You are on page 1of 7

Social Innovation

Alex Nicholls, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK


J Gregory Deesy, Duke University, Durham, NC, USA
Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Abstract

Social innovation refers to the processes and outcomes that develop a novel approach to addressing a social problem or need.
Compared to commercial innovation, it poses some distinctive challenges, particularly with regard to the incentives to invest
in it, assessment of performance, and diffusion of effective innovations. Scholars began paying attention to this phenomenon
in the late twentieth century, but many open research questions remain.
The term ‘social innovation’ has had two meanings in the academic literature. In its earliest scholarly uses, primarily in
sociology, it was used to refer to the creation of new patterns of human interaction, new social structures, or new social
relations. The second focuses on innovations designed to address a social or environmental issue or to meet a specific social
market failure or need. Often, both types of innovation are combined to establish new patterns of social relations that have
positive social outcomes. As Mulgan et al. (2007) argued, social innovations are “social both in their ends and their means”
creating “new social relationships and collaborations” as well as responding to specific social needs (p. 2). This article
provides an overview of the evolving field of social innovation globally. First, it introduces the term and sets out key defi-
nitions. Next, the chapter explores the key contexts and drivers of social innovation and maps the actors who engage with it.
Following this, social innovation is located within academic theory. The next section considers some of the distinctive
challenges faced by social innovation. The concluding section makes some final observations and sets out a future research
agenda.

Introduction production, knowledge intensity and transfer, and per capita


income growth. In other words, economic factors are used as the
Innovation designed specifically to address social or environ- primary evidence in defining such waves of innovation, with
mental issues is not new. However, it is only recently that social or societal factors being subsidiary or external to the
research, deliberative practice, and the formulation of bespoke main patterns of disruptive change discerned. More recently,
policy agendas focused specifically on such ‘social innovation’ however, social innovation has been recognized as a new wave
have begun to emerge. Today, social innovation is increasingly of innovation that gives primacy to systems and processes of
seen as essential in developing the ‘clumsy solutions’ needed to change in social relations on the one hand and, on the other,
tackle today’s complex ‘wicked problems’ across the world to innovation around the conceptualization, design, and
(Mulgan et al., 2007; Murray et al., 2010; Nicholls and production of goods and services that address social and
Murdock, 2011). environmental needs and market failures. Social innovation
Mainstream analyses of the emergence of innovation at the may represent a step change compared with previous waves of
country level have often identified a series of ‘waves’ based on innovation in that it often attempts to disrupt and reconfigure
technological change, usually starting with the Industrial systems themselves rather than simply providing disruption
Revolution in the eighteenth century (Kondratiev, 1998). In within existing systems. Social innovation can be seen as the
essence, five waves of modern macroinnovation have been simultaneous production of new ideas and new social struc-
discerned so far, each associated with a particular disruptive tures and a process of recontextualization of the norms of the
technology in the Schumpeterian sense: public good, justice, and equity.
Today, social innovation cuts across all sectors of society
l The Industrial Revolution (1771–1829)
often combining the conventionally disparate logics of private,
l The Age of Steam and Railways (1829–75)
public, and civil society in new, hybrid organizations and
l The Age of Steel, Electricity, and Heavy Engineering
forms of action. For the private sector, there are two dimen-
(1875–1908)
sions of social innovation: first, the recognition that techno-
l The Age of Oil, the Automobile, and Mass Production
logical innovations fail if they are not integrated with changes
(1908–71)
in social relations within the organization and second, as a new
l The Age of Information and Telecommunications (1971–)
agenda for the role of business in society. For the state, social
These waves are usually characterized by step changes in innovation reflects an established tradition of welfare reform
financial markets, productivity growth, urbanization, mass based on increased efficiency and effectiveness. It may also
challenge the governance status quo in societies by aiming to
transform the power structures across social relations that
y
Deceased. After a long illness that he had bravely fought, Professor
allocate goods and services ineffectively or unequally. For civil
J. Gregory Dees died suddenly on 20 December 2013. With Greg’s death, society, social innovation involves both internal process of
the academic field of social entrepreneurship lost its founder and most organizational change (such as new legal forms and collabo-
respected thinker and many of us lost a dear and kind friend. He is sorely
missed but his legacy will endure forever. This article is his last completed rations) and novelty in external outputs and outcomes (such as
work. new products and services).

International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Volume 22 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.73105-9 355
356 Social Innovation

Definitions The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Devel-


opment (OECD) endorsed this definition but also acknowl-
At its simplest, social innovation represents new ideas that edged the process dimension of social innovation (2011: p. 1),
address unmet social needs (Mulgan et al., 2007). However,
beyond this, there are two broad schools of thought
concerning the definition of social innovation: new social Social innovation is distinct from economic innovation because it is
not about introducing new types of production or exploiting new
processes and new social outcomes. The first emphasizes markets in itself but is about satisfying new needs not provided by
changes in social relations and often has a focus on the market (even if markets intervene later) or creating new, more
rebalancing power disparities in society. For example, satisfactory ways of insertion in terms of giving people a place and
Mumford (2002: p. 253) noted: a role in production.

Social innovation.refers to the generation and implementation of In addition to these two metadefinitions, three types of
new ideas about how people should organize interpersonal activi- social innovation can be identified that cut across both (see
ties, or social interactions, to meet one or more common goals.
Table 1). First, there is incremental innovation in existing
goods and services to address social need more effectively or
Westley and Antadze (2010: p. 2) subsequently expanded efficiently. Second, there is institutional innovation that aims
upon this. to harness or reshape existing social and economic struc-
tures to generate new social value and outcomes. Finally,
disruptive social innovation aims at systems change via
Social innovation is a complex process of introducing new products, political action and is typically driven by social movements
processes or programs that profoundly change the basic routines, aiming to reframe issues to the benefit of otherwise disen-
resource and authority flows, or beliefs of the social system in which franchised groups.
the innovation occurs. Such successful social innovations have
durability and broad impact.
Social innovation can also be defined in terms of the level of
its action or impact from the individual to the systems. Such
levels can be mapped against the two main definitions of social
Second, social innovation can be seen as the answer to innovation focused either on new processes or on new
social market failures in the provision of vital public goods. outcomes (see Table 2).
Phills et al. (2008: p. 36) proposed that social innovation is Finally, drawing upon theory from design thinking, Murray
et al. (2010) set out the key stages of the development of
a social innovation as a nonlinear process (see Figure 1). This
A novel solution to a social problem that is more effective, efficient, model is characterized by a series of key inflection points
sustainable, or just than existing solutions and for which the value
where the development of an innovation moves first from
created accrues primarily to society as a whole rather than private
individuals. prompts and proposals to prototyping (an important part of
the design process), then to sustainability and, finally, to scale.

Table 1 Types of social innovation

Level Objective Focus Example organization (sector)

Incremental To address identified market failures more effectively: Products and services Kickstart (low-cost irrigation foot pump)
e.g., negative externalities and institutional voids Aurolab (low-cost intraocular lenses)
Afghan Institute of learning (female
education)
Institutional To reconfigure existing market structures and patterns Markets Mpesa (mobile banking)
to create new social value Institute for one world health (‘orphan’
drugs)
Cafedirect (Fair Trade)
Disruptive To change the cognitive frames of reference around Politics (social Greenpeace (environmental change)
markets and issues to alter social systems and movements) BRAC (micro-finance)
structures Tostan (human rights)

Table 2 Levels of social impact

Social process (example) Social outcome (example)

Individual Coproduction (Southwark Circle) Lost-cost health care (Aravind Eye Hospital)
Organization Wiki-production (Wikipedia) Work integration social enterprise (Greyston Bakery)
Network/movement Open source technology (Linux) Nontraditional training and education (Barefoot College)
System Microfinance (Grameen Bank) Mobile banking (MPESA)
Social Innovation 357

Social innovation doesn’t have fixed boundaries: it happens in all


sectors, public, non-profit and private. Indeed, much of the most
creative action is happening at the boundaries between sectors.

Indeed, social innovation can often be the product of trying


to resolve apparent contradictions and tensions across different
fields of action. Taken together, the three ideal-type sectors
(public, private, and civil society) can be conceptualized as
a triad represented in stability as a triangle. Between each of the
three ideal-type points lies a range of hybrid organizations that
combine elements of the ideal types in different proportions:
Figure 1 Stages of social innovation development (Reproduced from these represent social innovation as boundary-blurring activi-
Murray, R., Caulier-Grice, J., Mulgan, G., 2010. The Open Book of ties (see Figure 2). Examples include social enterprises that
Social Innovation. Young Foundation/NESTA, London). combine business logics and models with social objectives and
ownership structures (such as mutual societies and coopera-
tives) and public–private partnerships that provide new
models of welfare provision outside of, but often in tandem
Contexts with, the state (Bovaird, 2006). Various models of the ‘shadow
state’ exist in which community organizations, as well as larger
Social innovation can be seen as a response to an acceleration charities and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs),
of global crises and the so-called wicked problems character- function as a surrogate state in terms of the functions of an
ized by multiple, contradictory analyses and diagnoses elected government (e.g., the Grameen organizations in
(Rayner, 2006; Murray et al., 2010). Examples include the Bangladesh that provide education, telecommunications,
failure of modern state welfare systems (Leadbeater, 1997; solar power, health care, employment, and financial services
Mulgan, 2006a), the impacts of mass urbanization (Moulaert across the country).
et al., 2007), the failure of conventional market capitalism, The potential of social innovation across sector boundaries
increasingly urgent global resource constraints, the impacts of has also been demonstrated in practice by the emergence of
climate change, increased social breakdown, rising life social innovation ‘hubs,’ incubators, and networks such as the
expectancy and associated health and social care costs, Social Innovation Exchange that aim to bring together dispa-
growing cultural diversity within and across countries, rate players from across institutional fields to spark new
growing inequality, rising incidences of chronic long-term thinking and modeling (http://socialinnovationexchange.org).
conditions and pandemics, behavioral problems associated The value of clustering organizations working across bound-
with the ‘challenge of affluence,’ difficult transitions to adult- aries in a larger innovation ecosystem is also behind the notion
hood, and endemic reductions in individual happiness and of ‘Social Silicon Valleys’ (Mulgan, 2006b).
indices of well-being (Mulgan et al., 2007: p. 9). In this context,
wicked problems can be seen as highlighting the failure of
conventional solutions and established paradigms across all Theoretical Traditions
three conventional sectors of society: private sector market
failures that ignore pernicious externalities or marginalized The topic of innovation – like entrepreneurship – has been of
populations, public sector thinking in departmental silos, interest to scholars for many years. Schumpeter’s work in the
and an absence of focus on performance outcomes in civil first half of the twentieth century provided much of the foun-
society. dational thinking for subsequent innovation research,
An important subset of these ‘wicked problems’ concerns
public sector welfare reform in response to demographic and
societal changes combined with the economic realities of rising Civil society
welfare costs and worsening public finances. In a different
reading of the rising interest in social innovation, such action is
seen as a necessary (but not always automatic) companion to
rapid technological change and economic innovation
(Hamalainen and Heiskala, 2007). This conceptualization Formal–informal
Social enterprises Shadow state
links to notions of social innovation as a process of Multisector
Pr

reshaping of social relations to maximize productivity and


c
of

Collaborations
bli
it–

pu

economic development, often framed by the optimistic


no

te–
np

assumption that the benefits of these changes will be shared


iva
ro

Pr

equally. Common to both contexts is a series of complex and


fit

multifaceted issues that drive innovation not only in


Private sector Public–private Public sector
processes and outcomes, but also, increasingly, as boundary- Partnerships
blurring activity across the conventional sectors of society. As
Murray et al. (2010: p. 3) noted: Figure 2 Social innovation: hybridity across boundaries.
358 Social Innovation

particularly within an economic context. Of particular influ- ‘corporate social entrepreneurship’ (see also Collins’s (2005)
ence have been Schumpeter’s (1942) reimagining of Marxian reflections on the similarities between his analysis of ‘great’
notions of ‘creative destruction’ caused by systemic businesses and successful social sector organizations).)
innovation and his typology of ‘five dimensions’ of However, the distinctiveness of – as well as overlaps
innovation. The latter provided a conceptual classification between – these two streams of work has been the subject of
used in much of the subsequent analysis of innovation: specific work only in the past 10 or so years. Building upon
the analysis of the existing social innovation literature set out
1. The introduction of a new product or an improved version
by Pol and Ville (2008), two broad conceptualizations of
of an existing product.
social innovation are identified here: innovation in social
2. The introduction of an improved method of production.
relations (that typically reflects process changes) and
3. The development of a new market (or entry into an existing
innovation to address social market failures (that typically
market for a new player).
reflects outcome changes). A third strand of social innovation
4. The development of a new source of supply or supply chain.
theory, focused on macrolevel systems resilience, has also
5. The more efficient or effective organization of any industry
emerged from complexity theory.
or sector.
Schumpeter’s work was also significant in that it introduced
the construct of the entrepreneur as endogenous to economic Innovation in Social Relations
systems in contrast to conventional economic analyses that had
The largest and most well-developed body of work in this
largely cast the actor as an exogenous agent of change. Recently,
category specifically focuses on innovation that addresses
Schumpeter’s theory has been extended to include noneco-
various dimensions of changes in social relations. This litera-
nomic forms of entrepreneurship and social entrepreneurship
ture can be subdivided into five categories of scholarship, as set
explicitly and broaden the categories of innovation. Even
out below:
though Schumpeter’s work transformed the study of innova-
tion, it has also been problematic in that it has led to the rise of l Research Design Challenges: Early work on social innova-
a ‘heroic entrepreneur’ focus of analysis that can obscure the tion developed from within behavioral science with
critical operational role of collaborations, networks, and a particular interest in devising ‘social change’ approaches to
groups. (This has also been the case in social entrepreneurship tackle key, contemporary social problems, often at
research; see Nicholls (2010).) a community level (Fairweather, 1967).
The next significant contribution to innovation theory came l Changes in Social Structures: Hamalainen and Heiskala
from rural sociology and the analysis of the processes behind (2007) argued that it is social innovation processes that
the diffusion of innovation in this context. (It is not entirely ultimately determine the economic and social
clear who first coined the term ‘social innovation’ to refer to performance of nations, regions, and industrial sectors
novel solutions to social problems.) This research established and organizations: “Social innovations are changes in the
categories of adopters of innovation – ‘innovators, early cultural, normative or regulative structures.of society
adopters, early majority, late majority, and laggards’ – that are which enhance its collective power resources and improve
still used today. Faced with a series of industrial crises, stag- its economic and social performance” (2007: p. 59).
flation, and increasing overseas competition, a second wave of l Changes in Patterns of Work: Holt (1971) focused on social
modern innovation research emerged from the 1970s onward innovation within organizations, conceived of as new social
focusing on the effects of new technologies on economic patterns of employee interaction. This work was echoed in
productivity. the activities of the Netherlands Centre for Social
In tandem with a range of new theorizing concerning the Innovation 30 years later (see Pot and Vaas, 2008).
competitive strategy of firms, the 1980s saw the emergence of l Diffusion of Social Change: from within sociology, there are
innovation studies based firmly within the management analyses of the microlevel structures of innovation and
discipline and pioneered by von Hippel (1988). This work led diffusion that affect society – for example, how medical
to important subsequent contributions by Christensen (1997, innovations spread across groups of clinicians – that have
2002) and Chesbrough (2003). In the past 10 years, there been classed as social innovation. Henderson (1993) was
has been a plethora of more generalist management books interested in the relationship between social innovation
on aspects of innovation, as well as specific studies looking at and political change in terms of diffusion processes. He
a single aspect of innovation and its effects. explored how citizen movements catalyze social
As part of this proliferation of work on innovation, innovation – conceptualized as distinct from dominant
a specific social innovation literature began to emerge, most cultural norms – from fluid positions outside of conven-
notably with attempts by Drucker (1987) and Moss Kanter tional societal structures.
(1999) to blend commercial and social innovation theory l Urban Studies: There is a significant cluster of work within
together within a hybrid construct of ‘business in society.’ urban studies exploring innovative responses to social
(Moss Kanter (1999) developed a model of corporate social exclusion as social innovation under the heading of Inte-
innovation that suggested that cross-sector partnerships grated Area Development. Much of this work centers on
between not-for-profits and business offered valuable innovation within social relations in urban contexts, and as
opportunities for innovation as a setting for ‘beta testing’ new a body of work, it explores the potential of public, private,
ideas and processes. These pioneering ideas around ‘new and civil society models; interventions; and interactions. In
paradigm partnerships’ led directly to subsequent work in Moulaert et al. (2007) characterized social innovation as
Social Innovation 359

“a polymorphic constellation of counter-hegemonic produced a powerful engine of innovation in capitalist


movements and initiatives” (p. 196) engaged in active economies.
processes of social struggle and change. While some social innovations may have significant
commercial potential and benefit from this dynamic, many
(if not most) create benefits for society that are not automatically
Innovation to Address Social Market Failures
rewarded in the marketplace (Phills et al., 2008). Direct
This stream of work relates to the outcome-driven model of beneficiaries may not be able or willing to pay more than the
social innovation already discussed above and focuses on cost of the innovation, even when the social benefits would
innovation as the means by which new products and make up for such expenditure. And third-party payers may not
services can be provided to underserved market segments. At have the resources (e.g., developing country governments), or
the macrolevel, this includes the mechanisms by which new may not even know the extent of social benefits created by
markets are created in weak institutional spaces or to a given social innovation, to judge how much to pay.
address market failures. The latter is conceived of as One example is education in developing countries. Inno-
encompassing failures not only in commercial markets but vative curricula and school designs might well improve
also in public sector ‘markets,’ where the state fails to outcomes in these countries, but without attendance by chil-
provide public goods, and civil society ‘markets,’ where dren in poor families, the improved education will not have its
charities, not-for-profits, and NGOs fail to provide effective desired widespread social benefits. Attendance by children of
goods and services to their beneficiaries. Such failures the poor can be low for many reasons. For instance, with the
typically provide innovation opportunities, but can also rural poor, the parents might be just as happy with their chil-
provide challenges in terms of reconciling potentially dren working on the small farm that constitutes the family’s
competing institutional logics. only source of income and food. One solution is paying poor
families to send their children to school, tying payment
amounts and timing to absentee rates, grade completion,
Resilience Theory
graduation, and even enrollment in tertiary education
A third strand of social innovation theory has emerged recently programs. Yet, some countries can barely afford their education
focusing on its relationship with the overall sustainability and, systems now, expecting parents to pay for textbooks, uniforms,
particularly, the resilience of the larger ecosystem within which and some school fees. The idea that social innovators working
it evolves. The overall resilience of a system may be examined in this space can make sufficiently high profits to draw in
through the lens of the adaptive cycle, which is graphically competitors and create a vibrant market with rapid diffusion
represented by an infinity loop encompassing four phases: seems unlikely, no matter how effective the innovation is at
release, reorganization, exploitation, and conservation. The improving educational outcomes. Similar dynamics exist in
exploitation and conservation phases in the ‘front’ loop health care, sanitation, clean water, clean air, and so on. Social,
represent periods of growth and resource accumulation, where long-term, and intangible benefits are hard to sell to
change is routine and almost always adaptive, while the release individuals, especially those feeling the day-to-day pressures
and reorganization phases in the ‘back’ loop can represent the of poverty. Third parties, such as governments, multilateral
introduction of novelty, either transformative (radical) or agencies, major NGOs, and foundations, can help, but have
adaptive change, and renewal of the system. The back loop limits and may not be a viable long-term sustainable source
represents, therefore, a precarious moment from the point of of revenue and profitability for a particular innovation.
view of whether the system remains stable, adapting, and
learning but not transforming or whether it is pushed close to
Inception
a threshold that tips the system into a new stability domain.
The new domain may share characteristics with the old stability Motivation does not seem to be a major problem. People
domain but will have radically different feedback loops, and innovate for many reasons. Research on innovators in busi-
hence different relationships between the phases (Moore and ness illustrates a wide range of motivations, some of which
Westley, 2011). Resilience theory offers a systems-level model have nothing to do with making money. There are a variety of
of the emergence and dissemination of patterns of social motivations for innovation, of which money is only one. It is
innovation. conceivable that innovators who are driven to solve a social
problem (or by other nonpecuniary motivations) will leave
the economic dimensions of their innovations as an after-
Distinctive Challenges of Social Innovation thought. They may be more concerned with developing
something that achieves the desired social impact than with
The structure of capitalism is often credited with providing something that is economically sustainable and scalable.
a powerful incentive for the development and dissemination There are certainly many examples of social innovations that
of commercially viable innovations. As long as markets are lack sustainable and scalable business models. This is a chal-
relatively open for innovators to sell what they believe people lenge when business model innovation may be what is
will be willing to pay for, there will be an incentive to inno- needed to create a viable solution. The following are the key
vate. With sufficient profitability, the innovators can attract questions. Is there more of a disconnect between the inno-
the capital needed to expand, and other players have an vation and finding a viable business model when the moti-
incentive to copy or build on commercially successful inno- vation of the innovator is social impact rather than making
vations, contributing to their diffusion. This system has money? Are there advantages to blending these motivations?
360 Social Innovation

Evaluation you can demonstrate value to paying customers, and a profit-


able business model, there are incentives for the innovation to
In the case of commercial innovations, the market is the
be spread more quickly, especially if it is not fully protected
ultimate judge. With social innovation, an extra step is
intellectual property. Copycats, clones, and adaptations are
required to decide if the intended social impact is achieved
likely to arise as others see an opportunity to profit. In the
and not offset by other unintended and undesirable side
absence of a profitable, self-funding business model, many
effects. This kind of standard is applied to some commercial
social innovations struggle to attract the capital and operating
products where public safety is an issue (such as pharma-
funding for expansion. Consider a clinic that provides and
ceuticals), but it is crucial for social innovations since market
monitors tuberculosis treatment that can sustain itself on
success may not be at all correlated with the social impact of
government funding once that funding is in hand, but it
the innovation. Effective evaluation of performance impact is
receives funding only months after opening each new site,
a challenge for social organizations: it can be costly and
requiring philanthropic operating capital to start up each new
difficult. Moreover, there are, as yet, no commonly agreed
site. The government funding is not enough to repay a loan.
methods or standards of evaluation for social impact,
Funding is not the only barrier. Some social innovators also
although this is changing with the growing recognition of the
report difficulty finding and retaining the necessary talent to
importance of this topic by funders. This raises a series of key
scale their innovations, due to the distinctive skills required
questions:
(often a mix of business skills and technical expertise in the
l What needs to be measured to establish impact? field in which they are operating) and due to limits on
l Why should such an evaluation be conducted? Who should compensation because of limited profitability and norms
pay for it? against profiteering from the poor. High salaries in social
l For whom is the data intended? Who decides what counts as ventures that get their revenue from governments, aid
a legitimate social impact? In many cases, social innovators agencies, or from the poor themselves are frowned upon.
may have uncontroversial benefits in mind related to
improving education, health status, increasing income
Innovation Ecosystems
opportunities for the poor, and so on. However, some goals
are more controversial, such as women’s rights, reproduc- Recent literature on innovation has recognized that successful
tive health decisions, political or ethical content in educa- innovations of all kinds require an ecosystem of resource
tional curricula, and more. providers, value chain partners, and complementary players.
l Who should generate/collect the data? How participative This poses special challenges for social innovators because they
should the data collection process be? Does it need to be are often operating in situations (distressed environments) in
done by a third party for objectivity? which the surrounding ecosystems are weak. Supply chains and
l When should impact be evaluated? distribution networks may be unreliable and underresourced.
l How should performance impact best be captured? Infrastructure may be flawed or nonexistent. Institutions that
are taken for granted in well-developed markets are often
Considering each of these questions in turn may allow the
absent or weak. Sometimes social innovators have to fill
most effective and appropriate methodology for a given social
institutional voids. They cannot count on the profit incentive to
innovation to be discerned but will also typically raise difficult
induce others to fill the gaps. Institutional voids affect
issues, not least potential contradictions across different
commercial entrepreneurs as well. They are more prominent in
perspectives on the nature and scale of an impact or benefit.
social innovation because the spaces in which social entrepre-
neurs frequently choose to work have weak institutional,
economic, and social ecosystems, and because social entre-
Diffusion and Scaling Impact
preneurship is a relatively recent phenomenon with distinct
Social innovations, even those with demonstrated positive resource and capability needs that have not been well served by
impact, have a reputation for scaling slowly, despite some clear existing markets.
exceptions, such as microcredit. Innovations require change, Altogether, social innovations face some distinctive chal-
which commonly meets resistance, and without powerful lenges in that they are not incentivized or reinforced by the
financial incentives to counter the resistance or clear demand kind of market system that rewards and supports the devel-
by consumers, it is not surprising that the pace of innovation opment of profitable commercial innovations. This raises
and its spread will be comparatively slow. It may also be serious research questions regarding how societies can create
slowed by the fact that in some cases its spread depends on the institutional environment to optimize the benefits of
adoption by large bureaucratic institutions such as govern- social innovation. However, there are promising develop-
ments. Consider the example of controlling scurvy in the ments. One example is Social Impact Bonds (SIBs), which
British Navy that Rogers mentions early in his classic Diffusion represent an interesting example of how incentives can be
of Innovations. In this case, even with a compelling controlled aligned across disparate groups engaged in social innovation.
trial as early as 1601 showing how lemon juice can prevent SIBs use outcome-based payments linked to rigorous perfor-
scurvy and save many sailors’ lives, and another study in 1751, mance metrics to align the interests of external investors,
it took until 1795 before the British Navy adopted the inno- government departments (or charitable foundations), and
vation as policy and until 1865 before the British Board of service providers around optimizing interventions that
Trade adopted the innovation. Commercial innovations can address difficult social issues where success leads to significant
also diffuse slowly. However, at least on the commercial side, if social impact.
Social Innovation 361

Failure, and Unintended Consequences Applications in Organizational Science; Organizations:


All innovation is risky, and many are bound to fail. If societies Authority and Power; Social Business; Social Changes: Models;
want to promote social innovation, they have to tolerate and Social Justice and Social Inequalities.
learn from failure. Yet, there appears to be a norm of hiding
failure in the social sector. There seems to be a sense of shame
at failing to deliver intended social benefits. The innovator has Bibliography
let down society or a set of needy beneficiaries, and perhaps
a generous donor or an investor intent on achieving that social Bovaird, T., 2006. Developing new forms of partnership with the ‘market’ in
impact. To complicate matters, some failures are unknown procurement of public services. Public Administration 84 (1), 81–102.
Chesbrough, H., 2003. Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Creating and Profiting
because of lack of serious evaluations. This has caused errors to from Technology. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
be repeated and progress to be slowed. Christensen, C., 1997. The Innovator’s Dilemma. Harvard Business School Press,
Moreover, it should also be acknowledged that social Boston, MA.
innovation is not, in and of itself, always a positive thing. Christensen, C., 2002. The rules of innovation. Technology Review 105 (5), 32–38.
Clegg, S., 2010. Flows of Globalization, Keynote Address to 26th EGOS Colloquium.
Indeed, social innovation may have a ‘dark side.’ This could be
Collins, J., 2005. Good to Great and the Social Sectors: Why Business Thinking Is Not
evidenced in several ways, for example: the Answer. J. Collins, Boulder, CO.
Drucker, P., 1987. Social innovation – management’s new dimension. Long Range
l By socially divisive or destructive objectives and intentions Planning 20 (6), 29–34.
(e.g., secret societies or extreme political parties). Fairweather, G., 1967. Methods for Experimental Social Innovation. John Wiley,
l By unintended consequences that achieve negative social New York.
effects (e.g., by excluding some groups from the focus of Hamalainen, T., Heiskala, R. (Eds.), 2007. Social Innovations, Institutional Change and
Economic Performance: Making Sense of Structural Adjustment Processes in
social goods, services, or change).
Industrial Sectors, Regions and Societies, SITRA. Edward Elgar.
l In cases of operational failure, mission drift, or strategic co- Henderson, H., April, 1993. Social innovation and citizen movements. Futures,
option by an external party. 322–338.
Holt, K., 1971. Social innovations in organizations. International Studies of Manage-
ment and Organization 1 (3), 235–252.
Conclusion Kondratiev, N., 1998. The works of Nikolai D. Kondratiev. In: Samuels, W.,
Makasheva, N., Wilson, S. (Eds.), Pickering Masters. Pickering & Chatto, London.
Leadbeater, C., 1997. The Rise of the Social Entrepreneur. Demos, London.
Today, social innovation may offer vital solutions to key global Moore, M., Westley, F., 2011. Surmountable chasms: networks and social innovation
problems such as climate change, the crisis of the welfare state, for resilient systems. Ecology and Society 16 (1), 5 [online].
health pandemics and failures, social dislocation and Moss Kanter, R., May–June, 1999. From spare change to real change: the social
inequality, and educational failure. Indeed, rather than sector as beta site for business innovation. Harvard Business Review, 122–132.
Moulaert, F., Martinelli, F., Gonzalez, S., Swyngedouw, E., 2007. Introduction: social
conceptualizing social innovation as a subset of technological– innovation and governance in European cities. European Urban and Regional
economic innovation, it may be the case that the reverse is Studies 14 (3), 195–209.
now true. Mulgan, G., 2006a. The process of social innovation. Innovations: Technology,
Social innovation offers a compelling set of examples of Governance, Globalization 1 (2), 145–162.
Mulgan, G., 2006b. Social Silicon Valleys: A Manifesto for Social Innovation. Young
hybrid logics and organizational models that offer both
Foundation, London.
microlevel novelty and the potential for macrolevel systems Mulgan, G., Tucker, S., Ali, R., Sanders, B., 2007. Social Innovation: What It is, Why It
change influence. These models provide useful templates to Matters, and How It Can Be Accelerated. Skoll Centre for Social Entrepreneurship
understand how innovation and change can be operationalized Working Paper, Oxford.
in other settings, as well as generating a range of interesting Mumford, M., 2002. Social innovation: ten cases from Benjamin Franklin. Creativity
Research Journal 14 (2), 253–256.
research questions concerning how to go to scale and the Murray, R., Caulier-Grice, J., Mulgan, G., 2010. The Open Book of Social Innovation.
development of ecosystems models of social and environ- Young Foundation/NESTA, London.
mental change. Indeed, policy makers, private sector leaders, Nicholls, A., 2010. The legitimacy of social entrepreneurship: reflexive isomorphism
and civil society actors are increasingly recognizing the need for in a pre-paradigmatic field. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 34 (4),
611–633.
more fluidity across the ideal-type sectors of the Triad model
Nicholls, A., Murdock, A. (Eds.), 2011. Social Innovation: Blurring Boundaries to
shown above. Reconfigure Markets. Palgrave MacMillan, London.
However, the study of social innovation remains at an early OECD, 2011. LEED Forum on Social Innovations. Available at: http://www.oecd.org/
stage of development. There are many important research document.
topics that require further work including the measurement of Phills, J., Deiglmeier, K., Miller, D., 2008. Rediscovering social innovation. Stanford
Social Innovation Review (Fall), 34–43.
innovation outcomes and impacts; the governance and Pol, E., Ville, S., 2008. Social innovation: buzz word or enduring term. The Journal of
accountability mechanisms for organizations in change Socio-Economics 38, 878–885.
processes or systems in flux; the challenges of the ‘liability of Pot, F., Vaas, F., 2008. Social innovation, the new challenge for Europe. International
newness’ in terms of societal legitimacy, funding mechanisms, Journal of Productivity and Performance Management 57 (6), 468–473.
Rayner, S., 2006. Wicked Problems: Clumsy Solutions – Diagnoses and Prescriptions
and wider resource strategies for social innovation; and the
for Environmental Ills. Jack Beale Memorial Lecture on Global Environment.
political processes around successful social innovation. Both in Available at: http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/research/Documents.
terms of practice and research, social innovation offers rich Schumpeter, J., 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper and Row,
opportunities for future action. Cambridge, MA; New York.
von Hippel, E., 1988. The Sources of Innovation. Oxford University Press, New York.
Westley, F., Antadze, N., 2010. Making a difference: strategies for scaling social
See also: Business and Society: Social Accounting; Human innovation for greater impact. The Innovation Journal: The Public Sector Innovation
Rights and Social Work; Innovation; Network Paradigm: Journal 15 (2), 1–19.

You might also like