You are on page 1of 8

Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Electoral Studies
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud

Democratization of party leadership selection: Do wider selectorates


produce more competitive contests?
Ofer Kenig*
Department of Political Science, University of British Columbia, Buchanan C425, 1866 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC, Canada, V6T 1Z1

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The last two decades saw a significant shift in party leaders’ selection methods. As part of
Received 9 October 2007 a wider phenomenon of intra-party democratization, many parties opened their leader-
Received in revised form 7 July 2008 ship selection procedure to wider selection bodies (selectorates). Such a step was expected
Accepted 6 November 2008
to reduce the parties’ elitist and oligarchic tendencies by attracting more leadership
aspirants and producing more competitive contests. This study aims to evaluate whether
Keywords:
these expectations materialized – do wider selectorates produce more competitive lead-
Leadership election
ership contests? Using the selectorate’s level of inclusiveness as the explanatory variable,
Party leaders
Competitiveness this paper explores 143 leadership contests to see whether these expectations material-
Democratization ized. Several operative indicators are used to evaluate the level of competitiveness. The
Candidates main conclusion is that larger selectorates tend to attract more leadership candidates, but
also tend to produce less competitive contests.
Ó 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

The post of party leader is one of the most prominent explore 143 leadership contests and leadership successions
positions in modern parliamentary democracies. Therefore, that were held in eleven parliamentary democracies
the methods through which party leaders achieve their between 1964 and September 2007.1 Several operative
position are important political institutions. The last two indicators are used to evaluate the level of competitive-
decades saw a significant shift in party leaders selection ness: Incumbents’ success rate, the likelihood of contests,
methods: as part of a wider phenomenon of intra-party the number of candidates, and the distribution of votes
democratization, many parties opened their leadership index. The conclusion is that more inclusive selectorates do
selection procedure to wider selection bodies (selec- not necessarily enhance competitiveness. On the contrary,
torates). Such a step was perceived by many as a means of contests held in inclusive selectorates (party primaries or
bypassing the party machine and as an expression of direct one-member-one-vote systems) are more likely to produce
democracy practice. Furthermore, it was expected to a distinct early front-runner who receives a considerable
reduce the parties’ elitist and oligarchic tendencies by share of the votes.
attracting more leadership aspirants and producing more
competitive contests.
This study aims to evaluate whether these expectations
1
Case studies include leadership contests and successions in the
materialized. In other words, do wider selectorates produce
following parties: Labor Party (Australia); People’s Party and Social-
more competitive leadership contests? Using the selector- Democrats (Austria); Bloc Québécois, Canadian Alliance, Conservatives,
ate’s level of inclusiveness as the explanatory variable, I Liberals, New Democrats and Progressive Conservatives (Canada); Chris-
tian-Democrats and Social-Democrats (Germany); Fianna Fáil, Fine Gael
and Labour (Ireland); Labour and Likud (Israel); l’Unione (Italy); Demo-
crats and Liberal-Democrats (Japan); Labour and Liberals (Netherlands);
* Tel.: þ1 604 822 4922; fax: þ1 604 822 5540. People’s Party and Socialists (Spain); Conservatives, Labour, Liberals and
E-mail address: ofer.kenig@gmail.com Liberal-Democrats (United Kingdom).

0261-3794/$ – see front matter Ó 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.electstud.2008.11.001
O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247 241

1. The importance of party leaders selection methods Table 1


Party leaders’ selectorates, 1976 and 2007.

Party leaders are among the most important political Party Selectorate, Selectorate, Trend
figures in modern representative democracies. Today, 1976 2007
general elections in parliamentary democracies are often AUS Labor (ALP) PPG PPG w
decided by the nature – or at least the image – of the party Liberals PPG PPG w
leaders (McAlister, 1996: 281; Arian, 2005: 171). This AUT People’s Party (ÖVP) Party Agency Party Agency w
phenomenon has been termed the ‘presidentialization’ or Social-Democrats Party Agency Party Agency w
‘personalization’ of politics (Poguntke and Webb, 2005; (SPÖ)

Mughan, 2000; Rahat and Sheafer, 2007). In most cases, Canada Bloc Québécois – Party Members
a person seeking to become prime minister must first Conservatives Party Agency Party Members þ
Liberals Party Agency Party Agency w
assume the position of party leader. In this way, the office of
New Democrats Party Agency Party Members þ
party leader often serves as gatekeeper to the highest (NDP)
political position in the country. The methods through
Germany Christian-Democrats Party Agency Party Agency w
which party leaders achieve their position are, therefore,
(CDU)
important political institutions. Liberals (FDP) Party Agency Party Agency w
These methods become especially important when the Social-Democrats Party Agency Party Agency w
prime minister retires or dies during the parliamentary (SPD)
term. Since general elections are not required by law in Ireland Fianna Fail PPG PPG w
such cases, a new prime minister may be selected or Fine Gael PPG PPG w
nominated by the ruling party.2 In these circumstances, the Labour PPG Party Members þ
decision concerning the highest office in the country is not Israel Labour (ILP) Party Agency Party Members þ
even in the hands of the entire electorate. Instead a more Likud Party Agency Party Members þ
exclusive selectorate makes that choice – be they party Meretz – Party Members

members, party activists, party legislators or even an Japan Democrats (DPJ) – Electoral College
informal party elite group. Only four of the last ten British Liberal-Democrats PPG or party Electoral College þ
(LDP) elite
prime ministers initially assumed their office following
general elections. The others (Eden, MacMillan, Home, Nether Christian-Democrats PPG PPG w
Callaghan, Major and Brown) assumed the premiership (CDA)
Labour (PvdA) PPG Party Members þ
following an intra-party procedure. This pattern is common
Liberals (VVD) PPG Party Members þ
in other countries as well. In Japan, for instance, each of
the last six prime ministers first assumed office following NZ Labour PPG PPG w
National PPG PPG w
an internal contest within the ruling Liberal-Democrats
(LDP). Spain People’s Party (PP) Party Agency Party Agency w
Socialists (PSOE) Party Agency Party Agency w
The selection of a party leader must, therefore, not be
seen as just an intra-party matter, but rather as a procedure UK Conservatives PPG Party Members þ
that may decide the top executive in a country. The selec- Labour PPG Electoral College þ
Liberal-Democrats Party Members Party Members w
tion methods of party leaders have gone through a consid-
Scottish Nationalists Party Members þ
erable shift during the last 30 years, especially in Canada, (SNP)
the UK, Japan and Israel (See Table 1). Reacting and
PPG, Parliamentary Party Group; AUS, Australia; AUT, Austria; NZ, New
adapting to social changes, an increasing number of parties Zealand; UK, United Kingdom; Nether, The Netherlands.
have changed their internal distribution of power to give
their members a role in candidate selection, policy-making
and leadership selection (Scarrow et al., 2000; LeDuc,
2001). These measures were designed to overcome an At this point I focus on the value of competitive-
intra-party democratic deficit and to bring the citizens back ness. Although other values are significant, I believe
into the political process. The reforms reflected the desire that competitiveness stands at the forefront. While
to reduce the oligarchic tendencies of parties by creating representation may well be important in contests
a participatory revolution and by providing the rank-and- comprising a list of candidates, where there are multi-
file members a chance to make a difference. A more seats available and therefore many winners (Hazan and
inclusive participation was expected to enhance demo- Rahat, 2006), it is not of great significance for leader-
cratic values as responsiveness, transparency, representa- ship selection, where there is only one winner. The
tion and competitiveness (Cross, 1996).3 same can be said about responsiveness – party leaders,
as opposed to members of parliament, are expected to
stand above their constituents, especially if they are
vying for the position of prime minister. Competitive-
2
In most cases, prime ministers are members of the largest party in ness, on the other hand, is most relevant for party
parliament (with or without parliamentary majority) or the largest party
leaders’ selection. It reflects not only the accessibility
in the ruling coalition. Only in rare cases do they belong to other parties.
3
Others suggested a more skeptical view in which party elites
of the selection process (how ‘open’ it is) but also how
maneuvered these reforms as a measure to reduce the power of party close it is in terms of results. True, there is no reason
activists (Mair, 1994: 16; Marsh, 1993: 230). to assume that a contest that is not close is less
242 O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247

democratic, but open procedure with close results does advantage to the front-runner and may also culminate in
reflect a viable intra-party democracy. reduced competitiveness.4
On the other hand, voters in more exclusive selectorates
2. Participation and competitiveness (party activists or the party parliamentary group) are less
likely to be effected of such circumstances. First, the con-
Given the fact that many parties have democratized ducting of opinion polls in exclusive selectorates is less
their methods for selecting their leaders, we must ask reliable and sometimes not possible at all. Furthermore,
whether this change really made a difference. From this these voters’ decisions regarding what candidate to
question we may derive several directions of investiga- support are more complex. While shaped by the popularity
tion. For example: do inclusive procedures tend to of one candidate or another, they are also affected by
produce different types of leaders? Do they provide the factors such as personal relationships, loyalties, partisan
elected leaders with a more solid position? Do they bear factions and ideology. These factors may reduce the likeli-
any negative side-effects? This study is concerned with hood of a front-runner effect and therefore culminate in
one question: Is there a positive relation between tighter contests.
participation and competitiveness? In other words, do In this stage it is important to acknowledge that the
more inclusive selectorates culminate in more competi- level of participation (selectorate’s inclusiveness) is not the
tive contests? only factor that determines competitiveness. Indeed, there
Political science research is rich in studies that explore are other dimensions of leadership selection methods that
the relation between various democratic values. A great affect the incentives of candidates to compete or shape
deal has been written on relations as representation and voting patterns. For instance, rigid candidacy requirements
governance or freedom and equality, but almost none has (contest fee or signature requirements) may deter or even
explored the relation between participation and competi- prevent potential candidates from stepping forward.5
tiveness. True, many political theorists stated these values Voting methods are also important. In American primaries,
as two critical dimensions for democracy, but did not there is evidence that runoff elections have enticed more
outline a relationship between the two (Schumpeter, 1943: candidates into elections compared to plurality (FPP)
269; Dahl, 1971: 8; Vanhanen, 2000: 253). This is most elections. This is due to the fact that a runoff election makes
likely due to the fact that participation (at least since the it possible for different candidates to compete in the first
spread of universal suffrage during the 20th century) is round without the concern of splitting the vote and elect-
perceived as a constant factor. Elections at the national, ing an unpalatable plurality candidate (Glaser, 2006: 779;
regional or local level are open to the participation of the Berry and Canon, 1993). If this applies to runoff elections, it
entire adult population. But elections in an intra-party is even truer for other voting methods such as preferential
arena are of a different nature. Parties, as autonomous vote or exhaustive ballots.6 These voting methods may not
entities, may restrict the voting procedure to distinct and only lure more candidates to compete, but may also create
more exclusive populations. In other words, intra-party a chance for a candidate to ‘come from behind’ and win the
elections, including the selection of party leaders, vary in
the degree of participation. It is possible, therefore, to
explore the connection between participation and 4
Arguably, opinion polls that show a front-runner with a wide margin
competitiveness. may also persuade front-runner’s supporters that their votes are not
As mentioned earlier, the opening of the process to really necessary for the win, and therefore they might abstain as well.
However, this effect is not as strong as it is for the trailing candidates’
more inclusive selectorates was expected to produce more
supporters. Casting vote for the winner is more pleasant (even if it is not
competitive contests. Here, however, I argue for a negative vital, voters feel part of the triumph) than doing so for a likely loser.
connection between the inclusiveness of the selectorate 5
Candidates for the leadership election of the Liberal Party of Canada
and the level of competitiveness, at least when it is in 2003 had to pay 75,000 Canadian Dollars as a contest fee. Several
perceived by the tightness of the contests. In other words, potential candidates proclaimed that this sum was the main reason for
them no to enter the contest. The British Labour Party requires a candi-
the more inclusive the selectorate, the less competitive the
date to present the support of at least 12.5% of the party MPs. This strict
selecting procedure is. requirement has twice (1992, 1994) prevented Ken Livingstone from
This hypothesis rests on the assumption that selec- competing for the post of party leader, and also ensured the coronation of
torates operate different calculations and judgments in Gordon Brown in 2007, after no other candidate surpassed this threshold.
In both examples we see a reduction in the field of candidates due to
their action. Voters in inclusive selectorates (party prima-
candidacy requirements.
ries) are more exposed to the influence of opinion polls that 6
In preferential vote (alternative vote) voters rank each of the candi-
reflect the support for candidates. If such polls indicate an dates from the most to the least preferable. In the first count, the first
early front-runner, undecided voters tend to ‘get on board preferences (most preferable) are counted. If no candidate meets the
the winning wagon’ and transfer their support to the likely majority requirement, the candidate who received the least number of
first preferences is dropped from the contest and his supporters’ second
winner. This ‘front-runner effect’ enhances the probability
preferences are re-allocated to the other candidates. This procedure is
of a candidate to gather considerable support, and there- repeated until one of the candidates meets the majority requirement and
fore reduces competitiveness. Such effect may also is declared a winner. In exhaustive (or eliminative) ballots voters vote for
persuade potential candidates not to run and thus reduce one candidate. If no candidate meets the majority requirement, the
the number of candidates in the contest. Alternatively, polls candidate who received the least number of the votes is dropped from the
contest and an additional ballot is held. This procedure is repeated until
that establish a clear front-runner may also persuade his or one of the candidates meets the majority requirement and is declared
her rival’s supporters to abstain, for their act of voting is winner. In multi-candidate contests, several ballots may be needed to
perceived as ineffective. This abstention gives further select a winning candidate.
O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247 243

contest, thus increasing competitiveness. Stéphane Dion, but rather special, ad-hoc entities with the prime task of
current leader of the Liberal Party of Canada, was ranked selecting a leader (Courtney, 1995; MacIvor, 1994; Perlin,
third in the first ballot of the leadership contest of 2006. He 1988). Another difference is that rank-and-file members
eventually won the contest on the fourth ballot. participate in the earlier stages of the process. Given these
Competitiveness may also be increased if potential distinctions, and also the fact that the Canadian leadership
candidates believe they will benefit by competing, even if conventions are much larger than other selected agencies,
their chance of winning is slim. For instance, a candidate it might be argued that this sub-type of selectorate, unique
may decide to enter a contest with the aim of promoting to Canadian parties, is slightly more inclusive than other
a particular issue. Neil Fraser joined the leadership contest selected party agencies.
of the Progressive Conservatives in Canada in 1983 with the Next in line we find a selectorate that is composed of the
sole aim of promoting his anti Metric system campaign. party members. In this selectorate, also known as ‘closed
More seriously, by stepping forward as candidates, politi- primaries’, ‘party primaries’ or ‘one-member-one-vote’
cians can upgrade their status within the party and mark system (OMOV), the entire party membership participates
themselves as future leaders (Alderman and Carter, 2002: in the selection of the leader and every vote is counted
571). Having said that, I will now focus on the selecting equally. Until thirty years ago this kind of selectorate was
body, which should be considered the most important rare indeed, but since then many parties expanded the
dimension of leadership selection methods. right to select the leader to the party members. Finally, the
most inclusive selectorate is the entire Electorate of
3. The independent variable – selectorate’s a nation; here parties allow anyone, regardless of party
inclusiveness affiliation, to vote. This kind of selectorate, also known as
‘open primary’, is quite rare in parliamentary democracies
The selectorate is the body that selects the party leader. (Carty and Blake, 1999). In 2005, Romano Prodi was
It can be composed of only one person, or several or many selected as the leader of left coalition bloc (l’Unione) in Italy
selectors – up to the entire electorate (Marsh, 1993; LeDuc, in such a selectorate. This primary election was open to all
2001; Rahat and Hazan, 2001). Fig. 1 presents a continuum Italian citizens at least 18 years old and to any immigrant
concerning the inclusiveness or exclusiveness of the who had lived in Italy for at least three years. Nearly 4.5
selectorates that are included in this study. The most million voters participated in the process.
exclusive selectorate concerned here are the members of The four types of selectorates presented above may be
the parliamentary party group (PPG). The selection of the regarded as ‘pure’ selectorates. Some parties, however, use
party leader by the party’s elected representatives in the a more complex system, which involves more than one
legislature was the dominant method in the United selectorate for selecting their leaders. For example, some
Kingdom and other Westminster-model democracies until parties have opened up the process to the entire member-
the mid 1970s (Punnett, 1992; Stark, 1996). Since then, the ship, but have not gone ‘all the way’ in terms of granting each
three major British parties have abolished this system in member an equal vote. Instead, they weight the votes. The
favour of more inclusive selectorates.7 The major parties in British Labour Party and the Japanese Liberal-Democrats
Ireland, Australia and New Zealand, however, still grant (LDP) both select their leaders according to an Electoral
their representatives in parliament the prerogative to College formula, which grants the PPG votes a proportion-
choose their party leader.8 ally heavier weight. Such selectorate presents a violation of
One step towards the inclusive pole, we find the selec- the ‘every vote is equal’ principle and therefore should not
tion of leaders by a selected party agency. This selectorate is be treated as a pure type of selectorate. In terms of inclu-
very common in parties within continental Europe. Here, siveness, weighted selectorates should be considered more
the leader is selected by the members of a selected party exclusive than the pure party members type.
agency – a convention, conference, congress or assembly. Another example of the blending of selectorate types is
These are regular party agencies that command various the method used by the British Conservative party since
functions and tasks, including the selection of the party 1998. While the entire party membership has the final say in
leader. The size of these agencies varies, but generally it the selection of its leader, they may only choose between
ranges between a few hundred to one thousand members. two candidates. If more than two candidates compete for the
For much of the last century the dominant Canadian parties position, the PPG, through a series of eliminative ballots,
have employed a similar type of party convention selec- produces a short list of two names, from which the members
torate. However, their conventions differ from the cases may choose (Alderman, 1999; Quinn, 2005). The PPG,
presented above since they are not regular party agencies therefore, still yields considerable power in the process.
Hence, a system of this kind should be considered less
7
inclusive than the pure party members’ type.
The first to introduce a more inclusive selectorate were the Liberals in
1976. They were followed by the Labour Party in 1981 and by the
Conservatives in 1998. 4. The dependent variable – indicators of
8
There are slight variations regarding what kind of parliamentarian is competitiveness
entitled to participate in the vote. Some parties restrict the vote to their
representatives in the lower (or single) house, while other parties, like Measuring competitiveness, especially for leadership
the Australian Labor Party, allow their representatives in the upper house
to participate in the selection of the leader. Still other parties, such as the
selection, is a challenging task. While in candidate selec-
Irish Fine Gael, allow their representatives in the European Parliament to tion, where we have multiple winners, we can rely on
participate as well. measures as incumbents winning indices (Rahat and
244 O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247

Parliamentary Selected Party Party


Party Group Agency Members Electorate

Exclusiveness Inclusivenes

Fig. 1. Inclusiveness and exclusiveness of party leaders’ selectorates.

Hazan, 2006: 377–378), here we are more constrained, for opposition. Not all the challenges mature into a formal
we have a maximum of one incumbent for each contest. contest, and sometimes the incumbent chooses to retire
Therefore, we have to think of additional measures as well. voluntarily and spare the taste of defeat. Second, it reduces
Each of the four measurements suggested below reflects the population only to contests in which incumbents
a slightly different expression of competitiveness. Each has competed. These cases constitute a minority of the pop-
its advantages and weaknesses. ulation (36 out of 143). The following measurements avoid
this weakness and look upon broader population.
4.1. Incumbents’ success rate
4.2. Contests vs. ‘Coronations’ (likelihood of contests)
The first indicator for competitiveness is the incum-
bents’ rate of success. When the incumbent leader is Leadership change may take the form of a contest if
defeated by a challenger we may speak of a high level of more than one aspirant steps forward. It also may take the
competitiveness. The literature is rich with studies that form of a nomination or ‘coronation’ if only a single
claim that incumbency is an advantage in all kinds of contender emerges. Coronations may, of course, occur in
electoral systems and voting methods, but is more signifi- any sort of selectorate. For instance, Gordon Brown (in
cant in inclusive procedures (Engstrom and Engstrom, 2007) and Angela Merkel (2000) were installed as leaders
2008; Boll and Rommele, 1994; Sorauf, 1988). Small of the British Labour Party and the German Christian-
(exclusive) selectorates allow challengers a chance to have Democrats respectively by selectorates of medium-size of
a personal contact with each of the selectors and conduct inclusiveness; Kim Beazley (2005) was selected to the
a face-to-face persuasion. On the other hand, in large leadership of the Australian Labor Party without opposition
(inclusive) selectorates contenders cannot reach every in the exclusive selectorate of the Parliamentary Party
voter and must rely on the media and have an effective Group. Eamon Gilmore (2007) was installed as the leader of
campaign machine. Naturally, the incumbent has easier the Irish Labour Party by the inclusive selectorate of party
access to media exposure and often benefits from financial members.9 But, are coronations more common under
and organizational resources. exclusive or inclusive selectorates?
From this we may conclude that incumbents are more ‘Coronations’ constitute a minority of the case studies –
successful in inclusive selectorates. The findings, presented there are 45 coronations (31%) in general. These 45 cases
in Table 2, are not conclusive, but we may at least say that are divided unevenly: 15 occurred in exclusive selectorates,
incumbents do not seem to enjoy higher level of success in 28 in medium-size selectorates while only two in inclusive
inclusive selectorates. The successful challenges (when the selectorates. The scarcity of coronations in inclusive selec-
incumbent was defeated) are divided rather evenly torates may be due to the attraction candidates find in
between the various selectorates. Additionally, six of the competing in such broad organs. Some candidates will
ten challenges in inclusive selectorates were successful, compete even if their chances are slim, because of the high
culminating in the ousting of the leader. It seems that media exposure and the chance to establish themselves as
incumbents are most likely to defeat challengers when serious force within the party.
contests occur in selected party agencies. This sort of The most striking finding, however, is that the best
selectorate – with a medium-size level of inclusiveness – is predictor for likelihood of a coronation is the country. Party
the most loyal to the incumbent. leaders in Germany, Austria or Spain (and in other parties in
Not only is the evidence inconclusive, this measurement continental Europe) are seldom selected following
has two major weaknesses. First, it fails to reflect properly a contest. Rather, the party elite announce its agreed-upon
the position of the incumbent leader as he faces intra-party candidate and rarely an alternative candidate steps
forward. The reluctance of an open and public contest is
Table 2
rooted in the political culture and organizational values of
Incumbents success in three levels of selectorate inclusiveness (N ¼ 36). these parties. A contest may damage the party’s image and
cohesiveness and ‘ruins the good life’ (Strøm, 1993). In
Exclusive Medium Inclusive
(PPG) (Party agency (Party
other countries, such as Canada, Japan and the United
and electoral members) Kingdom, a contest is almost a certainty. Even when the
college) successor is obvious, many encourage at least one more
Unsuccessful challenge 6 11 4
(Incumbent wins)
Successful challenge 4 5 6 9
Naturally, if only one person steps forward, there is no need to
(Incumbent loses) conduct a formal vote of approval. The party members did not actually
vote for Gilmore, because he was the sole candidate, but we may still
Total 10 16 10
regard it as case of coronation occurred in inclusive selectorate.
O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247 245

candidate to compete, in order to have a proper contest Table 3


rather than a coronation.10 Number of candidates in three levels of selectorate inclusiveness: ranges
and averages (N ¼ 143).
So here we find moderate evidence that refutes the
hypothesis. It seems that in inclusive selectorates, the Exclusive Medium Inclusive
likelihood of coronations is low and therefore competition (PPG) (party agency (party members
and electoral college) and electorate)
is higher. But, one may argue, the likelihood of coronations
is, in any case, a very limited indicator for competitiveness. N 41 73 29
Range 1–6 1–11 1–7
Its main weakness lies in the fact that it only differentiates
between single-candidate and multi-candidate cases. In Average 2.1 2.8 3.6
order to reflect competitiveness more successfully we need
to take into consideration the number of candidates.
(Laakso and Taagepera, 1979). Its strength lies in the fact
4.3. Number of candidates (N) that it takes into consideration not only the absolute
number of parties but also their relative size. By this it
This may serve as a decent indicator to the competi- supplies a better reflection of the nature of a party system.
tiveness of a contest. One may argue that a higher numbers The principle of the effective number of parties may also be
of candidates imply greater competitiveness. As demon- used on presidential contests (Cox, 1997: 216; Jones, 1999)
strated in Table 3, the average of number of candidates and on leadership selection contests. Instead of counting
increases as we move towards more inclusive selectorates. the number of candidates, it measures the relative support
This finding can be explained by the fact that primary each candidate received.
elections enjoy high media exposure, and therefore set The index is calculated as follows:
a high level of motivation for people to present candidacy.
1
Some of the candidates do not necessarily vie for a win, but ENC ¼ P 2
rather run in order to attract media attention for them- Vi
selves or for a specific issue. Vi is the share of votes of the candidate i.
Still, this finding stands against the hypothesis elabo- Table 4 demonstrates the operation of the index for
rated above. But taking the absolute number of candidates four leadership contests. In each of the cases presented,
as an indicator for competitiveness may be misleading, four candidates competed, but the distribution of votes
because it does not take into account the relative strength was quite different. The contest in the Conservative Party
of the candidates. In other words, the absolute number of was the tightest, as only 12 points separated the first and
candidates may testify to the ‘openness’ or ‘accessibility’ of last candidates. This tight contest is expressed by the
a contest, but not much on its level of competitiveness. For value (3.85), only slightly lower than the maximal value of
instance, no less than seven candidates competed for the (4). The contests for the leadership of the Spanish
leadership of l’Unione in Italy in 2005. Apparently a highly Socialists (PSOE) and the Dutch Labour Party (PvdA) were
competed contest, but looking at the results we find that less tight, with two obvious front-runners. The 1983
the front-runner, Romano Prodi, secured about 75 per cent Labour leadership contest was the least tight. Neil Kin-
of all votes. This paints a very different picture of the nock gathered more than 70% support and two candidates
contest. received very few votes. This is reflected in the low value
Therefore, in order to evaluate competitiveness more of ENC.
accurately one must also take into consideration the Using the ENC as an indicator for competitiveness is an
distribution of votes between the candidates. In other important step, but we must acknowledge that it has one
words, we must also look at the results. critical drawback: it works to its best when the (absolute)
number of candidates is equal. But in this study, in oppose
4.4. Distribution of votes index (ENC/N) to the demonstration on Table 4, the number of candidates
in the population varies from 1 to 11. An ENC value of 2.7
All three measurements for competitiveness that were may reflect a high level of competitiveness if there are
presented so far lacked one basic feature – they ignored the three candidates, but a low level of competitiveness if
results, or the share of support each candidate received. seven candidates competed. We therefore need an index
This presents a substantive weakness, because the
measurement of competitiveness should take into consid-
eration the electoral performance of the candidates, or in Table 4
other words – their relative strength. The effective number Share of votes and the effective number of candidates in four contests.
of candidates may be useful for this cause. Conservatives Socialists Labour Labour
The effective number of candidates (ENC) is based on (UK) 2005 (Spain) 2000 (Netherlands) (UK) 1983
a similar index called the effective number of parties 2002
Candidate A 31.3 41.8 60.6 71.3
Candidate B 28.3 40.9 31.8 19.3
10
Former Tory leader Michael Howard (in 2003) and Labour leader Candidate C 21.2 10.5 4.7 6.2
Gordon Brown (in 2007) were both selected unopposed, but this is far Candidate D 19.2 6.8 2.9 3.2
from being the norm. This is the first time coronations occurred in the
ENC 3.85 2.79 2.12 1.82
two main UK parties for over 50 years.
246 O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247

In order to validate or refute the claim, four different


1.00
measures for competitiveness were suggested. Admittedly,
measuring competitiveness is a challenging task. There is
0.80
not a single index that can reflect it in an optimal manner.
Each of the measurements may be critiqued on different
ENC/N

0.60
grounds. Some reduce the number of cases significantly.
0.40 Others ignore the results while others yet may be only used
for multi-candidate cases and ignore the results beyond the
0.20 first round of voting. Still, I believe that the last index
R2 = 0.1965 (distribution of votes) is the best measurement available for
0.00 assessing the level of competitiveness in single-winner
PPG Selected Party Party Electorate
contests.
Agency Members
The four measurements produced different findings in
Selectorate's Inclusiveness
n = 96; regard to the main question. The first showed that
significant at p < 0.05. incumbents are not secured in their position and may be
ousted by challengers regardless of the selectorate’s level of
Fig. 2. Selectorate’s inclusiveness and distribution of votes index. N ¼ 96; inclusiveness. We also saw that ‘coronations’ are most
Significant at p < 0.05.
common in selected party agencies, a selectorate with
a medium level of inclusiveness, and are rather rare in
that will reflect the distribution of votes and will neutralize inclusive selectorates. The most striking findings, however,
the absolute number of candidates. is that while the correlation between the selectorate’s
The basic solution is to apply the ENC on a 0–1 scale. In inclusiveness and the absolute number of candidates is
order to do that we will conduct the following trans- positive, its correlation with the distribution of votes’ index
formation: ENC/N (dividing of the ENC in the absolute is negative. In other words, larger selectorates tend to
number of candidates). The resulting value reflects the attract more candidates, but also tend to produce less
extent to which the number of candidates had shrunk. competitive contests.
A maximal value of (1) means an equal distribution of votes The adoption of more inclusive measures for selecting
and reflects a maximum level of competitiveness. The party leaders perhaps increased transparency (a direct and
lower the value, the unequal the distribution of votes is, clear translation of the voters’ preferences), participation
and the less competitive the contest is. (every member is entitled to vote) and accessibility (more
I examined the relationship between the inclusiveness candidates stand), but not competitiveness, at least not as
of the selectorate and the distribution of votes index reflected by the tightness of contests.
according to the following criteria: In light of the findings, is it possible to conclude and say
that the democratization in the selection methods of party
1 Cases with a single candidate were omitted; leaders did not meet its expectations? The answer for this
2 Results refer to first ballot only; question is rather normative. If indeed the expectation was
3 In cases of mixed selectorates (Electoral College and the for the increasing of competitiveness, it has not material-
sort) I measured the results separately for each segment. ized. But, it is possible that from the point of view of a party
the democratization had succeeded well. There are more
candidates and more attention of the media for the party’s
This resulted in 97 observations. As shown in Fig. 2,
affairs. On the other hand, the likelihood of a distinct front-
there is a distinct correlation between the two variables.
runner diminishes the chances for a hard-fought race that
The probability for lower values of distribution of votes
might risk the party’s cohesiveness and public image.
index is higher in inclusive selectorates. The most evident
Furthermore, it may consolidate the position of the elected
finding is the difference of the ranges. We can find high
leaders, for they passed a double legitimating process –
values (competitive contests) in all kind of selectorates,
they were elected by a broad selectorate and with
but lower values (uncompetitive contests) are quite rare
a substantial majority.
in exclusive selectorates and more common in inclusive
Finally, although the findings are derived from a large
selectorates. The lowest value in the PPG category is 0.51
population, we need further cases of leadership selection in
and most observations have values higher than 0.8. The
inclusive selectorates for producing more solid conclusions.
lowest value in the selected party agency category is 0.44
Leadership selections in inclusive selectorates are
and except for three observations, all others are higher
becoming more common in parties worldwide. Future
than 0.6. The lowest value in the party members’ category
studies will be able to rely on larger populations for
is 0.3.
assessing the political consequences of this democratiza-
5. Conclusion tion process. In addition, the field is in need of scholars who
will investigate other factors which affect competitiveness.
This study explored the relationship between partici-
pation and competitiveness in contests for party leader-
References
ship. I claimed that in oppose to expectations, the opening
of the selection process to broader populations did not Alderman, K., 1999. Revision of leadership election procedures in the
bring with it more competitive contests. conservative party. Parliamentary Affairs 52 (2), 260–274.
O. Kenig / Electoral Studies 28 (2008) 240–247 247

Alderman, K., Carter, N., 2002. The conservative party leadership election Adaptation in Party Organizations in Western Democracies. Sage,
of 2001. Parliamentary Affairs 55 (3), 569–585. London, pp. 1–22.
Arian, A., 2005. Politics in Israel: the Second Republic. CQ Press, Wash- Marsh, M., 1993. Introduction: selecting the party leader. European
ington DC. Journal of Political Research 24 (3), 229–231.
Berry, W.D., Canon, B.C., 1993. Explaining the competitiveness of guber- McAlister, I., 1996. Leaders. In: LeDuc, L., Niemi, R.G., Norris, P. (Eds.),
natorial primaries. The Journal of Politics 55 (2), 454–471. Comparing Democracies: Elections and Voting in Global Perspective.
Boll, B., Rommele, A., 1994. The problem of incumbency in democratic Sage, Thousand Oaks, pp. 280–298.
systems. In: Somit, A., Wildermann, R., Boll, B., Rommele, A. (Eds.), Mughan, A., 2000. The Presidentialization of Parliamentary Elections.
The Victorious Incumbent: a Threat to Democracy? Dartmouth, Palgrave, Basingstoke.
Aldershot, pp. 19–25. Perlin, G., 1988. Party Democracy in Canada: the Politics of National Party
Carty, R.K., Blake, D.E., 1999. The adoption of membership votes for Conventions. Prentice-Hall, Scarborough, Ontario.
choosing party leaders – the experience of Canadian parties. Party Poguntke, T., Webb, P. (Eds.), 2005. The Presidentialization of Politics:
Politics 5 (2), 211–224. a Study in Comparative Politics. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Courtney, J.C., 1995. Do Conventions Matter? Choosing National Party Punnett, R.M., 1992. Selecting the Party Leader: Britain in Comparative
Leaders in Canada. McGill-Queen’s University Press, Montreal. Perspective. Harvester-Wheatsheaf, London.
Cox, G.W., 1997. Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the Quinn, T., 2005. Leasehold or freehold? Leader-eviction rules in the British
World’s Electoral Systems. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. conservative and labour parties. Political Studies 53 (4), 793–815.
Cross, W., 1996. Direct election of provincial party leaders in Canada, Rahat, G., Sheafer, T., 2007. The personalization(s) of politics: Israel, 1949–
1985–1995: the end of leadership convention. Canadian Journal of 2003. Political Communication 24 (1), 65–80.
Political Science 29 (2), 295–315. Hazan, R.Y., Rahat, G., 2006. The influence of candidate selection methods
Dahl, R.A., 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. Yale University on legislatures and legislators: theoretical propositions, methodo-
Press, New Haven. logical suggestions and empirical evidence. The Journal of Legislative
Engstrom, R.L., Engstrom, R.N., 2008. The majority vote rule and runoff Studies 12 (3-4), 366–385.
primaries in the United States. Electoral Studies 27 (3), 407–416. Rahat, G., Hazan, R.Y., 2001. Candidate selection methods: an analytical
Glaser, J.M., 2006. The primary runoff as a remnant of the old south. framework. Party Politics 7 (3), 297–322.
Electoral Studies 25 (4), 776–790. Scarrow, S.E., Webb, P., Farrell, D.M., 2000. From social integration to
Jones, M.P., 1999. Electoral laws and the effective number of candidates in electoral contestation: the changing distribution of power within
presidential elections. Journal of Politics 61 (1), 171–184. political parties. In: Dalton, R.J., Wattenberg, M.P. (Eds.), Parties
Laakso, M., Taagepera, R., 1979. Effective number of parties: a measure Without Partisans: Political Change in Advanced Industrial Democ-
with application to western Europe. Comparative Political Studies 12 racies. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 129–151.
(1), 3–27. Schumpeter, J.A., 1943. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. George
LeDuc, L., 2001. Democratizing party leadership selection. Party Politics 7 Allen and Unwin, London.
(3), 323–342. Sorauf, F.J., 1988. Money in Elections. Harper Collins, New York.
MacIvor, H., 1994. The leadership convention: an institution under Stark, L.P., 1996. Choosing A Leader: Party Leadership Contests in Britain
stress. In: Mancuso, M., Price, R.G., Wagenberg, R. (Eds.), Leaders from Macmillan to Blair. Macmillan, Basingstoke.
and Leadership in Canada. Oxford University Press, Toronto, pp. Strøm, K., 1993. Competition ruins the good life: party leadership in
13–27. Norway. European Journal of Political Research 24 (3), 317–347.
Mair, P., 1994. Party organizations: from civil society to the state. In: Vanhanen, T., 2000. A new dataset for measuring democracy, 1810–1998.
Katz, R.S., Mair, P. (Eds.), How Parties Organize: Changing and Journal of Peace Research 37 (2), 251–265.

You might also like