices. Economica, study of structural transformation: Never the
22, 336-341. Twain shall meet? Structural Change and
Economic Dynamics, 21, 248-257.
Stampfl, N. S. (2011). Die Zukunft der
Dienstleistungsökonomie. Momentaufnahme Wolfe, M. (1955). The concept of economic
und Perspektiven. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. sectors. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
69, 402-420.
Statistics Norway. (2005). Statistical Yearbook
of Norway. Oslo: Autor. Young, A. (1993). Invention and bounded
learning by doing. Journal of Political
Statistics Norway. (2006). Statistical Yearbook
Economy, 101, 443-472
of Norway. Oslo: Autor.

18

You might also like