You are on page 1of 46

MICROECONOMICS I

Lecture 13: Cost Curves (Ch. 21)


May 29, 2023

1
Motivation
• We have looked at the behavior of a profit-maximizing firm for a given
output price 𝑝.
• Optimal production plan 𝑥1∗ , 𝑥2∗ ; 𝑦 ∗
• So where does 𝒑 come from?

• We have taken a step back and looked at cost minimization.


• Conditional factor demand functions 𝑥1∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 and 𝑥1∗ 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦 ,
which do not (directly) depend on 𝑝.
• So where does 𝒚 come from?

2
Motivation
• To understand where 𝑦 and 𝑝 come from, we need to understand
competitive markets.

• But before we can come to that, we need to think harder about the
firms‘ cost structure.

• For that, cost curves are helpful.

3
Motivating example: newspapers
• Cost structure (and, thus, cost curves) is important for understanding
what is happening in different industries

• We will take a short look at the newspaper industry as well as the digital
industry in the US

4
Paid circulation of daily newspapers in US

5
Revenues of US newspaper publishers

6
Number of US newspapers

7
Newspaper ownership concentration

8
Competing daily newspapers in the US
• What do these numbers tell us?
• Apparently, newspapers cannot simply shrink in proportion to
the market
• And/or, the tendency goes towards bigger outlets

• Why is that?
• High fixed costs, low marginal/variable costs
• Increasing fixed costs and/or decreasing marginal variable costs
over time

9
Digital industries (2010)

“The Internet has long been held up as a model for what the free market is
supposed to look like — competition in its purest form. So why does it look
increasingly like a Monopoly board? Most of the major sectors today are
controlled by one dominant company or an oligopoly. Google ‘owns’ search;
Facebook, social networking; eBay rules auctions; Apple dominates online
content delivery; Amazon, retail; and so on.”

Tim Wu: “In the grip of the Internet monopolists,” Wall Street Journal, 2010.

➢ Besides high fixed costs and low marginal costs,


there are also be important network effects.
10
Fixed and variable costs
• Fixed costs
• Costs that are associated with fixed factors and independent of the level of output (𝐹)
• Must be paid regardless of the level of output

• Quasi-fixed costs
• Costs that are associated with quasi-fixed factors and independent of the level of
output
• Must be paid only if the level of output is positive

• Sunk costs
• Irrecuperable fixed costs. Have already been incurred

• Variable costs
• Costs that vary with the level of production (𝑣𝑐 𝑦 )
• In the short run they could be the costs of using the factor labor
11
The cost function 𝑐(𝑦)
• Reminder: cost function c(𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦) is the minimum cost of producing
output level 𝑦 when factor prices are (𝑤1 , 𝑤2 ).

• In today’s lecture, we fix 𝒘𝟏 , 𝒘𝟐 → we can then write the cost function


simply as 𝐜 𝒚 .

• Our focus:
• Average costs (variable, fixed, total)
• Marginal costs
• Short vs. long run cost functions

12
Average cost
• The average cost function (AC(𝑦)) measures the cost per unit of
production.

• The average variable cost function (AVC(𝑦)) measures the variable cost
per unit of production.

• The average fixed cost function (AFC(𝑦)) measures the fixed cost per
unit of production.

13
Average fixed and variable costs

14
Fixed and variable costs

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


15
Average fixed cost curve
AFC 𝑦 = 𝐹ൗ𝑦

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


16
Average variable cost curve
𝑐𝑣 𝑦
AVC 𝑦 =
𝑦

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


17
Average total cost curve
𝐹 + 𝑐𝑣 𝑦
ATC 𝑦 = AFC 𝑦 + AVC 𝑦 =
𝑦

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


18
Average cost curves
𝐹 + 𝑐𝑣 𝑦
ATC 𝑦 = AFC 𝑦 + AVC 𝑦 =
𝑦

Figure 21.1 from Varian (2010), p. 379


19
Marginal cost function
• The marginal cost is the rate of change of variable production cost as
the output level changes

𝜕𝑐𝑣 𝑦
MC 𝑦 =
𝜕𝑦

• Remember: 𝑐 𝑦 = 𝐹 + 𝑐𝑣 𝑦

• Thus:

𝜕𝑐 𝑦 𝜕𝑐𝑣 𝑦
= = MC 𝑦
𝜕𝑦 𝜕𝑦

20
Marginal and variable cost
𝑦
𝑐𝑣 𝑦 = න MC 𝑦෤ d𝑦෤
0

21
Marginal cost and average variable cost
• How does the average variable cost change when output marginally increases?

𝑐𝑣 𝑦
𝜕AVC 𝑦 𝜕 MC 𝑦 𝑦 −𝑐𝑣 𝑦
𝑦
= =
𝜕𝑦 𝜕𝑦 𝑦2

• Thus:

< 0 if MC 𝑦 < AVC 𝑦


𝜕AVC 𝑦
൞= 0 if MC 𝑦 = AVC 𝑦
𝜕𝑦
> 0 if MC 𝑦 > AVC 𝑦

• The MC curve intersects the AVC curve from below at the AVC curve’s minimum
22
Marginal cost and average variable cost

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


23
Marginal cost and average variable cost

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


24
Marginal cost and average variable cost

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


25
Marginal cost and average total cost
• How does the average total cost change when output marginally increases?

𝐹 + 𝑐𝑣 𝑦
𝜕ATC 𝑦 𝜕 MC 𝑦 𝑦 − 𝐹 − 𝑐𝑣 𝑦
𝑦
= =
𝜕𝑦 𝜕𝑦 𝑦2

• Thus:

< 0 if MC 𝑦 < ATC 𝑦


𝜕ATC 𝑦
൞= 0 if MC 𝑦 = ATC 𝑦
𝜕𝑦
> 0 if MC 𝑦 > ATC 𝑦

• The MC curve intersects the ATC curve from below at the ATC curve’s minimum
26
Marginal cost and average total cost

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


27
Marginal cost and total cost

• The intercepts of the MC and


AVC curves coincide
• If the MC initially decrease, the
AVC initially decrease
• With strictly positive fixed cost,
the ATC initially decreases
• The MC curve passes through
the minima of the AVC and
ATC curves

28
Example I

29
Example I

c(y)

VC(y)

FC

30
Example I

MC(y)

AC(y)

AVC(y)

31
Example I
MC(y) = AVC(y)
c(y)
MC(y) = AC(y)

VC(y)

FC

32
Short run vs. long run
• In the short run:
• the amounts of some input factors are fixed
• we can have strictly positive fixed costs

• In the long run:


• the amounts of input factors are variable
• there might still be quasi-fixed costs

• Since there are more opportunities of optimizing: long-run costs (as


functions of output) must be weakly lower than short-run costs

33
Short- vs. long-run cost functions
• Long-run cost function:

𝑐 𝑦 = 𝑐𝑆 𝑦, 𝑘 𝑦

• Fix some level of output 𝑦 ∗ and define 𝑘 ∗ = 𝑘 𝑦 ∗ . Then:

𝑐 𝑦 ∗ = 𝑐𝑆 𝑦 ∗ , 𝑘 𝑦 ∗ = 𝑐𝑆 𝑦 ∗ , 𝑘 ∗

• Generally, for any output level 𝑦:

𝑐 𝑦 ≤ 𝑐𝑆 𝑦, 𝑘 ∗

34
Short- vs. long-run average cost

• The SAC curve is tangent to the LAC curve where the level of the fixed input factor
is equal to its long-run optimum (where 𝑘 ∗ = 𝑘 𝑦 , i.e., at 𝑦 ∗ ).

35
Short- vs. long-run cost functions
With continuous units of factor 2

➢ The LAC curve is the lower envelope of the SAC curves.


36
Short- vs. long-run cost functions
With discrete units of factor 2

➢ The LAC curve is the lower envelope of the SAC curves.


37
Short- vs. long-run cost functions
With discrete units of factor 2

➢ The long-run MC curve consists of the relevant segments


of the short-run MC curves
38
Cost functions and returns to scale

39
Cost functions and returns to scale

40
Cost functions and returns to scale

41
Cost functions and returns to scale

42
Cost functions and returns to scale
𝑐 𝑤1 , 𝑤2 , 𝑦
average cost =
𝑦

• Constant returns to scale: average cost is constant

• Increasing returns to scale: average cost is decreasing

• Decreasing returns to scale: average cost is increasing

43
Cost functions and returns to scale
$/output unit

AC(y)

decreasing r.t.s.

constant r.t.s.

increasing r.t.s.

y
44
Total cost functions and returns to scale

Figure 1 Figure 2 Figure 3 Figure 4

• Figure 1: decreasing returns to scale

• Figure 2: constant returns to scale

• Figure 3: increasing returns to scale

• Figure 4: increasing (𝑌 < 𝑌 ′ ), constant (𝑌 = 𝑌 ′ ), and


decreasing (𝑌 > 𝑌 ′ ) returns to scale
45
Thanks. See you next week!

46

You might also like