You are on page 1of 43

Econ growth and hist development

Income and Democracy

Acemoglu et al. (2008)

Casper Worm Hansen


UCPH, Department of Economics

1
Purpose of todays lecture
• Introduction/motivation

• Income democracy: Acemoglu et al. (2008)

• Discussion

2
Let’s start with a broad introduction
to the subject

3
Introduction
• What is the origin of the vast differences in political rights
across countries in the world

• What accounts for the divergence in political institutions?

• Is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income


than at low levels?
– May inform why efforts to impose democracy are difficult

• Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions


(property rights, etc.) or are they endogenous, primarily a
function of wealth or income?

4
Introduction
What is democracy?
• “Democracy is associated with a set of institutions such
as free and fair elections, the accountability of
politicians to the electorate, and free entry into
politics.” (Acemoglu type definition)

• Important for the empirical analysis—what is the


measurement?
• Typical, an index known as the Polity IV (V) index, as an
overall measure of democracy, is used.
• There are alternatives, as the next slide suggests.

5
Measurement of democracy

6
Measurement of democracy

7
‘The democratic divergence’

Database:
(Polity V):
Download here:
POLITY index 8
‘The democratic divergence’

9
Now to the paper:
Acemoglu et al. (2008)

10
Income and democracy
Why - in theory - should income cause the level of democracy to increase?

The Lipset or Modernization hypothesis after Lipset (APSR, 1959):

– New social groups emerge, including a middle class, which are empowered by
the spread of communication technologies and higher education standards.
This creates demand for democratic governance from a growing numbers of
citizens who eventually succeed in their demand

– Modernization as measured by:


1. industrialization,
2. urbanization,
3. Wealth (GDP per capita), and
4. education

11
Income and democracy
• Why - in theory - should income cause the
level of democracy to increase? (continued)

– Lack of a well-articulated theory?

– How to theoretical model modernization?

12
Income and democracy
Main aim (question) of the paper:

– Revisits the relationship between income per


capita and democracy:

𝑦𝑦 ↑ ⇒ 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 ↑

Causal?

13
Democracy (polity) and GDP per Capita

14
Democracy (freedom house) and GDP per
Capita

15
Income and democracy
What are the problem when attempting to apply a causal
interpretation to such correlations?

– Reverse causality
• Democracy  y

– Omitted variables
• The correlations could be due to a third factor (e.g., country-
specific, historical factors influencing both political and economic
development)

Such issues would bias the OLS estimates (the correlations) 


we cannot interpret them as causal

16
Income and democracy
At that point in time (around 2008), most
studies, which argues that y  democracy, are
based on cross-country evidence, where
omitted variables are a particular problem

– Thus, most papers are basically flawed in their


conclusions (Acemoglu et al. argue)

17
Income and democracy
Their contribution:

– Investigating the issue in a panel framework,


where country fixed effects can be excluded from
the error term

– They further apply an IV-panel approach

18
Income and democracy
Their main findings:

– Once controlling for country-fixed effects, the


correlation disappears

– No causal effect from income to democracy

– Though, the evidence suggests a positive correlation


in the very long run (the last 500 year)
• How should one interpret this?
• They argue that this is due to some critical junctures and
attempt to convince the reader by regression analysis

19
Let’s dig into the analysis

We start out by looking at some ‘preliminary


evidence’

20
Income and democracy
‘Short run’ using the polity score

21
Income and democracy
‘short run’ using freedom house

22
Income and democracy
‘long run’ using the polity score

23
Data

24
Data
The democracy data:
1. Freedom house
• Only available for the post-war period
• Ranges from 0-10

2. Polity IV database (Polity2 variable)


• Available from 1800
• Ranges from -10 to 10 (rescaled to 0 to 1)

25
Data: Polity IV (now V) measure
The Polity IV measure is based on the following
characteristics:

1) competitiveness of executive recruitment


2) openness of executive recruitment
3) constraints that exist on the executive
4) regulation of political participation
5) competitiveness of political participation

This is a continuous measure from aggregating the above,


ranging from -10 to 10.

26
Empirical strategy

27
Empirical strategy
The econometric model:

Where
– 𝑑𝑑𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is democracy in country i period t
– 𝑑𝑑𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 is democracy in former period (lagged value)
– 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 is lagged value of log GDP per capita
– 𝒙𝒙𝒙𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 is a set of time varying confounders
– 𝜇𝜇𝑡𝑡 is time fixed effects
– 𝛿𝛿𝑖𝑖 is country fixed effects
– 𝑢𝑢𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is the error term

28
Empirical strategy
– If this eq. is estimated by pooled OLS, we need to,
assume that 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑦𝑦𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 , 𝛿𝛿𝑖𝑖 = 0 and 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑦𝑦𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 , 𝑢𝑢𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 =
0
• could also be written as 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑦𝑦𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 , 𝑢𝑢𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛿𝛿𝑖𝑖 = 0

– However, when applying the FE-estimator, we’ll


“only” need to assume that 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑦𝑦𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 , 𝑢𝑢𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 0

29
Empirical strategy
– In other words, use the FE-approach, because
here we fix the time invariant stuff out of the error
term
• In principle one can apply Hausman test (RE vs FE)

30
Empirical strategy

– The presence of lagged dependent value is intended to


capture persistence in democracy

– This creates a problem  Nickell Bias or lagged dependent


variable bias (by construction 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐(𝑑𝑑𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 , 𝑢𝑢𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ) ≠ 0)

Solution:
– Arellano-Bond (diff) GMM estimation, where we use
further lagged values of democracy as instruments for
𝑑𝑑𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 .
31
Results

32
Main results 5 lags of
logged
GDP/capita
[p-value]

33
Robustness

Macroeconomics of Development
34
Further robustness

– While FE-estimation takes care of country-fixed


effects, we cannot be sure that the identifying
assumption is satisfied. That is, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 , 𝑢𝑢𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 =
0

– This assumption can be broken:


1. Reverse causality
2. Time varying omitted varibales.

35
Further robustness

– For these reasons, they use savings rates and


trade shares as time varying instruments for GDP
per capita (IV-panel approach)
• Shift-share type IV
• Other papers look at [short-run] shocks (e.g., rainfall –
Brückner and Ciccone, 2011)

– Nevertheless, they reach similar conclusions when


deploying this framework

36
What if we consider the correlation during the
last 100 years?

37
Long run: Income and democracy

Macroeconomics of Development
38
What about the very long run?

39
Income and democracy
Positive correlation, but possibly biased

40
Very long run: Income and democracy
Section VI.A (p.827) in words:
Eliminate this one
Critical juncture by further controls
(setup of Estimates
institutions, etc. ) not biased

Estimate
biased

time
1500 1850 1960 2000

41
Income and democracy

42
Income and democracy
Weak conditional relationship

43

You might also like