You are on page 1of 15

Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Business Research


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbusres

A tiger with wings: CEO–board surname ties and agency costs T


a,⁎ a,⁎ b a,c
Liang Zhang , Zhe Zhang , Ming Jia , Yeyao Ren
a
School of Management, Xi’an Jiaotong University, China
b
School of Management, Northwestern Polytechnical University, China
c
College of Business in City University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: Although corporate governance literature recognizes the influence of acquired social ties between CEOs and
Surname ties directors, innate social ties are hardly explored. To extend this literature, this study examines how CEO–board
Agency costs surname ties influence agency costs. Drawing on social identity theory, we first develop the argument that
Corporate governance CEO–board surname ties result in increased agency costs. We then employ agency theory to examine the
Social identity theory
boundary conditions under which such directors are less likely to act as group members of surname ties.
Agency theory
Specifically, we consider three key governance tools as such conditions, namely, monitoring by shareholders,
aligning directors’ interests with firm value, and aligning supervisors’ interests with firm value. We find em-
pirical support for our arguments by using a sample of 16,926 listed firms and 165,287 directors in China from
2005 to 2015. We discuss the contributions to corporate governance literature and elucidate the practical im-
plications of our findings.

1. Introduction background, and political orientation, influence governance outcomes


(e.g., Fracassi & Tate, 2012; Hwang & Kim, 2009; Lee et al., 2014;
As corporate “apex of decision control systems,” boards of directors Westphal, 1999). However, limited attention has been given to ascribed
are the primary and prominent governance mechanisms that monitor or innate social ties (e.g., surname), which are formed once individuals
managers and protect shareholders’ interests (Fama & Jensen, 1983, p. are born (Tsui & Farh, 1997). As the “roots” of individuals, innate
311). However, certain studies suggest that directors are likely in- characteristics tend to accompany them throughout life and influence
effective controllers and monitors and even become “conspirators” or their interactions with others and their decisions. For example, Kish-
“puppets” of executives (e.g., Hwang & Kim, 2009; Westphal, 1999; Gephart and Campbell (2015) suggest that executives’ social class ori-
Westphal & Zajac, 1995). Scholars of behavioral perspectives on cor- gins have a lasting impact on their tendency to take risks. Compared
porate governance argue that it is mainly because directors’ psycholo- with achieved ties, ascribed ties are more likely to be a basis of group
gical biases potentially restrict board monitoring (Gupta & Wowak, identity because of their higher visibility to in- and out-group members
2017; Lee, Lee, & Nagarajan, 2014). They emphasize the role of social- and are more exogenous for governance outcomes (Gompers,
psychological factors (e.g., CEO–board social relations) in governance Mukharlyamov, & Xuan, 2016).
outcomes (Boivie, Lange, McDonald, & Westphal, 2011; Westphal & Second, the boundary conditions of relationship between
Zajac, 2013; Zhu & Westphal, 2014). In this view, directors are “socially CEO–board social ties and governance outcomes remain unsettled.
situated and constituted agencies,” who construct decisions based on Although behavioral governance literature sheds valuable insights into
their “multiplex roles and identities” embedded in their social lives and the effect of agencies’ social-psychological factors on governance out-
relationships (Westphal & Zajac, 2013, p. 624). comes, the findings are equivocal. Hwang and Kim (2009), for example,
Therefore, a flourishing body of governance research pays attention indicate that social-psychological factors (e.g., CEO-director social ties)
to social ties between CEOs and directors, which likely elicit directors’ impair board independence and reduce firm performance. However,
psychological biases in evaluating executives and hence affect agency other studies hold that such factors are not determinant (Gompers et al.,
conflicts and agency costs. However, this literature reveals two major 2016; Hoitash, 2011; Harris, Karl, & Lawrence, 2019). These studies
gaps. First, most studies on CEO–board social ties focus on how achieved failed to consider the role of agencies’ economic rationality as a
or acquired social ties, such as mutual alma mater, professional boundary condition of the relationship between social ties and


Corresponding authors at: Xi’an, Shannxi 710049, China.
E-mail addresses: 13772073171@163.com (L. Zhang), zhangzhe220@sina.com (Z. Zhang), jiaming@nwpu.edu.cn (M. Jia), 18294413280@163.com (Y. Ren).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.06.026
Received 14 February 2019; Received in revised form 10 June 2020; Accepted 11 June 2020
Available online 07 July 2020
0148-2963/ © 2020 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

governance outcomes. This angle may help us explain such conflicting attach great importance to social and family ties (Du, 2016; He et al.,
results because directors conduct monitoring activities not only as so- 2017), yet little scholarly attention has been given to how these ties
cial actors with multiple roles and identifies but as rational agents of influence directors’ behaviors. This study contributes to corporate
shareholders (Hillman, Nicholson, & Shropshire, 2008). In addition to governance literature in several ways. First, rather than focusing on
social-psychological factors, economic rationality also impacts direc- acquired social ties, this study examines one form of innate social ties,
tors’ decisions (Gupta & Wowak, 2017; Harris et al., 2019). Thus, it namely, CEO–board surname ties. In addition, it adds to the literature
would be valuable to examine and clarify the boundary conditions on the antecedents of agency costs. Second, a noteworthy contribution
under which directors are more likely to act in an economic manner that we make to behavioral governance literature (Hillman et al., 2008;
than as group members of social ties. Doing so furthers our under- Westphal & Zajac, 2013) is to identify when and why socially situated
standing of the interactions between directors’ social and economic and constituted agencies may act as economic actors. Finally, this study
roles. extends the literature on surname ties by reasoning why in-group fa-
To fill the mentioned research gaps, this study draws on social voritism elicited by surname ties occurs, introducing governance tools
identity theory and agency theory to examine (1) whether and how to reduce such favoritism, and revealing the potential benefits of sur-
surname ties between a CEO and directors influence agency costs and name ties.
(2) the boundary conditions under which such directors are less likely
to act as group members of surname ties but may act as rational agents. 2. Literature review
Surname ties are one form of innate social ties. Similar to a genetic
locus on the Y chromosome, a surname can be transmitted along gen- In this part, we first review the literature on different perspectives
erations virtually unchanged as a “reliable genetic marker” in patri- on corporate governance. Economic perspectives treat directors as
lineal systems (Gymrek, McGuire, Golan, Halperin, & Erlich, 2013; purely economic actors; in contrast, behavioral perspectives assume
Manni, Heeringa, Toupance, & Nerbonne, 2008, p. 41; Sykes & Irven, directors’ behaviors as a function of their social identities and roles. We
2000). Therefore, a shared surname is a sign of the ancestral relation- then review the literature on surnames to explain the implications of
ship among people (Jacobs, 1979; Langenberg, 2007; Liu, Chen, Yuan, surname ties to people.
& Chen, 2012). Du (in press) suggests that “the shared surname on
individual behavior and corporate decisions is still a pending but im- 2.1. Economic and behavioral perspectives on corporate governance
portant problem.”
Specifically, drawing on social identity theory (Ashforth & Mael, Economic and behavioral perspectives on corporate governance
1989; Tafjel & Turner, 1986; Turner, 1987), we argue that surname ties propose different theoretical lenses on directors’ decisions and beha-
motivate the CEO and directors to classify themselves into the same viors. Economic perspectives assume economic rationality as the dri-
group. Because of in-group biases or favoritism elicited by surname ties, vers of directors’ behaviors and emphasize the role of formal structures
directors are biased in evaluating and monitoring the CEO’s self-serving and systems in aligning the interests of owners and directors. Such
activities, thereby increasing agency costs. Furthermore, we examine perspectives form the basis of agency theory (Fama & Jensen, 1983;
how this relationship is contingent upon corporate governance tools Jensen & Meckling, 1976). With the separation of ownership and con-
based on agency theory. This theory highlights directors’ roles as ra- trol, firm power is delegated to managers (executives). Managers may
tional agents of shareholders and introduces governance tools to miti- conduct self-serving activities to maximize their own interests at the
gate agents’ biased behaviors (e.g., directors’ biases triggered by sur- expense of shareholders. Agency theorists argue that the primary duty
name ties) (e.g., Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Jia, Huang, & Man Zhang, of directors is to control managerial opportunism (i.e., managers’ self-
2019). Therefore, we consider three key governance tools—monitoring serving and unethical behaviors) and to ensure that corporate decisions
by shareholders, aligning directors’ interests with firm value, and carried out by managers are in the best interests of owners, thereby
aligning supervisors’ interests with firm value. reducing agency conflicts (e.g., Hillman & Dalziel, 2003).
In addition, to extend the literature on surname ties, we conduct a However, empirical results on the role of directors in reducing
series of further analyses that investigate (1) whether surname ties are agency costs are ambivalent. According to agency theory, independent
harmful to firm performance; (2) the potential benefits of surname ties; directors should control CEOs’ self-serving and irresponsible behaviors,
(3) why directors do not care about their reputation in the labor market thus increasing firm value and reducing agency costs (Liu, Miletkov,
and the reputation of the surname-ties group to show their biased Wei, & Yang, 2015; Rashid, 2015). However, this relationship has re-
evaluation on the CEO; (4) how CEO–director dialect similarity influ- ceived little support from other studies (Ramdani & Witteloostuijn,
ences the effect of surname ties on agency costs. 2010; Singh & Davidson, 2003). Such inconclusiveness shifts scholars’
We find empirical support for our overall theory by using a sample focus away from directors’ economic rationality and toward their psy-
of 16,926 listed firms and 165,287 directors in China from 2005 to chological biases and social relationships, which may affect board
2015. Our results show that CEO–board surname ties increase agency monitoring (Hillman et al., 2008; Lee et al., 2014).
costs and this relationship weakens when firms have strong monitoring Therefore, scholars propose behavioral perspectives on governance,
by shareholders or when directors’ or supervisors’ interests are closely which hold that directors’ social-psychological factors “play a central
aligned with firm value. We select China as the empirical context for role” in decisions and behaviors (Gupta & Wowak, 2017, p. 5; Westphal
several reasons. First, given that formal systems and institutions in & Zajac, 2013). Such perspectives suggest that “the molecule of all
China are underdeveloped and incomplete, informal institutional con- social life is the socially constructed and socially situated individual,
straints, such as interpersonal ties, may play an important role in af- who lives, acts, and develops within a set of proximate social re-
fecting economic exchanges and corporate governance (He, Pittman, lationships, institutions, norms, and rules” (Little, 2012, p. 143). As
Rui, & Wu, 2017; Xin & Pearce, 1996). Second, the influence of surname socially situated and socially constituted agencies, directors conduct
ties can be easily observed in China because of its Confucian culture, monitoring activities as social actors whose motives are derived from
which attaches considerable importance to the sense of family and multiple roles and identities they accumulate through social relation-
ancestry (Du, 2016). Third, the Chinese do not change their surnames ships and socialization (Westphal & Zajac, 2013). For example, Lee
generally (Liu et al., 2012), hence ensuring the validity of CEO–board et al. (2014) demonstrate that alignment in political orientation be-
surname ties as the independent variable. tween CEOs and directors leads to increased agency conflicts. Hwang
Departing from a majority of board research that has focused on and Kim (2009) demonstrate that CEO–board social ties (i.e., mutual
Western countries, we provide a new context (i.e., China) to examine alma mater and military service) inhibit board monitoring and thus
directors’ social ties. This context is interesting because Chinses people increase agency costs. According to such behavioral perspectives,

272
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

directors’ social identities elicited by social-psychological factors can Farh, 1997). From ancient to modern times, Chinese with the same
affect board decisions and the effectiveness of board monitoring. surname have always practiced the custom of inheriting family gen-
Consequently, a large body of literature examines how CEO–board ealogy and building clans, which were paramount social organizations
social-psychological factors (e.g., social ties) influence board mon- in pre-modern China (Greif & Tabellini, 2017). Doing so allows them to
itoring. Most of studies examine that how achieved or acquired social promote clan culture, help each other (e.g., defend against enemies),
ties, such as mutual alma mater, military service, professional back- and enhance cooperation. Nowadays, Chinese people with the same
ground, employment experience, education level, and political or- surname still construct and maintain ancestral halls (“Ci Tang” in
ientation influence governance outcomes (e.g., Fracassi & Tate, 2012; Chinese), which are used for sacrifices, meetings for affairs, recording
Hwang & Kim, 2009; Lee et al., 2014; Westphal, 1999; Westphal & or commending great people (i.e., Hall of Fame), and the manifestation
Zajac, 1995). However, ascribed or innate social ties between CEOs and of their clans’ reputation and prestige. “These cultural practices help
directors have been receiving little attention. The “roots” of individuals, reinforce the bond between clan members, create group identities, and
including corporate decision makers, have important influences on forge solidarity” (Peng, 2004, p. 1050). Hence, people with the same
their decisions and behaviors (Kish-Gephart & Campbell, 2015). Com- surname always show favor and generosity to each other.
pared with achieved ties, ascribed ties are more visible to in- and out- Consequently, scholars examine how clan culture or surname ties
group members and thus more likely to elicit individuals’ psychological affect corporate outcomes. In the early stages of market reform, private
biases. The influence of ascribed ties on corporate governance is more entrepreneurs largely rely on informal norms for security because of
exogenous than achieved ties, because shareholders tend to select di- ineffective legal protection. Peng (2004) suggests that kin solidarity and
rectors based on their ability-related characteristics (e.g., educational kin trust embedded in clan culture protect the property rights of private
background and employment experience) rather than their innate entrepreneurs against cadre predation and political discrimination,
characteristics (Gompers et al., 2016). Therefore, governance research which are the greatest obstacles to the development of private en-
on innate ties incurs little endogeneity issues related to self-selection trepreneurship. Audit firms face great competitive pressures in China,
biases. where signing auditors may submit to managers and lose their in-
dependence in order to retain clients, especially when auditors have
2.2. Implications of surname ties social ties with the CEO (Du, in press; Wang, Wong, & Xia, 2008). Given
that clan culture based on shared surnames motivate people to form
Surnames signify people’s blood relationships, which are basic so- group identity, in-group favoritism may occur. Du (in press) finds that
cial ties (Jacobs, 1979; Peng, 2004). Surname ties have considerable such favoritism impairs the independence of signing auditors who share
implications for people, especially the Chinese. First, it is due to his- surnames with the CEO and thus increase the likelihood of corporate
torical factors. The culture of Chinese surnames has continued and financial misstatement.
developed throughout the last 5000 years. In 2852 BC, Emperor Fuxi
established surnames to distinguish among clans and to conduct a 3. Hypothesis development
census. Discovering the harm of consanguineous marriages, Xi Zhou
dynasty (1046 BC–771 BC) stipulated that people in the same clans (i.e., In this section, we develop four hypotheses. The first hypothesis
sharing the same surname) should not marry. This concept still plays a examines the relation between CEO–board surname ties and agency
role in certain rural areas of modern China. As the population grows, costs. The remaining hypotheses examine the boundary conditions of
the number of surnames increases sharply. Nowadays, more than this relationship, i.e., how governance tools—monitoring by share-
20,000 surnames exist, but merely 100 of them are common (called holders and aligning directors’ or supervisors’ interests with firm va-
“one hundred surnames” in Chinese; see Appendix A). lue—weaken this relationship.
Second, surnames are preserved well through generations as a sign
of honor or dignity of Chinese people. Unlike citizens in western 3.1. CEO–board surname ties and agency costs
countries, Chinese women keep their surnames unchanged after mar-
riage. Children’s surnames are generally inherited from their fathers. Drawing on social identity theory, we elucidate how CEO–board
Men are considered impuissant, and social discrimination may incur if surname ties increase agency costs. According to this theory, people
their surnames cannot be endowed on their children after marriage. routinely classify themselves and others into social categories in order
This phenomenon is called “son-in-law by adoption” (“Ruzhui” in to locate or define themselves in a social environment (Ashforth &
Chinese). Mael, 1989; Tafjel & Turner, 1986; Turner, 1987). Such categorization
Third, surname ties are an important basis of self-identity and social may occur “automatically and without conscious awareness”
identity for people. Deeply influenced by Confucian culture, people (Hewstone, Hantzi, & Johnston, 1991, p. 579). People always cate-
attach considerable importance to the concept of “self in relation to gorize themselves and others based on some visible or readily ob-
other” (Tsui & Farh, 1997, p. 60) and “one’s obligations to kin” (Peng, servable characteristics such as surname (Du, in press; Jacobs, 1979),
2004, p. 1049). Different from the western view of an independent self, race (Hewstone et al., 1991), and gender (Westphal & Stern, 2007).
guanxi or interpersonal ties are always the most important clue for the Social identity theory argues that social categorization can lead to
Chinese in forming their views and identities of society. People with the in-group or out-group biases consciously or unconsciously (Ashforth &
same surname always consider themselves and are believed to have the Mael, 1989; Brewer, 1979). That is, people show a positive bias when
same ancestors (Jacobs, 1979; Langenberg, 2007, p. 61). Consequently, evaluating others who have similar characteristics such as surnames
they categorize themselves into the same social group based on this and a negative bias toward out-group people, who do not have such
ancestral relationship. characteristics. Consequently, “ultimate attribution error” likely occurs
Consistent with the view that a shared surname signals a common because people always attribute positive behaviors of in-group mem-
ancestor, previous studies find that surnames can be used as proxies to bers to internal traits such as ability and attribute their negative be-
identify race and ancestry (Cheng, 2012; Shah et al., 2010; Waters, haviors to external causes (Hewstone, 1990; Westphal & Stern, 2007, p.
1989), to identify the distribution of dialect pronunciations (Manni 271).
et al., 2008), and are reliable identifiers for the genetic locus on the Y Considering the behavioral perspectives on governance, corporate
chromosome (Gymrek et al., 2013; Manni et al., 2008, p. 41; Sykes & decision makers (e.g., executives and directors), who are socially si-
Irven, 2000). tuated and constituted agencies, can have multiple social identities that
Fourth, surname ties among people can shorten their social distance are based on observable features (Westphal & Zajac, 2013). We argue
and improve their group identity (Charness & Gneezy, 2008; Tsui & that a CEO and relative directors classify each other into social groups

273
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

based on shared surnames. In-group biases or favoritism elicited by with agency costs.
such ties inhibit the directors’ monitoring and control of the CEO’s self-
serving behavior, thereby increasing agency costs.
First, surname ties between executives and directors can be im- 3.2. Boundary conditions of the relationship between surname ties and
portant conduits for their categorization. Throughout time, Chinese agency costs
people persistently attach great importance to kinship. Kinship has a set
of norms about social life and family education, which impacts in- It would be valuable to investigate when and why socially situated
dividuals’ values and behaviors (Peng, 2004). As a sign and symbol of and constituted agencies are more likely to act economically. Scholars
kinship, surnames bond people together and bring them a sense of of behavioral perspectives predict that social-psychological factors
belonging (Greif & Tabellini, 2017). Nowadays, people with the same largely determine the behaviors of socially situated and constituted
surname are considered to have a common ancestor (Langenberg, agencies (e.g., directors and CEOs) and firm performance (Fracassi &
2007). Chinese people hardly change surnames because surnames are a Tate, 2012; Hwang & Kim, 2009). However, other studies find that such
sign of dignity and a key to identify ancestors. To inherit the notion of factors are not determinant (Gompers et al., 2016; Hoitash, 2011;
respect for ancestors, Chinese fathers often educate children, “because Harris et al., 2019). These studies failed to consider the role of agencies’
you are a member of our clans, I hope that you can bring honor to our economic rationality as a boundary condition of the social ties and firm
ancestors in the future” (“Guang Zong Yao Zu” in Chinese). Thus, the outcomes relationship. This issue is a worthwhile subject because di-
ancestral relationship based on surnames likely motivates people to rectors act not only as group members of social ties but also as rational
categorize them into the same social groups (e.g., the same clans) agents of owners (Gupta & Wowak, 2017; Hillman et al., 2008). For
consciously or unconsciously. For example, the picture that appears in example, a director may have identities associated with his/her role as
the minds of Chinese people is of their common ancestral halls or clan a parent, a son, and a member of a basketball team or other social ties;
groups when they share the same surname. Given the under- he/she is also the agent of owners and should perform the duty. Thus,
development of formal institutions (e.g., laws and rules) in China, scholars warrant future research on the integration of multiple theo-
managers often rely on informal ties (e.g., social ties and culture) to retical lenses to clarify such conditions (Boyd, Haynes, & Zona, 2011;
conduct their decisions and behaviors (Du, 2016; He et al., 2017). Thus, Christopher, 2010).
directors and the CEO may classify them into the same group based on Previous studies on economic and behavioral perspectives indicate
shared surnames. that treating directors either as social or economic actors alone would
Second, in-group biases or favoritism derived from shared surnames result in conflicting findings, which hinders our understanding of di-
occur when directors evaluate the CEO. This is because surname ties rectors’ behaviors (Hillman et al., 2008). The integration of the per-
shorten social distance among people, such as showing favor and gen- spectives from economic and behavioral governance can be useful to
erosity to one another and “creating group identities” (Peng, 2004, p. explain the inconclusiveness. For example, integrating gender sociali-
1050). Clan organizations expect their members to “assist each other in zation theory with agency theory, Harris et al. (2019) find that female
any way that may be required (Greif & Tabellini, 2017, p.5).” Biases or CEOs are not necessarily risk-averse and exhibit similar economic be-
favoritism occur among surname-sharing people. Charness and Gneezy haviors (i.e., earnings management) to male CEOs at high levels of
(2008) find that dictators allocate more pie to people whose surnames equity-based compensation. Hence, the limited influence of social-
are revealed than those with anonymity in a dictator game. Citizens psychological factors on directors’ behaviors can be attributed to their
might vote for a candidate who shares the same surname with them in economic rationality.
elections (Jacobs, 1979). Thus, directors who share surnames with a However, previous studies examined directors’ social roles and ra-
CEO likely exhibit empathy and favoritism toward the CEO and slightly tional agents separately. Behavioral governance literature mostly fo-
criticize the CEO. cuses on when socially situated and constituted agencies (e.g., direc-
Such biases inhibit board monitoring and increase the CEO’s self- tors) are more likely to act as social actors (Du, in press; Westphal &
serving behavior. According to social identity theory, the attribution Zajac, 2013). For instance, Du (in press) find that a CEO and auditors
error likely occurs among in-group members. We thus argue that di- are more likely to act as group members of surname ties when they
rectors may make excuses for the self-serving behaviors of the CEO who establish another social identity based on hometown relationship.
share the same surnames with them. For instance, when receiving and However, little is known about when and why such agencies are more
entertaining visitors from governments and other organizations, a CEO likely to act in an economic manner than as group members of social
likely consumes the firm’s resources to pursue his/her own interests ties.
(e.g., obtain appointments in governments). Surname-sharing directors Drawing on agency theory, we examine such boundary conditions.
may attribute the CEO’s high entertainment expense on visitors and This theory emphasizes directors’ economic rationality and introduces
himself/herself to the demand of building corporate networks. These corporate governance tools, including monitoring mechanisms and in-
directors may also attribute good team performance to the CEO’s out- centive schemes, to improve board monitoring and reduce agency
standing leadership and competence and attribute bad firm perfor- conflicts (e.g., Hillman & Dalziel, 2003; Jia et al., 2019; Pepper & Gore,
mance to external causes, and thus paying the CEO excessive salaries 2015). These tools can force or motivate directors to act as rational
and bonuses. Consequently, such biased evaluation of the CEO lessens agents of owners and prevent them from engaging in certain activities
the effectiveness of board monitoring in preventing the CEO’s self-ser- that increase agency costs. Such activities include directors’ biased
ving behavior. evaluation of CEOs and their reduction in monitoring due to CEO–-
Finally, agency costs increase because the effectiveness of board director social ties (Westphal, 1999) or group and social identities
monitoring in preventing the CEO’s self-serving behavior is lessening. (Hillman et al., 2008). Therefore, we consider whether surname-sharing
According to corporate governance research, agency costs include costs directors exhibit economic behaviors in the face of corporate govern-
used to prevent the CEO’s self-serving behavior and “those incurred ance tools.
when such behavior is not prevented” (Boivie et al., 2011, p. 551; Agency theorists suggest that modern firms have “two key corporate
Jensen & Meckling, 1976). In sum, CEO–board surname ties elicit in- governance practices” that control the agency risk (Jia et al., 2019, p.
group biases or favoritism, which inhibits directors’ monitoring and 223), including the monitoring of owners and aligning agents’ private
control of the CEO’s self-serving behavior, thereby increasing agency interests with firm value (Dharwadkar, Goranova, Brandes, & Khan,
costs. Therefore, we propose the following hypothesis. 2008; Shleifer & Vishny, 1997). Accordingly, we consider three im-
portant governance tools—monitoring by shareholders, aligning direc-
Hypothesis 1 (H1). CEO–board surname ties are positively associated
tors’ private interests with firm value, and aligning supervisors’ private

274
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

interests with firm value. Given that supervisors (i.e., members of the are largely determined by surname ties. In this case, these directors may
supervisory board) are important agents in monitoring CEOs and di- show more biases toward the CEO than their counterparts whose pri-
rectors in many countries (e.g., Germany, Netherlands, and China), we vate interests are more aligned with firm value, thereby inhibiting the
also considered the role of supervisor monitoring. directors’ monitoring and exacerbating the CEO’s self-serving activities.
Therefore, we propose the third hypothesis.
3.2.1. Monitoring by shareholders
Hypothesis 3 (H3). The relationship between CEO–board surname ties
With strong monitoring, shareholders are more likely to control
and agency costs will be weakened when directors’ interests are more
directors’ biases triggered by surname ties. Agency theorists suggest
aligned with firm value.
that large shareholders provide more effective monitoring than free-
riding small shareholders because the former have more stakes in firms,
and thus have more incentives to monitor agents (Dharwadkar et al., 3.2.3. Aligning supervisors’ private interests with firm value
2008; Hartzell & Starks, 2003; Pedersen & Thomsen, 2003). For in- Listed firms in many countries, such as Germany, Netherlands, and
stance, Hartzell and Starks (2003) find that large shareholders can re- China, are required to adopt a two-tier board, a board of directors and a
duce executive compensation and increase pay–performance sensi- supervisory board (e.g., Dahya, Karbhari, Xiao, & Yang, 2003; Farag &
tivity. Jia et al. (2019) indicate that the largest shareholders can Mallin, 2016; Maassen & Van Den Bosch, 1999). The main responsi-
effectively control the moral hazard that arises from managers and bility of the supervisory board is to monitor the ethical conduct of CEOs
directors. Hence, when a shareholder exerts a stronger monitor on and directors, to review corporate financial reports, to take corrective
agents’ actions, such actions are more likely aligned with the share- measures when the behavior of CEOs or directors is detrimental to
holder’s interests. firms, and to propose shareholders’ temporary meetings (Farag &
As a result, the agents are more likely to act as rational agents of Mallin, 2016; Ran, Fang, Luo, & Chan, 2015). We expect that the effect
shareholders and protect shareholders’ interests.1 Facing strong mon- of CEO–board surname ties on agency costs is weakened when super-
itoring, surname-sharing directors are less likely to show biased eva- visors’ interests are more aligned with firm value.
luation of the CEO. Otherwise, they may incur punishments (e.g., dis- The supervisory board is an important and effective monitor that
missal and decreased compensation) from shareholders. Hence, we prevents and controls CEOs’ and directors’ self-serving and irrespon-
offer a hypothesis. sible behaviors. First, the supervisory board has the power and re-
sponsibility to monitor CEOs and directors. For example, the Chinese
Hypothesis 2 (H2). The relationship between CEO–board surname ties
Company Law in 2005 stipulated that the supervisory board has the
and agency costs will be weakened when firms have strong monitoring
power to call for shareholders’ decisions on the dismissal of CEOs and
performed by shareholders.
directors. The supervisory board is appointed by shareholders and must
consist of shareholders and elected employees. Supervisors should hold
3.2.2. Aligning directors’ private interests with firm value regular meetings and write reports about corporate affairs, which can
When directors’ private interests or incentives are more aligned be important information channels for shareholders. Second, super-
with firm value, they have a greater personal stake in protecting or visors are more effective monitors when their interests are more aligned
improving shareholder or firm value (Jia et al., 2019; Shleifer & Vishny, with firm value (Farag & Mallin, 2016; Ran et al., 2015). For example,
1997). Compared with their counterparts whose interests are unaligned the presence of a supervisory board is conducive to improving the
with firm value, these directors have a stronger identification with quality of corporate governance (Dahya et al., 2003). Shareholding
being shareholders and show more willingness to monitor executives among supervisors provides strong incentives for them to monitor CEOs
(e.g., Hillman & Dalziel, 2003; Hillman et al., 2008). Hence, these di- and directors in driving firms to enhance accounting information
rectors become vigilant and stringent in evaluating executives. quality (Ran et al., 2015).
We expect that surname-sharing directors may act rationally to Consequently, when supervisors’ private interests are more aligned
pursue their own interests when their private interests are aligned with with firm value (i.e., stronger monitoring performed by the supervisory
firm value. In firms with directors whose private interests are aligned board), surname-sharing directors may act rationally (i.e., lessen fa-
with firm value, these directors can be group members of surname ties voritism toward the CEO) to avoid punishments and complaints from
and shareholders. Thus, their evaluations of the CEO are not simply the supervisory board. Hence, monitoring by supervisors may mitigate
determined by surname ties but also by private costs and returns. The the effect of surname ties. Therefore, we propose the following hy-
costs of their biased evaluation on the surname-sharing CEO are high pothesis.
due to a close alignment between their interests and firm value. As Hypothesis 4 (H4). The relationship between CEO–board surname ties
mentioned, such biases increase corporate agency costs, which are and agency costs will be weakened when supervisors’ interests are more
detrimental to firm value. To avoid these costs and protect private in- aligned with firm value.
terests, these directors may act as economic actors and proactively
lessen biases or favoritism. In addition, the CEO may conduct less self-
serving activities than before. 4. Methodology
By contrast, when directors’ private interests are only slightly
aligned with firm value, their evaluations of the surname-sharing CEO 4.1. Data and sample

Our initial sample includes all firms listed on Shanghai and


1
We consider the possible reasons that explain why large shareholders con- Shenzhen Stock Exchanges from 2005 to 2015. Initially, we obtain
sent to hire directors who share the same surname with the CEO. First, share- 21,099 firm-year observations. Based on previous studies (e.g., Cao,
holders likely attach more importance to directors’ ability-related character- Lemmon, Pan, Qian, & Tian, 2019; Du, in press), we select our sample
istics (e.g., past performance, educational background, and external networks)
by using the following criteria. First, we exclude firms pertaining to
than their innate characteristics when they select directors (Gompers et al.,
banking, insurance, and other financial industries because these firms
2016). Second, as our results shown in the “The potential benefits of surname
ties” part, surname ties improve the efficiency of decision making and thus have have strikingly different financial characteristics compared with other
potential benefits for firms operating in a dynamic environment. In such an firms (344 observations). Second, we delete special and particular
environment, shareholders may focus more on managers’ quick reactions and treatment firms due to their abnormal financial conditions (717 ob-
fast decision making, which helps shareholders grasp new opportunities and servations). Third, we drop the outliers of net assets and CEO tenure,
obtain long-term returns. specifically, those whose net assets (368 observations) and CEO tenure

275
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

(294 observations) are below zero.2 Fourth, we eliminate firms with et al., 2019), we use director share to measure the degree of alignment
unavailable data (2450 observations). Finally, we obtain an unbalanced between directors’ private interests and firm value. Director share is
panel dataset of 2499 firms and 16,926 firm-year observations. The calculated as the shares owned by the directors divided by the firm’s
final sample covers 18 industries (one-digit industry code).3 Among total shares. The directors holding many firm shares are more willing to
these firms, 1248 unique firms, pertaining to 4400 firm-year observa- monitor executives than those with only a few shares.
tions, have CEO–board surname ties. Such ties exist in approximately Supervisor share. To measure the degree of alignment between su-
26% of the sample firms, with each firm having approximately 0.35 pervisors’ private interests and firm value, we measure supervisor share
directors with the same surname as the CEO. as the proportion of firm shares owned by the supervisory board.
Our data are mainly derived from the Chinese Stock Market and Research on corporate governance suggests that agents receive addi-
Accounting Research (CSMAR) database, which is widely used in pre- tional incentives to perform their monitoring duties when their private
vious studies (e.g., Cao et al., 2019; Sun, Hu, & Hillman, 2016). Spe- interests are closely aligned with firm value (Ran et al., 2015).
cifically, we collect firms’ financial and corporate governance in-
formation from CSMAR’s Corporate Governance Research Database,
4.5. Control variables
Stock Market Financial Information Database, Shareholder Research
Database, and Features of the Character Database. We also obtain
We control for a set of variables that can influence agency costs.
provincial-level data from the China Statistical Yearbook (CSY).
First, we include the following control variables at the firm level: firm
size (logarithm of total assets) and firm age (number of years since in-
4.2. Dependent variables ception). Managers are less likely to engage in self-serving activities in a
large firm because it is highly visible and exposed to intensive scrutiny
Agency costs. Agency theorists argue that executives may perform (Meznar & Nigh, 1995). Older firms can be more efficient than younger
self-serving or unethical behaviors (e.g., excessive pay and perquisite counterparts due to the effects of learning curve (Ang, Cole, & Lin,
consumption) at the expense of shareholder value, thereby increasing 2000).6 We also control for industry adjusted ROA (return on assets)
agency costs. Executives always use operating expenses, such as ad- and growth (ratio of the annual increase in sales revenues) because
vertising, selling, and administrative expenses, to “camouflage ex- profitable firms may have better monitoring mechanisms in controlling
penditures on perquisites” (Singh & Davidson, 2003, p.799). Following managers (He & Luo, 2018). The separation of ownership and control
previous studies (e.g., He & Luo, 2018; Rashid, 2015; Singh & Davidson, gives managers discretionary power to use resources based on their
2003), we measure agency costs as sales expenses and administrative preferences (Fama & Jensen, 1983). Thus, we control for separation,
expenses scaled by the total annual sales. We compute the logarithm of which is calculated as the difference value between the ownership and
agency costs to mitigate the influence of skewed distributions.4 In China, control rights of a firm’s actual controllers.
executives easily conceal their self-serving and unethical behaviors Second, we control for the characteristics of the CEO and the board.
(e.g., excessive consumption) via sales expenses and administrative A CEO’s discretionary power increases as his or her tenure lengthens or
expenses because the undeveloped audit market cannot ensure audit when he or she is also chairperson (Van Essen, Otten, & Carberry,
independence in examining company annals (Du, in press; He et al., 2015). Thus, we control for CEO tenure, which is the total number of
2017). years in position; and CEO duality, which equals “1” if the CEO and
chairperson are the same people and “0” otherwise. Similarly, the high
4.3. Independent variables level of CEO pay can be the result of a powerful CEO, who possesses
more discretionary power to allocate firms’ resources on their own in-
Surname ties. Based on Du (in press), we calculate CEO–board sur- terests that increase agency costs (Morse, Nanda, & Seru, 2011).
name ties as an indicator variable, which equals “1” if a firm’s CEO However, high compensation may motivate CEOs to align their interests
shares the same surname with (one or more) directors and “0” other- with firm performance because they are often rewarded based on firm
wise. financial performance (Hwang & Kim, 2009). We thus control for CEO
pay, which is measured as the logarithm of the CEO’s salary, bonus, and
4.4. Moderating variables long-term incentives (Cao et al., 2019; Bergstresser & Philippon, 2006;
Lee, Cho, Arthurs, & Lee, 2019). Following Bergstresser and Philippon
Shareholder monitoring. Consistent with previous studies (e.g., Jia (2006), we calculate the total value of long-term incentives (stock op-
et al., 2019; Pedersen & Thomsen, 2003), we measure shareholder tions, restricted stocks, shares, and other long-term incentives) by
monitoring by the proportion of firm shares owned by the largest multiplying the total number of these incentives with the closing stock
shareholder. As argued above, large shareholders are willing to exercise price in a given year. Politically tied managers are less likely to pursue
strong monitoring over agents’ actions.5 self-interests behavior in consideration of reputation and risk. CEO
Director share. Following prior studies (Hillman & Dalziel, 2003; Jia political ties entails that the CEO is an official of government agencies,
the National People’s Congress, or the Chinese People’s Political Con-
sultative Conference (Sun et al., 2016). In accordance with prior studies
2
Heckman two-step sample selection models showed that sample selection (Liu et al., 2015; Zona, Gomez-Mejia, & Withers, 2018), we also control
bias did not exist if we dropped these observations. for the following board characteristics that are closely associated with
3
These industries include agribusiness, mining, manufacturing, electricity,
the effectiveness of board monitoring: board size (number of board
water, oil and gas, construction, wholesale and retail, transportation, hotel and
members), board interlocks (number of external directorships), board
catering, information technology, real estate, leasing, scientific research, water,
environment and public works, residents’ services, education, health and social political ties (the number of politically tied directors divided by board
work, culture, sports and entertainment, and other industries. size), board independence (the number of independent directors divided
4
The minimum, mean, and maximum values of agency costs (before taking the by board size), and meeting attendance (logarithm of total meetings at-
logarithm) are 0.01, 0.16, and 1.58, respectively. The skewness and kurtosis of tended by independent directors).
agency costs (before taking the logarithm) are 3.9 and 29.4, respectively, which Third, previous studies demonstrate that the demographic similarity
deviate from the normal skewness (0) and kurtosis (3). Hence, it is better to take between the CEO and the board may lead to similarity attraction and
the logarithm of agency costs.
5
Our results are consistent with our arguments when we remeasure share-
6
holder monitoring by the proportion of firm shares owned by the three or five However, empirical results of Ang et al. (2000) show younger firms are
largest shareholders (Dharwadkar et al., 2008; Hartzell & Starks, 2003). more efficient, which is consistent with our results.

276
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

influence the decisions of either party (Westphal & Stern, 2007; surname ties and moderating variables. Model 6 is the full model.
Westphal & Zajac, 1995; Zhu & Westphal, 2014). Age dissimilarity is H1 posits that CEO–board surname ties are positively associated
calculated as the deviation between the CEO’s age and the board’s mean with agency costs. As shown in Model 2, the coefficient of surname ties is
age. Women are rarely part of managerial teams; hence, they tend to positive and significant (β = 0.03, p < 0.01), thus strongly supporting
classify each other into a group (Westphal & Stern, 2007). Thus, we H1. The marginal effect of surname ties is 0.03, suggesting that an in-
control for gender similarity, which is measured as the number of di- crease in surname ties by one level leads to a 3% increase in agency costs.
rectors with the same gender (i.e., female) to the CEO divided by board H2 assumes that the effect of surname ties on agency costs is weaker
size. Education similarity is computed as the number of directors with for firms with strong monitoring performed by shareholders. The in-
similar education levels to the CEO divided by board size. Function si- teraction effect of surname ties and shareholder monitoring on agency costs
milarity equals the number of directors with a similar functional back- is negative and significant in Model 3 (β = −0.23, p < 0.01). To fully
ground to the CEO divided by board size. We first collect the CEO and consider the nature of this relationship, we follow Aiken and West
directors’ biographical sketches from CSMAR and then use a number of (1991) and plot the moderating effect of shareholder monitoring on the
keywords (e.g., serve, soldier, army, navy, air force) to identify whether relationship between surname ties and agency costs in Fig. 1. The figure
the CEO and the directors have military experience (Luo, Xiang, & Zhu, illustrates that this relationship weakens as shareholder monitoring
2017). Military similarity is calculated as the number of directors with strengthens. Thus, H2 receives support.
similar military experience to the CEO divided by board size. Based on H3 assumes that the positive relationship between surname ties and
the biographical information, we calculate alumni similarity as the agency costs is weaker when directors’ interests are closely aligned with
number of directors who graduated from the same college or university firm value. The interaction effect of surname ties and director share on
as the CEO divided by board size. Finally, we include institutional de- agency costs is negative and significant in Model 4 (β = −0.11,
velopment of the province in which a firm is headquartered, which is p < 0.05). Likewise, we plot this moderating effect in Fig. 2, which
defined as the logarithm of the province’s GDP divided by its population displays that the effect of surname ties on agency costs becomes weak as
(acquired from CSY) (Marquis & Qian, 2014). director share increases. Thus, H3 is supported.
H4 posits that H1 is weaker when supervisors’ private interests are
4.6. Estimation methods more aligned with firm value. The interaction effect of surname ties and
supervisor share on agency costs is negative and significant in Model 5
Given our panel dataset, we use a firm fixed effects model to test our (β = −1.52, p < 0.05). Similarly, we plot the moderating effect of
hypotheses. This model can eliminate the potential endogeneity that supervisor share on the relationship between surname ties and agency
arises from omitted time-invariant firm characteristics. An F-test con- costs in Fig. 3, which shows that this relationship weakens as supervisor
firms that a firm fixed effects model is better than a pooled regression share strengthens. Thus, H4 is supported.
model (p = 0.00). We further perform the Hausman (1978) specifica-
tion test, which confirms that a firm fixed effects model is more ap- 6. Endogeneity and robustness tests
propriate than a random effects model (p = 0.00).
In addition, we allow a one-year lag between the dependent vari- 6.1. Propensity score matching (PSM) technique
ables and all explanatory variables. We winsorize the top and bottom
1% of all continuous variables to avoid undue effects from outliers. We use PSM technique to mitigate “sample selection bias” caused by
Specifically, we use the following model to test H1: observable factors (Dehejia & Wahba, 2002, p. 151).7 For example,
CEOs with high demographic similarity to directors likely appoint si-
Agency costsi, t
milar directors (e.g., directors who share the same surname) and affect
= 0 + 1 surname tiesi, t 1 + 2 Xi, t 1 + (year and firm fixed effects ) + agency costs (Westphal & Zajac, 1995). Following one-to-one non-re-
(1) placement matching principle, we match treated firms (firms with
CEO–board surname ties) with control firms (firms without CEO–board
where i and t denote firm and year, respectively. X is a vector of con-
surname ties) on all control variables. Finally, we obtain 4345 pairs of
trols, β is the regression coefficient, and ε is the error term. According to
treated and control firms. The differences between treated and control
H1, the coefficient of β1 is positive.
firms are insignificant (p > 0.1), indicating good matching quality
To test H2, H3, and H4, we use the following model:
(results can be requested from authors). Table 3 presents the regression
Agency costsi, t results that are based on the matched samples. As shown in Table 3, the
PSM results are consistent with those in Table 2.
= 0 + 1 surname tiesi, t 1 + 2 surname tiesi, t 1 × moderatori, t 1 +

3 Xi, t 1 + (year and firm fixed effects ) + , (2) 6.2. Instrumental variable (IV) approach
where moderator can be shareholder monitoring, supervisor share, or di-
rector share. Consistent with H2 (or H3 or H4), β2 should be negative. We adopt the IV approach to address the potential endogeneity
problem between surname ties and agency costs, especially when CEOs or
directors in firms with high agency costs may appoint demographically
5. Results
similar CEOs or directors. The results are shown in Table 4.
We use two IVs — (1) the mean of surname ties in a province (pro-
Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics and the Pearson correlations
vince surname) and (2) the mean of surname ties in an industry (industry
of all variables. Because significant correlations exist among several
surname). Province surname (or industry surname) is closely associated
variables, we compute variance inflation factors (VIFs) to investigate
with surname ties but is less likely to directly associated with agency
whether a potential multicollinearity problem exists. The maximum VIF
costs. We conduct several tests to confirm the validity of our IVs. First,
in the regression model is 1.95 (director share), and the mean VIF is
province surname (or industry surname) is positively and significantly
1.26, which is below the rule-of-thumb cutoff of 10. Hence, multi-
associated with surname ties (p < 0.01). The Kleibergen-Paap F-
collinearity is not a concern. Among 165,287 directors, 6,012 directors
share surnames with the CEO (approximately 4%).
Table 2 reports the regression results. Model 1 only includes control 7
We also used Heckman two-step sample selection model to rule out the
variables, whereas Model 2 includes the independent variable. In the potential bias that surname-sharing directors may be appointed by the CEO to
subsequent Models 3, 4, and 5, we add the interaction terms between assist his/her self-serving activities. Our results remain consistent.

277
L. Zhang, et al.

Table 1
Descriptive Statistics and Pearson Correlations (Note. * denotes statistical significant at 5% level. N = 16,926).
Variables Mean S.D. Min Median Max 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

1. Agency costs −2.11 0.77 −4.51 −2.08 0.46 1


2. Surname ties 0.26 0.44 0 0 1 0.03* 1
3. Shareholder monitoring 0.37 0.15 0.09 0.35 0.75 −0.20* 0.01 1
4. Director share 0.08 0.17 0 0 0.65 0.19* 0.10* −0.10* 1
5. Supervisor share 0.002 0.01 0 0 0.06 0.10* 0.04* −0.13* 0.42* 1
6. Firm size 21.71 1.21 18.76 21.56 25.99 −0.37* −0.03* 0.23* −0.21* −0.13* 1
7. Firm age 12.71 5.07 0 12 28 −0.03* −0.01 −0.20* −0.23* −0.14* 0.16* 1
8. ROA 0.01 0.05 −0.4 0.003 0.23 −0.09* −0.02* 0.10* 0.08* 0.06* 0.04* −0.09* 1
9. Growth 0.47 1.6 −0.95 0.11 12.37 0.01 −0.02* 0.02* −0.03* −0.02* 0 0.09* −0.01 1
10. Separation −0.05 0.08 −0.29 0 0 0.02* 0 −0.11* 0.22* 0.09* 0 −0.01 −0.02* 0.01 1
11. CEO tenure 2.42 2.26 0 1.67 10.75 0.08* 0.02* −0.06* 0.10* 0.05* 0.10* 0.17* 0.01 −0.02* 0.02* 1
12. CEO duality 0.2 0.4 0 0 1 0.14* 0.10* −0.07* 0.26* 0.11* −0.13* −0.06* 0.01 0 0.03* 0.13*
13. CEO pay 11.71 3.69 0 12.78 15 0.01 0.03* −0.11* 0.12* 0.06* 0.13* 0.15* 0.02* −0.02* 0 0.17*
14. CEO political ties 0.16 0.37 0 0 1 0.03* 0.10* −0.02* 0.10* 0.05* −0.02* −0.07* 0.04* −0.01 0.01 0.05*
15. Board size 9.08 1.85 5 9 15 −0.11* 0.01 0.02* −0.19* −0.06* 0.25* −0.04* 0.01 −0.05* 0 −0.05*
16. Board interlocks 8.57 9.24 0 6 52 −0.01 0.03* 0.06* 0.04* 0.03* 0.18* −0.05* 0.05* −0.05* −0.08* 0.11*
17. Board political ties 0.26 0.2 0 0.22 1 −0.02* 0.05* 0 0.06* 0.03* 0.01 −0.11* 0.03* 0.01 0.02* −0.07*
18. Board independence 0.36 0.05 0 0.33 0.56 0.02* 0.01 0.02* 0.12* 0.01 0.05* 0.03* −0.02* 0.03* 0.06* 0.06*
19. Meeting attendance 3.31 0.4 2.3 3.33 4.39 −0.06* 0.01 −0.03* 0.01 −0.01 0.29* 0.07* −0.05* 0.04* 0.02* −0.02*

278
20. Age dissimilarity 5.17 3.4 0.1 4.33 18 −0.01 0.08* 0.01 0.01 −0.01 0.01 −0.02* 0.01 −0.01 −0.05* −0.05*
21. Gender similarity 0.01 0.05 0 0 0.67 0.03* 0.02 −0.03* 0.05* −0.01 −0.03* 0.03* 0.01 0.03* 0.01 0.02*
22. Education similarity 0.32 0.26 0 0.3 2.2 0.05* −0.01 0.03* 0.22* 0.13* −0.04* −0.19* 0.06* −0.05* 0.02* 0.07*
23. Function similarity 0.64 0.38 0 0.67 2.5 0.02* 0.05* −0.05* 0.17* 0.09* 0.13* 0.21* −0.04* 0.02* 0.02* 0.14*
24. Alumni similarity 0.004 0.03 0 0 0.55 0.10* −0.01 −0.03* 0.11* 0.07* −0.01 −0.05* 0.01 0.01 0.02* 0.03*
25. Military similarity 0 0.01 0 0 0.33 0 −0.01 0 0.01 0.01 −0.01 −0.01 0 0 0 0.03*
26. Institutional development 10.53 0.63 8.37 10.61 11.65 0.06* 0.05* −0.03* 0.23* 0.11* 0.18* 0.24* 0 0.01 0.04* 0.28*
12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26

12. CEO duality 1


13. CEO pay 0.04* 1
14. CEO political ties 0.23* 0.01 1
15. Board size −0.16* −0.07* −0.02* 1
16. Board interlocks 0.04* 0.14* 0.03* 0.09* 1
17. Board political ties 0.04* 0.01 0.40* −0.02* 0.04* 1
18. Board independence 0.10* 0.09* 0.02* −0.36* −0.01 0.07* 1
19. Meeting attendance −0.02* 0.14* 0.02 0.28* 0.14* 0.05* 0.17* 1
20. Age dissimilarity −0.06* −0.04* 0 −0.01 0 0.06* 0 −0.04* 1
21. Gender similarity −0.02 0.02* 0.02* −0.04* −0.01 −0.01 0.02* 0 0 1
22. Education similarity 0.12* 0.04* 0.07* −0.09* 0.09* 0.15* 0.03* 0 −0.05* 0.02* 1
23. Function similarity 0.12* 0.35* 0.04* −0.14* 0.15* 0.12* 0.12* 0.16* −0.03* 0.03* 0.13* 1
24. Alumni similarity 0.06* 0.05* 0.01 −0.02* 0.04* 0.02* 0.01 0.04* −0.04* −0.01 0.13* 0.06* 1
25. Military similarity −0.01 0.01 0 0.01 0.01 0.02* 0 0 −0.02* 0.03* 0.02* 0.01 0.04* 1
26. Institutional development 0.14* 0.35* 0 −0.14* 0.22* −0.04* 0.13* 0.13* −0.03* 0.02* 0.03* 0.42* 0.07* 0.01 1
Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

Table 2
Results of the Effect of Surname Ties on Agency Costs.
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

*** *** *** ***


Surname ties H1 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Surname ties × H2 −0.23*** −0.24***
Shareholder monitoring (0.06) (0.06)
Surname ties × H3 −0.11** −0.11*
Director share (0.05) (0.06)
Surname ties × H4 −1.52** −1.04
Supervisor share (0.65) (0.75)
Shareholder monitoring −0.34*** −0.34*** −0.34*** −0.34*** −0.34*** −0.34***
(0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07)
Director share −0.04 −0.04 −0.04 −0.03 −0.04 −0.03
(0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09)
Supervisor share 0.37 0.35 0.28 0.37 0.42 0.33
(0.68) (0.68) (0.68) (0.68) (0.68) (0.69)
Firm size −0.11*** −0.11*** −0.11*** −0.11*** −0.11*** −0.11***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Firm age 0.12*** 0.12*** 0.12*** 0.12*** 0.12*** 0.12***
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
ROA −0.31*** −0.31*** −0.30*** −0.31*** −0.31*** −0.30***
(0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11)
Growth −0.01** −0.01** −0.01** −0.01** −0.01** −0.01**
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Separation 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
(0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09)
CEO tenure 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
CEO duality 0.03** 0.03** 0.03** 0.03** 0.03** 0.03**
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
CEO pay −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
CEO political ties −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01
(0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02)
Board size −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Board interlocks 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Board political ties −0.08*** −0.08*** −0.08*** −0.08*** −0.08*** −0.08***
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Board independence −0.17 −0.17 −0.18* −0.18* −0.17 −0.18*
(0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11)
Meeting attendance −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Age dissimilarity 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Gender similarity 0.34** 0.34** 0.34** 0.34** 0.34** 0.35**
(0.14) (0.14) (0.14) (0.14) (0.14) (0.14)
Education similarity −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01
(0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02)
Function similarity −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01
(0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02)
Alumni similarity −0.02 −0.02 −0.03 −0.02 −0.02 −0.03
(0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.09)
Military similarity 0.14 0.14 0.15 0.14 0.15 0.16
(0.41) (0.41) (0.41) (0.41) (0.41) (0.41)
Institutional development 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04
(0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)
Constant −0.70 −0.69 −0.68 −0.69 −0.69 −0.68
(0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50)
F 14.97*** 14.81*** 14.86*** 14.49*** 14.51*** 14.21***
Adjust R2 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80

Notes. N = 16,926. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Firm and year effects are included in all models.

statistics of 174.03 is statistically significant (p-value is far below 0.1 6.3. Robustness checks
because the Stock-Yogo weak ID test critical value in the 10% maximal
IV size is 19.93). Thus, our models are not subject to weak instrument We conduct additional tests to establish the robustness of our re-
problems. Second, the Hansen J statistics is insignificant (p = 0.22), sults. First, we perform several tests by changing the proxies for our key
which indicates that our instruments are exogenous and uncorrelated variables. We remeasure surname ties by counting the number of di-
with the error terms. In the second stage regression, Table 4 shows that rectors with the same surname as the CEO. We also remeasure agency
surname ties is still positively and significantly correlated with agency costs as the ratio of total annual sales to total assets (RATIO). A high
costs. ratio indicates a low agency cost (He & Luo, 2018; Singh & Davidson,

279
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

Table 3
Endogeneity Test Using PSM.
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

** ** ** **
Surname ties 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.03**
(0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.01)
Surname ties × −0.27*** −0.28***
Shareholder monitoring (0.09) (0.09)
Surname ties × −0.14** −0.14*
Director share (0.07) (0.08)
Surname ties × −1.49* −0.84
Supervisor share (0.88) (1.05)
Constant −0.976 −0.948 −0.971 −0.978 −0.943
(0.865) (0.864) (0.865) (0.865) (0.864)
Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F 8.92*** 8.93*** 8.87*** 8.77*** 8.74***
Adjust R2 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82

Notes. N = 8,708. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust
standard errors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, ***
Fig. 1. Moderating effect of shareholder monitoring.
p < 0.01. Firm and year fixed effects are included in all models.

Table 4
Endogeneity Test Using IV Approach.
Panel A Second-Stage Regression Model 1

Surname ties 0.18***


(0.009)
Control variables Yes
Firm and year fixed effects Yes
N 16,841
F 14.84***
R2 0.067
Adjust R2 −0.13

Panel B First-Stage Regression (firm fixed effects)


Industry surname 0.70*** (0.00)
Province surname 0.81*** (0.00)
Test of weak identification: Kleibergen-Paap F-statistics 174.03
Stock-Yogo weak ID test critical values:
10% maximal IV size 19.93
15% maximal IV size 11.59
Fig. 2. Moderating effect of director share. Test of overidentification: Hansen J statistics 1.53 (p-value = 0.22)

Notes. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust standard er-
rors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 We
use STATA’s command “xtivreg2, fe gmm robust”. Because singleton groups are
detected, 85 observations are not used.

Table 5
Results of Remeasuring Surname Ties.
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

Surname ties 0.02*** 0.02** 0.02** 0.02** 0.02**


(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Surname ties × −0.14*** −0.15***
Shareholder monitoring (0.04) (0.04)
Surname ties × −0.10*** −0.09**
Director share (0.03) (0.04)
Surname ties × −1.16*** −0.74
Supervisor share (0.42) (0.47)
Constant −0.69 −0.68 −0.68 −0.69 −0.67
(0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50)
Fig. 3. Moderating effect of supervisor share. Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F 14.75*** 14.66*** 14.50*** 14.49*** 14.13***
Adjust R2 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80
2003). These results shown in Tables 5 and 6 are highly consistent with
our arguments. Notes. N = 16,926. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust
Second, we argue that directors with the same surname as the CEO standard errors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, ***
are biased in evaluating the CEO’s competence and thus these directors p < 0.01. Firm and year fixed effects are included in all models.
pay the CEO excessive salaries and bonuses. If this argument is true,
then surname ties increases CEO pay and decreases CEO pay–- Following Cao et al. (2019), we employ four industry adjusted
performance sensitivity (Gupta & Wowak, 2017; Lee et al., 2014). variables to measure firm performance: ROA, ROS (the ratio of net in-
Boivie et al. (2011) also use an increased value for CEO pay to proxy come to total sales), Tobin’s Q (the ratio of market capitalization to total
high agency costs. assets), and stock returns (the annual change in stock prices).

280
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

Table 6 Table 8
Results of Remeasuring Agency Costs. Results of CEO-Director Pairs.
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

** ** ** *** *** *** ***


Surname ties −0.01 −0.01 −0.01* −0.01 −0.01* Surname ties 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Surname ties × −0.01 −0.00 Surname ties × −0.07*** −0.08***
Shareholder monitoring (0.03) (0.03) Shareholder (0.03) (0.03)
Surname ties × 0.06** 0.06* monitoring
Director share (0.03) (0.03) Surname ties × −0.05*** −0.05***
Surname ties × 0.35 −0.03 Director share (0.02) (0.02)
Supervisor share (0.29) (0.34) Surname ties × −0.61*** −0.46**
Constant 1.15*** 1.15*** 1.14*** 1.15*** 1.14*** Supervisor share (0.21) (0.23)
(0.30) (0.30) (0.30) (0.30) (0.30) Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Constant −0.48*** −0.48*** −0.48*** −0.48*** −0.48***
F 18.93*** 18.51*** 18.00*** 18.25*** 18.02*** (0.15) (0.15) (0.15) (0.15) (0.15)
Adjust R2 0.81 0.81 0.81 0.81 0.81 N (the number of 165,287 165,287 165,287 165,287 165,287
directors)
Notes. N = 16,926. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust F 156.24 152.18 152.05 152.04 144.41
standard errors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** Adjust R2 0.83 0.83 0.83 0.83 0.83
p < 0.01. Firm and year fixed effects are included in all models.
Notes. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust standard er-
rors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Firm
Table 7
and year fixed effects are included in all models.
Influence of Surname Ties on CEO Pay and CEO Pay–Performance Sensitivity.
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 7. Further analyses
DV CEO pay CEO pay CEO pay CEO pay CEO pay

Surname ties 0.11* 0.11* 0.11* 0.09 0.10* 7.1. Surname ties and firm performance
(0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06)
Surname ties × ROA −1.46* Given that CEO–board surname ties restrict board monitoring and
(0.88)
increase agency costs, such ties may be harmful to firm performance. As
ROA 2.80***
(0.70)
stated above, we still use the four variables (i.e., ROA, ROS, Tobin’s Q,
Surname ties × ROS −0.64** and stock returns) to measure firm performance. Consistent with our
(0.27) predictions, Models 1–2 of Table 9 show that surname ties is negatively
ROS 0.50*** and significantly associated with accounting performance (ROA and
(0.18)
ROS).
Surname ties × Tobin’s Q −0.03
(0.04)
Tobin’s Q 0.13***
7.2. Potential benefits of surname ties
(0.03)
Surname ties × Stock −0.00
returns The board of directors has dual roles: monitoring and advising
(0.00) (Adams & Ferreira, 2007; Raheja, 2005). In the context of agency costs,
Stock returns 0.00
we focus on the board’s monitoring role. Further, we test whether di-
(0.00)
Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
rectors’ surname ties influence the effectiveness of their advising. Di-
Constant −4.91 −4.91 −4.92 −6.72* −4.51 rectors who have social similarities with the CEO may perform their
(4.01) (4.01) (4.01) (4.08) (4.01) advisory role better because social similarities likely facilitate in-
N 16,926 16,926 16,926 16,926 16,926 formation sharing, reduce conflicts, and lead to a fast and timely de-
F 92.24*** 89.73*** 89.67*** 90.49*** 89.94***
cision-making process (Bernile, Bhagwat, & Yonker, 2018; Gompers
Adjust R2 0.66 0.66 0.66 0.66 0.66
et al., 2016). Given that firms can benefit from managers’ quick re-
Notes. Control variables include shareholder monitoring, director share, su- sponses and fast decision making in a dynamic or volatile environment,
pervisor share, firm size, firm age, ROA, growth, separation, CEO tenure, CEO we expect the negative effect of surname ties on firm performance to be
duality, CEO political ties, board size, board interlocks, board political ties, smaller when firms operate in a dynamic industry.8 Consistent with our
board independence, meeting attendance, age dissimilarity, gender similarity, arguments, Models 5–6 of Table 9 presents that the coefficients of the
education similarity, function similarity, military similarity, alumni similarity, interaction term (surname ties × dynamism) on ROA and ROS are
institutional development. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. * positive and significant.
p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Firm and year fixed effects are included
in all models.
7.3. Surname ties and board appointments
Accounting performance is expected to “deliver more consistent and
robust results than stock market performance” because stock market As previously argued, surname ties result in directors’ biased eva-
trading in China reflects little information and is noisy (Cao et al., 2019, luation of the CEO. We further investigate the incentives of directors
p. 2952). In line with our arguments, Table 7 shows that surname ties is that motivate them to engage in this collusive behavior, which likely
positively associated with CEO pay. The coefficient of the interaction damages their reputation in the director labor market and the reputa-
term between surname ties and accounting performance (i.e., ROA and tion of the surname-ties group. Based on Westphal and Stern (2007), we
ROS) on CEO pay is negative and significant. expect that directors may not care about such negative consequences
Finally, we construct a sample of 165,287 CEO-director pairs to
further support our argument that CEO–board surname ties increase a 8
Following Pathak, Hoskisson, and Johnson (2014), we calculate industry
firm’s agency costs. Specifically, we merge each director with the cor-
dynamism by regressing time on industry gross revenues for the previous five
responding CEO and firm-level data. As presented in Table 8, the results
consecutive years, and dividing the standard error of the regression slope
are consistent with all hypotheses. coefficient by the average value of the five-year industry revenues.

281
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

Table 9
Effects of Surname Ties and Industry Dynamism on Firm Performance.
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8
DV ROA ROS Tobin’s Q Stock returns ROA ROS Tobin’s Q Stock returns

Surname ties −0.00** −0.01** −0.01 −0.07 −0.00** −0.01** −0.01 −0.07
(0.00) (0.00) (0.02) (0.13) (0.00) (0.00) (0.02) (0.13)
Surname ties × 0.03** 0.13** 0.22 1.40
Dynamism (0.01) (0.06) (0.36) (2.44)
Dynamism 0.01 0.10** 0.06 −1.14
(0.01) (0.04) (0.26) (1.76)
Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Constant 0.19*** 0.35** 15.87*** 52.34*** 0.19*** 0.34* 15.87*** 52.63***
(0.05) (0.17) (1.13) (7.68) (0.05) (0.17) (1.13) (7.69)
Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F 21.57*** 14.47*** 78.87*** 13.85*** 20.56*** 13.99*** 74.61*** 13.12***
N 16,926 16,926 16,485 16,901 16,926 16,926 16,485 16,901
Adjust R2 0.37 0.21 0.57 0.03 0.37 0.21 0.57 0.03

Notes. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Firm and year
fixed effects are included in all models.

because directors with the same surname as the CEO can obtain addi- Table 10
tional board appointments. Effect of Surname Ties on Board Appointment and Effect of Surname Ties Based
Models 1–2 of Table 10 show that surname ties is positively and on Dialect Similarity on Agency Costs.
significantly associated with board appointment,9 and this effect be- Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
comes stronger for higher-value CEO interlock (i.e., the CEO has more DV Director Director Agency costs Agency costs
networks).10 These results suggest that the CEO helps surname-sharing appointment appointment
directors obtain additional appointments in exchange for their favor-
Surname ties 0.35*** 0.34*** 0.02*
itism.11 (0.03) (0.03) (0.01)
Surname ties × 0.04***
7.4. Surname ties based on dialect similarity CEO interlocks (0.01)
CEO interlocks 0.12***
(0.00)
As another ascribed or innate social tie, we expect that CEO–board Same-surname- 0.05***
dialect similarity strengthens the effect of surname ties on agency costs. dialect
Language is the sign or a carrier of an individual’s social identity (0.01)
(Gumperz, Drew, & Goodwin, 1982; Tong, Hong, Lee, & Chiu, 1999). Difference- −0.03
surname-
Dialect can be a particularly important dimension of cultural and social
dialect
identity due to its inheritance and immutability (Chen, Lu, & Xu, 2014). (0.02)
Drawing on social identity theory, we argue that the CEO and directors Control Yes Yes Yes Yes
may also classify one another into the same social group based on their variables
Constant 0.42 0.77 −3.57*** −3.56***
shared dialect. Hence, when directors share the same surname and
(0.67) (0.66) (0.68) (0.68)
dialect with the CEO, in-group favoritism becomes severe and agency Control Yes Yes Yes Yes
costs increase. variables
We obtain the country-level dialect data from Sun Yat-Sen F 151.06*** 189.59*** 13.04*** 12.97***
University, where Liu, Xu, and Xiao (2015) manually collected this data N (the number 165,287 165,287 9922 9922
of directors)
from the Language Atlas of China and The Great Dictionary of Chinese
Adjust R2 0.20 0.21 0.87 0.87
Dialects. Chinese can be classified into different dialects, which include
10 supergroups, 20 groups, and 105 sub-groups. China has 34 pro- Notes. Control variables are the same as those in Table 2. Robust standard er-
vinces, 294 cities, and 2876 countries. According to the dialect dataset, rors are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Firm
Chinese people from different cities (the same provinces) may speak the and year fixed effects are included in all models.
same dialect (different dialects). To identify whether directors share the
same dialect with the CEO, we first collect the birthplace of CEOs and speak the same dialect (different dialects)12 and “0” otherwise. Con-
directors from the CSMAR database and then merge them with the sistent with our arguments, Model 4 of Table 10 shows that the coef-
dialect that people speak in the place. We obtain 9922 CEO-director ficient of same-surname-dialect is positive and significant, but difference-
pairs who have birthplace information related to the city and province. surname-dialect has an insignificant coefficient.
Second, we construct same-surname-dialect (difference-surname-dialect)
that equals “1” if a CEO and a director share the same surname and
8. Discussion and conclusion

9
Board appointment is measured as the number of a director’s external di- Although corporate governance literature has long recognized the
rectorships (Zona et al., 2018). impact of acquired social ties on governance outcomes, we know little
10
CEO interlock is calculated as the number of a CEO’s external directorships about innate social ties. Such ties often accompany people throughout
(Zona et al., 2018). life, shape their social identities, and impact their interactions with
11
Another reason is likely that directors obtain higher pay. Further analysis others. Moreover, the findings regarding the relationship between
reveals that CEO-board surname ties help directors, who are also members of
top member team (TMT), receive higher compensation. A CEO is the first one to
12
evaluate other executives in TMT and determine their pay (Chin & Semadeni, Because the birthplace information related to city and province is avail-
2017). This relationship becomes strong when the CEO has greater power. The able, we can only identify whether CEOs and directors speak the same dialect
proxies for CEO power are CEO duality, CEO shareholding, and CEO tenure. belonging to the 20 groups.

282
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

social ties and governance outcomes are equivocal and contradictory. less attention to when and why the agencies are less likely to be group
To fill these gaps, this study draws on social identity theory and agency members of social ties but act as rational agents.
theory to examine (1) whether and how CEO–board surname ties in- To fill this gap, we use agency theory to consider three key gov-
fluence agency costs, and (2) the boundary conditions under which ernance tools. Our findings suggest that directors who share the same
such directors are less likely to act as group members of surname ties. surnames as the CEO are less likely to act as group members of surname
Consistent with our arguments, we find that such ties increase agency ties but as rational representatives of shareholders when facing mon-
costs. This relationship weakens when firms have strong monitoring by itoring from shareholders and supervisors or when their interests are
shareholders and when directors’ or supervisors’ interests are closely closely aligned with firm value. As such, this study provides a complete
aligned with firm value. As such, our findings indicate that directors picture of how directors perform their social and economic roles and
tend to act as social group members when they share the same surname thus influence governance outcomes. Integrating social identity theory
with the CEO. Such directors are more likely to act economically when with agency theory, we provide an example to examine the interactions
they face monitoring from shareholders or supervisors or when their between directors’ social and economic roles. Doing so helps to un-
interests are aligned with firm value. derstand when and why directors are likely to act as social actors or
Our further analyses suggest that CEO–board surname ties lower rational agents. Our findings indicate that directors tend to be socially
firm performance but have potential benefits for firms operating in a situated and constituted actors due to their surname ties. Such directors
dynamic environment. Directors with the same surname as the CEO can are also likely to act economically in the face of corporate governance
acquire additional board appointments. Such ties based on dialect si- tools.
milarity exacerbate in-group favoritism and result in increased agency Third, this study extends the literature on surname ties. Although
costs. prior literature suggests that surname ties elicit group and social
identity or in-group favoritism (Charness & Gneezy, 2008; Du, in press),
little is known about why such favoritism occurs, how to reduce fa-
8.1. Theoretical contributions
voritism behavior, and the potential benefits of surname ties. Our
findings suggest that corporate governance tools can reduce the effect
This study has several contributions to corporate governance lit-
of CEO-board surname ties. Our further analyses indicate that surname-
erature. First, this study complements and extends corporate govern-
sharing directors may show favoritism toward the CEO because they
ance literature by introducing CEO–board surname ties and examining
tend to obtain additional board appointments in the director labor
how such ties affect governance outcomes. Behavioral perspectives on
market with the help of the CEO. Further, our analyses suggest that
corporate governance have emphasized the role of socio-psychological
surname ties facilitate information sharing and accelerate the decision-
factors, such as social ties among decision makers (Gupta & Wowak,
making process, both of which bring potential benefits for firms oper-
2017; Westphal & Zajac, 2013). As such, numerous studies examine
ating in a dynamic environment. In addition to surname ties based on
how the achieved or acquired social ties between a CEO and directors
hometown relationships (Du, in press), our further analyses suggest that
influence governance outcomes (Fracassi & Tate, 2012; Hwang & Kim,
such ties based on dialect similarity can also exacerbate in-group fa-
2009). However, little attention has been given to ascribed or innate
voritism.
social ties, which have substantial implications among managers (Kish-
Gephart & Campbell, 2015). Recently, Du (in press) extends audit lit-
erature by examining how surname ties affect auditor behavior. How-
8.2. Practical and policy implications
ever, the effect of surname ties on corporate governance outcomes re-
mains unexplored. This study fills this gap by examining how
Our findings recommend that shareholders should focus on
CEO–board ties increase agency costs.
CEO–board surname ties. Shareholders delegate boards of directors to
In addition, this study adds to the literature on the determinants of
monitor executives because of imperfect information about managerial
owner-manager agency costs by taking surname ties into account. Most
behavior and contribution. However, some directors may not monitor
studies examine how formal systems, such as board structure and
executives effectively, particularly, when directors with the same sur-
managerial incentives, restrain managers from performing unethical
name as executives. Our findings suggest that CEO–board surname ties
behaviors and reduce agency costs (e.g., Rashid, 2015; Singh &
inhibit board monitoring and result in increased agency conflicts and
Davidson, 2003). Scholars have recently recognized and called for ad-
costs.
ditional studies on the role of informal systems, including social norms
Furthermore, our findings offer practical ways for shareholders and
and cultural factors (Du, Weng, Zeng, & Pei, 2017; Fidrmuc & Jacob,
policymakers to reduce the undesirable effects of CEO–board social ties.
2010). As a response to this call, we examine whether and how clan
First, our findings suggest that the undesirable effects of CEO–board
culture based on surname ties influences agency costs.
surname ties can be mitigated by the largest shareholders. However,
Second, this study contributes to behavioral governance literature
policymakers in the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC)
by identifying boundary conditions under which socially situated and
should be careful with employing this tool because high ownership
constituted agencies are likely to act economically (Hillman et al.,
concentration may lead to principal-principal agency problems (Sun
2008; Westphal & Zajac, 2013).13 To better understand the diverse
et al., 2016).
findings regarding the effect of social-psychological factors (e.g., social
Second, our findings indicate that closely aligning directors’ inter-
ties) on governance outcomes (e.g., Hwang & Kim, 2009; Gompers
ests with firm value can mitigate their biased evaluation of surname-
et al., 2016), we consider agencies’ economic rationality as a boundary
sharing CEO. Thus, to mitigate the effect of CEO–board social ties (e.g.,
condition of this relationship. Because directors act not only as group
surname ties), shareholders may consider increasing the board of di-
members of social ties but also as rational agents of owners (Hillman
rectors’ shareholdings rather than adding outside directors to the board,
et al., 2008), the limited influence of social-psychological factors can be
who are usually busy and have little power.
attributed to economic rationality. However, previous studies explored
Third, aligning supervisors’ interests with firm value weakens the
directors’ social and economic roles separately. Despite shedding va-
positive relationship between CEO–board surname ties and agency
luable insights into when agencies are more likely to act as social actors
costs, suggesting that the supervisory board can effectively monitor
(Du, in press; Westphal & Zajac, 2013), existing accounts have exerted
executives and boards of directors. To improve the effectiveness of
supervisory monitoring, policymakers in the CSRC should require firms
13
We sincerely appreciate that both reviewers inspire us to articulate this to increase supervisors’ shareholdings. For example, a supervisory
contribution. board should comprise additional shareholders’ representatives.

283
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

8.3. Generalizability, limitations, and future research the CEO as superior among the group members of surname ties is an
interesting topic to investigate.
Our findings are based on the empirical context of Chinese listed
firms, thus we must consider the generalizability of our results.
Specifically, our findings are grounded on two contextual conditions. Declaration of Competing Interest
First, underdeveloped formal systems make interpersonal ties important
in the business environment. Second, people attach importance to clan The authors declare that they have no known competing financial
culture, surnames, or Chinese culture. Therefore, we expect that our interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influ-
findings may also be supported in other Asian contexts (e.g., Korea and ence the work reported in this paper.
Singapore). As such, future research can examine whether surname ties
matter in western countries. In addition, women’s surnames change
after marriage in some western countries (e.g., the US and UK). Future Acknowledgements
research should consider the role of gender when examining surname
ties. Second, the governance tools (i.e., shareholders’ monitoring and The authors appreciate Professor Santiago Mingo and the anon-
aligning directors’ or supervisors’ interests with firm value) that we ymous reviewers for their insightful comments and suggestions. Liang
have identified are formal mechanisms. Future research can also con- Zhang and Yeyao Ren appreciate their common supervisor during un-
sider the role of informal mechanisms, such as ethical codes and cul- dergraduate period, Professor Jianzu Wu, Lanzhou University. This
tural factors (Du, 2016). Third, given that surname-sharing directors study was funded by grants from National Natural Science Foundation
tend to show biases toward the CEO, whether such directors consider of China (Grant No. 71672139; No. 71932007).

Appendix A. “One Hundred Surnames” lists (The ranking is based on the sixth national census)

Ranking 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Surname 李 陈 刘 王 张 杨 赵 黄 周 吴
Ranking 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Surname 郑 孙 胡 朱 高 林 何 郭 马 罗
Ranking 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30
Surname 梁 宋 徐 谢 韩 唐 冯 于 董 萧
Ranking 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40
Surname 程 曹 袁 邓 许 傅 沈 曾 彭 吕
Ranking 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50
Surname 苏 卢 蒋 蔡 贾 丁 魏 薛 叶 阎
Ranking 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60
Surname 余 潘 杜 戴 夏 锺 汪 田 任 姜
Ranking 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70
Surname 范 方 石 姚 谭 廖 邹 熊 金 陆
Ranking 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80
Surname 郝 孔 白 崔 康 毛 邱 秦 江 史
Ranking 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90
Surname 顾 侯 邵 孟 龙 万 段 雷 钱 汤
Ranking 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100
Surname 尹 黎 易 常 武 乔 贺 赖 龚 文

References author: A proposed solution. Chinese Journal of Integrative Medicine, 18, 243–244.
Chin, M. K., & Semadeni, M. (2017). CEO political ideologies and pay egalitarianism
within top management teams. Strategic Management Journal, 38(8), 1608–1625.
Adams, R. B., & Ferreira, D. (2007). A theory of friendly boards. The Journal of Finance, Christopher, J. (2010). Corporate governance—A multi-theoretical approach to re-
62(1), 217–250. cognizing the wider influencing forces impacting on organizations. Critical
Aiken, L. S., & West, S. G. (1991). Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions. Perspectives on Accounting, 21(8), 683–695.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Dahya, J., Karbhari, Y., Xiao, J. Z., & Yang, M. (2003). The usefulness of the supervisory
Ang, J. S., Cole, R. A., & Lin, J. W. (2000). Agency costs and ownership structure. The board report in China. Corporate governance: An international review, 11(4), 308–321.
Journal of Finance, 55(1), 81–106. Dharwadkar, R., Goranova, M., Brandes, P., & Khan, R. (2008). Institutional ownership
Ashforth, B. E., & Mael, F. (1989). Social identity theory and the organization. Academy of and monitoring effectiveness: It's not just how much but what else you own.
Management Review, 14(1), 20–39. Organization Science, 19(3), 419–440.
Bergstresser, D., & Philippon, T. (2006). CEO incentives and earnings management. Dehejia, R. H., & Wahba, S. (2002). Propensity score-matching methods for nonexperi-
Journal of Financial Economics, 80(3), 511–529. mental causal studies. Review of Economics and statistics, 84(1), 151–161.
Bernile, G., Bhagwat, V., & Yonker, S. (2018). Board diversity, firm risk, and corporate Du, X. (2016). Does Confucianism reduce board gender diversity? Firm-level evidence
policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 127(3), 588–612. from China. Journal of Business Ethics, 136(2), 399–436.
Boivie, S., Lange, D., McDonald, M. L., & Westphal, J. D. (2011). Me or we: The effects of Du, X. (2018). What’s in a surname? The effect of auditor-CEO surname sharing on fi-
CEO organizational identification on agency costs. Academy of Management Journal, nancial misstatement. Journal of Business Ethics in press.
54(3), 551–576. Du, X., Weng, J., Zeng, Q., & Pei, H. (2017). Culture, marketization, and owner-manager
Boyd, B. K., Haynes, K. T., & Zona, F. (2011). Dimensions of CEO–board relations. Journal agency costs: A case of merchant guild culture in China. Journal of Business Ethics,
of Management Studies, 48(8), 1892–1923. 143(2), 353–386.
Brewer, M. B. (1979). In-group bias in the minimal intergroup situation: A cognitive- Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. The Journal of
motivational analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 86(2), 307. Law and Economics, 26(2), 301–325.
Cao, X., Lemmon, M., Pan, X., Qian, M., & Tian, G. (2019). Political promotion, CEO Farag, H., & Mallin, C. (2016). The impact of the dual board structure and board diversity:
incentives, and the relationship between pay and performance. Management Science, Evidence from Chinese initial public offerings (IPOs). Journal of Business Ethics,
65(7), 2947–2965. 139(2), 333–349.
Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2008). What's in a name? Anonymity and social distance in Fidrmuc, J. P., & Jacob, M. (2010). Culture, agency costs, and dividends. Journal of
dictator and ultimatum games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(1), Comparative Economics, 38(3), 321–339.
29–35. Fracassi, C., & Tate, G. (2012). External networking and internal firm governance. The
Chen, Z., Lu, M., & Xu, L. (2014). Returns to dialect: Identity exposure through language Journal of Finance, 67(1), 153–194.
in the Chinese labor market. China Economic Review, 30, 27–43. Gompers, P. A., Mukharlyamov, V., & Xuan, Y. (2016). The cost of friendship. Journal of
Cheng, T. O. (2012). The continuing confusion in figuring out the surname of a Chinese Financial Economics, 119(3), 626–644.

284
L. Zhang, et al. Journal of Business Research 118 (2020) 271–285

Gumperz, J. J., Drew, P., & Goodwin, M. H. (1982). Language and social identity. Pepper, A., & Gore, J. (2015). Behavioral agency theory: New foundations for theorizing
Cambridge University Press. about executive compensation. Journal of Management, 41(4), 1045–1068.
Gupta, A., & Wowak, A. J. (2017). The elephant (or donkey) in the boardroom: How Raheja, C. G. (2005). Determinants of board size and composition: A theory of corporate
board political ideology affects CEO pay. Administrative Science Quarterly, 62(1), boards. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 40(2), 283–306.
1–30. Ramdani, D., & Witteloostuijn, A. V. (2010). The impact of board independence and CEO
Greif, A., & Tabellini, G. (2017). The clan and the corporation: Sustaining cooperation in duality on firm performance: A quantile regression analysis for Indonesia, Malaysia,
China and Europe. Journal of Comparative Economics, 45(1), 1–35. South Korea and Thailand. British Journal of Management, 21(3), 607–627.
Gymrek, M., McGuire, A. L., Golan, D., Halperin, E., & Erlich, Y. (2013). Identifying Ran, G., Fang, Q., Luo, S., & Chan, K. C. (2015). Supervisory board characteristics and
personal genomes by surname inference. Science, 339(6117), 321–324. accounting information quality: Evidence from China. International Review of
Harris, O., Karl, J. B., & Lawrence, E. (2019). CEO compensation and earnings manage- Economics & Finance, 37, 18–32.
ment: Does gender really matters? Journal of Business Research, 98, 1–14. Rashid, A. (2015). Revisiting agency theory: Evidence of board independence and agency
Hartzell, J. C., & Starks, L. T. (2003). Institutional investors and executive compensation. cost from Bangladesh. Journal of Business Ethics, 130(1), 181–198.
The Journal of Finance, 58(6), 2351–2374. Shah, B. R., Chiu, M., Amin, S., Ramani, M., Sadry, S., & Tu, J. V. (2010). Surname lists to
Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica: Journal of The identify South Asian and Chinese ethnicity from secondary data in Ontario, Canada: A
Econometric Society, 1251–1271. validation study. BMC Medical Research Methodology, 10(1), 42.
He, W., & Luo, J. H. (2018). Agency problems in firms with an even number of directors: Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of
Evidence from China. Journal of Banking & Finance, 93, 139–150. Finance, 52(2), 737–783.
He, X., Pittman, J. A., Rui, O. M., & Wu, D. (2017). Do social ties between external Singh, M., & Davidson, W. N., III (2003). Agency costs, ownership structure and corporate
auditors and audit committee members affect audit quality? The Accounting Review, governance mechanisms. Journal of Banking & Finance, 27(5), 793–816.
92(5), 61–87. Sun, P., Hu, H. W., & Hillman, A. J. (2016). The dark side of board political capital:
Hewstone, M. (1990). The ‘ultimate attribution error’? A review of the literature on in- Enabling blockholder rent appropriation. Academy of Management Journal, 59(5),
tergroup causal attribution. European Journal of Social Psychology, 20(4), 311–335. 1801–1822.
Hewstone, M., Hantzi, A., & Johnston, L. (1991). Social categorization and person Sykes, B., & Irven, C. (2000). Surnames and the Y chromosome. The American Journal of
memory: The pervasiveness of race as an organizing principle. European Journal of Human Genetics, 66(4), 1417–1419.
Social Psychology, 21(6), 517–528. Tafjel, H., & Turner, J. C. (1986). The social identity theory of intergroup behavior.
Hillman, A. J., & Dalziel, T. (2003). Boards of directors and firm performance: Integrating Psychology of Intergroup Relations, 7–24.
agency and resource dependence perspectives. Academy of Management Review, 28(3), Tong, Y. Y., Hong, Y. Y., Lee, S. L., & Chiu, C. Y. (1999). Language use as a carrier of social
383–396. identity. International Journal of Intercultural Relations, 23(2), 281–296.
Hillman, A. J., Nicholson, G., & Shropshire, C. (2008). Directors’ multiple identities, Tsui, A. S., & Farh, J. L. L. (1997). Where guanxi matters: Relational demography and
identification, and board monitoring and resource provision. Organization Science, guanxi in the Chinese context. Work and Occupations, 24(1), 56–79.
19(3), 441–456. Turner, J. C. (1987). Rediscovering the social group: A self-categorization theory (Oxford
Hoitash, U. (2011). Should independent board members with social ties to management ed.). Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.
disqualify themselves from serving on the board? Journal of Business Ethics, 99(3), Van Essen, M., Otten, J., & Carberry, E. J. (2015). Assessing managerial power theory: A
399–423. meta-analytic approach to understanding the determinants of CEO compensation.
Hwang, B. H., & Kim, S. (2009). It pays to have friends. Journal of Financial Economics, Journal of Management, 41(1), 164–202.
93(1), 138–158. Wang, Q., Wong, T. J., & Xia, L. (2008). State ownership, the institutional environment,
Jacobs, J. B. (1979). A preliminary model of particularistic ties in Chinese political alli- and auditor choice: Evidence from China. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 46(1),
ances: Kan-ch’ing and Kuan-hsi in a rural Taiwanese township. The China Quarterly, 112–134.
78, 237–273. Waters, M. C. (1989). The everyday use of surname to determine ethnic ancestry.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). The theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency Qualitative Sociology, 12(3), 303–324.
costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360. Westphal, J. D. (1999). Collaboration in the boardroom: Behavioral and performance
Jia, N., Huang, K. G., & Man Zhang, C. (2019). Public governance, corporate governance, consequences of CEO-board social ties. Academy of Management Journal, 42(1), 7–24.
and firm innovation: An examination of state-owned enterprises. Academy of Westphal, J. D., & Stern, I. (2007). Flattery will get you everywhere (especially if you are
Management Journal, 62(1), 220–247. a male Caucasian): How ingratiation, boardroom behavior, and demographic min-
Kish-Gephart, J. J., & Campbell, J. T. (2015). You don’t forget your roots: The influence of ority status affect additional board appointments at US companies. Academy of
CEO social class background on strategic risk taking. Academy of Management Journal, Management Journal, 50(2), 267–288.
58(6), 1614–1636. Westphal, J. D., & Zajac, E. J. (1995). Who shall govern? CEO/board power, demographic
Langenberg, E. A. (2007). Guanxi and business strategy: Theory and implications for multi- similarity, and new director selection. Administrative Science Quarterly, 60–83.
national companies in China. Springer Science & Business Media. Westphal, J. D., & Zajac, E. J. (2013). A behavioral theory of corporate governance:
Lee, G., Cho, S. Y., Arthurs, J., & Lee, E. K. (2019). CEO pay inequity, CEO-TMT pay gap, Explicating the mechanisms of socially situated and socially constituted agency. The
and acquisition premiums. Journal of Business Research, 98, 105–116. Academy of Management Annals, 7(1), 607–661.
Lee, J., Lee, K. J., & Nagarajan, N. J. (2014). Birds of a feather: Value implications of Xin, K. K., & Pearce, J. L. (1996). Guanxi: Connections as substitutes for formal institu-
political alignment between top management and directors. Journal of Financial tional support. Academy of Management Journal, 39(6), 1641–1658.
Economics, 112(2), 232–250. Zhu, D. H., & Westphal, J. D. (2014). How directors' prior experience with other demo-
Little, D. (2012). Explanatory autonomy and Coleman’s boat. THEORIA Revista de Teoría, graphically similar CEOs affects their appointments onto corporate boards and the
Historia y Fundamentos de la Ciencia, 27(2), 137–151. consequences for CEO compensation. Academy of Management Journal, 57(3),
Liu, Y., Chen, L., Yuan, Y., & Chen, J. (2012). A study of surnames in China through 791–813.
isonymy. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 148(3), 341–350. Zona, F., Gomez-Mejia, L. R., & Withers, M. C. (2018). Board interlocks and firm per-
Liu, Y., Miletkov, M. K., Wei, Z., & Yang, T. (2015). Board independence and firm per- formance: Toward a combined agency–resource dependence perspective. Journal of
formance in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 30, 223–244. Management, 44(2), 589–618.
Liu, Y., Xu, X., & Xiao, Z. (2015). The pattern of labor cross-dialects migration. Economic
Research Journal, 10, 134–162 (in Chinese). Liang Zhang is a Ph.D. candidate at School of Management in Xi’an Jiaotong University.
Luo, J. H., Xiang, Y., & Zhu, R. (2017). Military top executives and corporate philan- His research interests include topics related to government-firm interactions, stakeholder
thropy: Evidence from China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 34(3), 725–755. management, and corporate governance, he has published in the Management and
Maassen, G., & Van Den Bosch, F. (1999). On the Supposed Independence of Two-tier Organization Review, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, and Chinese
Boards: Formal structure and reality in the Netherlands. Corporate Governance: An Management Studies, E-mail: 13772073171@163.com
International Review, 7(1), 31–37.
Manni, F., Heeringa, W., Toupance, B., & Nerbonne, J. (2008). Do surname differences
mirror dialect variation. Human Biology, 80(1), 41–64. Zhe Zhang is a Professor at School of Management in Xi’an Jiaotong University. Her
Marquis, C., & Qian, C. (2014). Corporate social responsibility reporting in China: Symbol research interests include topics related to human resource management and corporate
or substance? Organization Science, 25(1), 127–148. social responsibility, she has published in the Human Relation, Human Resource
Meznar, M. B., & Nigh, D. (1995). Buffer or bridge? Environmental and organizational Management, and Management and Organization Review, E-mail: zhangzhe220@sina.com
determinants of public affairs activities in American firms. Academy of Management
Journal, 38(4), 975–996. Ming Jia is a Professor at School of Management in Northwestern Polytechnical
Morse, A., Nanda, V., & Seru, A. (2011). Are incentive contracts rigged by powerful CEOs? University. His research interests include topics related to corporate governance and
The Journal of Finance, 66(5), 1779–1821. corporate social responsibility, he has published in the Journal of Management Studies,
Pathak, S., Hoskisson, R. E., & Johnson, R. A. (2014). Settling up in CEO compensation: Journal of Business Research, and Journal of Business Ethics. E-mail: jiaming@nwpu.edu.cn
The impact of divestiture intensity and contextual factors in refocusing firms.
Strategic Management Journal, 35(8), 1124–1143. Yeyao Ren is a jointly training Ph.D. student at School of Management in Xi’an Jiaotong
Pedersen, T., & Thomsen, S. (2003). Ownership structure and value of the largest University and at College of Business in City University of Hong Kong. Her research in-
European firms: The importance of owner identity. Journal of Management and terests include topics related to on corporate governance, innovation, and en-
Governance, 7(1), 27–55. trepreneurship. E-mail: 18294413280@163.com
Peng, Y. (2004). Kinship networks and entrepreneurs in China’s transitional economy.
American Journal of Sociology, 109(5), 1045–1074.

285

You might also like