You are on page 1of 70

Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 1/62]

Econometric Analysis of Panel Data

William Greene
Department of Economics
University of South Florida
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 2/62]

Time Series Applications


 Panel Data Time Series Models
 Univariate Time Series
 Autocorrelation in Regression
 Vector Autoregression
 ARCH and GARCH Models
 Macroeconomic Data
 Nonstationarity and Integrated Series
 Unit Roots
 Cointegration
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 3/62]

Cross Country Growth Convergence


Solow - Swan Growth Model

Yi,t  K i,t (A i,tL i,t )1
A i,t  index of technology
K i,t  capital stock = Ii,t-1 + (1-)K i,t-1
Ii,t 1  s i Yi,t 1  Investment  Savings
L i,t  labor  (1  ni )L i,t 1
Equilibrium Model for Steady State Income
logYi,t  i  i t   i log Yi,t 1  i,t
i  (1-i )gi , gi =technological growth rate
i  "convergence" parameter; 1- i = rate of convergence to steady state
Cross country comparisons of convergence rates are the focus of study.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 4/62]

A Heterogeneous Dynamic Model

logYi,t  i  i log Yi,t 1  i x it  i,t


i
Long run effect of interest is i 
1  i

Average (over countries) effect:  or
1
(1) "Fixed Effects:" Separate regressions, then average results.
(2) Country means (over time) - can be manipulated to produce
consistent estimators of desired parameters
(3) Time series of means across countries (does not work at all)
(4) Pooled - no way to obtain consistent estimates.
(5) Mixed Fixed (Weinhold - Hsiao): Build separate i into the
equation with "fixed effects," treat i    ui as random.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 5/62]

“Fixed Effects” Approach


logYi,t  i  i log Yi,t 1  i x it  i,t
i 
i  , =
1  i 1
(1) Separate regressions;  ˆi , ˆ
ˆi ,  i

ˆ 1 N ˆ i 1 ˆi or
(2) Average estimates =   i1  Ni1
N 1 ˆi N

ˆ= (1 / N)Ni1ˆ
i
Function of averages: 
ˆi
1  (1 / N)Ni1
In each case, each term i has variance O(1/Ti )


N
Each average has variance O(1/N)  i=1
(1/N)O(1/Ti )
Expect consistency of estimates of long run effects.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 6/62]

Country Means
(Average the T observations for each i)
logYi,t  i  i log Yi,t 1  i x it  i,t
i 
i  , =
1  i 1
logYi  i  i log Yi,1  i x i  i
i contains log Yi,1
Estimates are inconsistent. But,
 tT1 log y it
logYi  ,
Ti
 tT2 log y i,t 1 y i,T  y i,0
log Yi,1   logYi   logYi   T (y) / Ti
Ti Ti
logYi  i  i log Yi,1  i x i  i  i  i (logYi   T (y) / Ti )  i x i  i
i i i i
  xi   T (y) / Ti 
1  i 1  i 1  i 1  i
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 7/62]

Country Means (cont.)


logYi  i  i log Yi,1  i x i  i
 T (y) y i,T  y i,0
 i  i (logYi   T (y) / Ti )  i x i  i   0
Ti Ti
i i i i
  xi   T (y) / Ti 
1   i 1  i 1  i 1  i
(1) Let = i0  i / (1  i ), expect i0  0 to be random
i =i /(1  i ) and i   to be random
(2) Level variable x i should be uncorrelated with change (logYi   T (y) / Ti ).
Regression of logYi on 1, x i should give consistent estimates of 0 and .
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 8/62]

Time Series of Means


(Average across countries)
log y t  (1 / N)Ni1 log y i,t
=  + (1/N)Ni1i y i,t 1  (1/N)Ni1i x i,t  (1/N)Ni1 i,t
Use =(1/N)Ni1i so i    (i  ) then
(1/N)Ni1i log y i,t 1   log y 1,t  (1/N)Ni1 (i  ) log y i,t 1
Likewise for (1/N)Ni1i x i,t
log y t     log y 1,t  x t  ( t  (1/N)Ni1 (i  ) log y i,t 1 ...)
Disturbance is correlated with the regressor. There is
no way out, and by construction no instrumental variable
that could be correlated with the regressor and not the
disturbance. This is hopeless.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 9/62]

Pooling

Essentially the same as the time series case.


OLS and GLS are inconsistent
There could be no instrument that would work
(by construction)
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 10/62]

A Mixed/Fixed Approach

log y i,t  i  Ni1idi,t log y i,t 1  i x i,t  i,t


di,t = country specific dummy variable.
Treat i and i as random, i is a 'fixed effect.'
This model can be fit consistently by OLS and
efficiently by GLS.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 11/62]

A Mixed Fixed Model Estimator

log y i,t  i  Ni1 idi,t log y i,t 1  x i,t  (w i x i,t  i,t )


i    w i
Heteroscedastic : Var[w i x i,t  i,t ]=2w x i,t
2
 2
Use two step least squares.
(1) Linear regression of logy i,t on dummy variables, dummy
variables times logy i,t-1 and x i,t .
(2) Regress squares of OLS residuals on x i,t2 and 1 to
estimate 2w and 2 .
(3) Return to (1) but now use weighted least squares.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 12/62]
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 13/62]

Nair-Reichert and Weinhold on Growth


Weinhold (1996) and Nair–Reichert and Weinhold (2001) analyzed growth and
development in a panel of 24 developing countries observed for 25 years, 1971–1995. The
model they employed was a variant of the mixed-fixed model proposed by Hsiao (1986,
2003). In their specification,

GGDPi,t = αi + γi dit GGDPi,t-1 + β1i GGDIi,t-1 + β2i GFDIi,t-1


+ β3i GEXPi,t-1 + β4 INFLi,t-1 + εi,t

GGDP = Growth rate of gross domestic product,


GGDI = Growth rate of gross domestic investment,
GFDI = Growth rate of foreign direct investment (inflows),
GEXP = Growth rate of exports of goods and services,
INFL = Inflation rate.
The constant terms and coefficients on the lagged dependent variable are country specific.
The remaining coefficients are treated as random, normally distributed, with means βk and
unrestricted variances. They are modeled as uncorrelated. The model was estimated using
a modification of the Hildreth–Houck–Swamy method
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 14/62]

ki  k   k wki
wki ~ N [0,1]

0.757
5.67
6.45
22.18
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 15/62]

Heterogeneous Dynamic Models


logYi,t  i  i log Yi,t 1  i x it  i,t
i
long run effect of interest is i 
1  i
See :
Pesaran,H., Smith,R., Im,K.," Estimating Long-Run Relationships
From Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels," Journal of Econometrics, 1995.
(Repeated with further study in Matyas and Sevestre, The
Econometrics of Panel Data.
Smith, J., notes, Applied Econometrics, Dynamic Panel Data Models,
University of Warwick.
http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/economics/staff/faculty/jennifersmith/panel/
Weinhold, D., "A Dynamic "Fixed Effects" Model for Heterogeneous
Panel Data," London School of Economics, 1999.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 16/62]

TIME SERIES DATA


Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 17/62]

Modeling an Economic
Time Series
 Observed y0, y1, …, yt,…
 What is the “sample”
 Random sampling?
 The “observation window”
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 18/62]

Estimators
 Functions of sums of observations
 Law of large numbers?
 Nonindependent observations
 What does “increasing sample size” mean?
 Asymptotic properties? (There are no finite
sample properties.)
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 19/62]

Interpreting a Time Series


 Time domain: A “process”
 y(t) = ax(t) + by(t-1) + …
 Regression like approach/interpretation
 Frequency domain: A sum of terms
 y(t) =
 j  j Cos( j t )  (t )
 Contribution of different frequencies to the observed
series.
 (“High frequency data and financial econometrics
– “frequency” is used slightly differently here.)
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 20/62]

For example,…
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 21/62]

Decomposed
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 22/62]

Studying the Frequency Domain


 Cannot identify the number of terms
 Cannot identify frequencies from the time series
 Deconstructing the variance, autocovariances
and autocorrelations
 Contributions at different frequencies
 Apparent large weights at different frequencies
 Using Fourier transforms of the data
 Does this provide “new” information about the
series?
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 23/62]

Stationary Time Series


 zt = b1yt-1 + b2yt-2 + … + bPyt-P + et
 Autocovariance: γk = Cov[yt,yt-k]
 Autocorrelation: k = γk / γ0
 Stationary series: γk depends only on k, not on t
 Weak stationarity: E[yt] is not a function of t, E[yt * yt-s] is not a
function of t or s, only of |t-s|
 Strong stationarity: The joint distribution of [yt,yt-1,…,yt-s] for any
window of length s periods, is not a function of t or s.
 A condition for weak stationarity: The smallest root of the
characteristic polynomial: 1 - b1z1 - b2z2 - … - bPzP = 0, is greater
than one.
 The unit circle
 Complex roots
 Example: yt = yt-1 + ee, 1 - z = 0 has root z = 1/ ,
| z | > 1 => |  | < 1.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 24/62]

The characteristic polynomial is 1 - 1.220175z - (-0.262198)z 2 = 0


Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 25/62]

Side Issue
How does y(t) = 1.220175 y(t-1) - 0.262198 y(t-2) + a behave?
y(t) = 1.220175 y(t-1) + a is obviously explosive.
1.220175 0.262198
How to tell: A =  
 1 0 
Smallest (possibly complex) root must be greater than 1.0.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 26/62]

Stationary (et) vs.


Nonstationary (yt) Series

1 2 .5 9

8 .0 1

3 .4 3
V a ri a b l e

-1 . 1 5

-5 . 7 3

-1 0 . 3 1
0 20 40 60 80 100
T

YT ET
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 27/62]

The Lag Operator


 Lc = c when c is a constant
 Lxt = xt-1
 L2 xt = xt-2
 LPxt + LQxt = xt-P + xt-Q
 Polynomials in L: yt = B(L)yt + et
e.g., B(L) = (1.22L – 0.262L2)
 A(L) yt = et
 Invertibility: yt = [A(L)]-1 et
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 28/62]

Inverting a Stationary Series


 yt= yt-1 + et  (1- L)yt = et
 yt = [1- L]-1 et = et + et-1 + 2et-2 + …

1
 1  (L)  (L)  (L)  ...
2 3

1  L
 Stationary series can be inverted
 Autoregressive vs. moving average form of series
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 29/62]

VECTOR
AUTOREGRESSION
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 30/62]

Vector Autoregression
The vector autoregression (VAR) model is one of the most successful, flexible,
and easy to use models for the analysis of multivariate time series. It is
a natural extension of the univariate autoregressive model to dynamic multivariate
time series. The VAR model has proven to be especially useful for
describing the dynamic behavior of economic and financial time series and
for forecasting. It often provides superior forecasts to those from univariate
time series models and elaborate theory-based simultaneous equations
models. Forecasts from VAR models are quite flexible because they can be
made conditional on the potential future paths of specified variables in the
model.
In addition to data description and forecasting, the VAR model is also
used for structural inference and policy analysis. In structural analysis, certain
assumptions about the causal structure of the data under investigation
are imposed, and the resulting causal impacts of unexpected shocks or
innovations to specified variables on the variables in the model are summarized.
These causal impacts are usually summarized with impulse response
functions and forecast error variance decompositions.
Eric Zivot: http://faculty.washington.edu/ezivot/econ584/notes/varModels.pdf
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 31/62]

VAR
y1 (t )  11 y1 (t  1)  12 y2 (t  1)  13 y3 (t  1)  1 x(t )  1 (t )
y2 (t )   21 y1 (t  1)   22 y2 (t  1)   23 y3 (t  1)   2 x(t )   2 (t )
y3 (t )   31 y1 (t  1)   32 y2 (t  1)   33 y3 (t  1)   3 x(t )   3 (t )
(In Zivot's examples,
1. Exchange rates
2. y(t)=stock returns, interest rates, indexes of industrial production,
rate of inflation
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 32/62]

VAR Formulation
y (t) = y (t-1) + x(t) + (t)
SUR with identical regressors.
Granger Causality: Nonzero off diagonal elements in 
y1 (t )  11 y1 (t  1)  12 y2 (t  1)  13 y3 (t  1)  1 x(t )  1 (t )
y2 (t )   21 y1 (t  1)   22 y2 (t  1)   23 y3 (t  1)  2 x(t )   2 (t )
y3 (t )   31 y1 (t  1)   32 y2 (t  1)   33 y3 (t  1)  3 x(t )   3 (t )
Hypothesis: y2 does not Granger cause y1: 12 =0
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 33/62]

Impulse Response
y (t) = y (t-1) + x(t) + (t)
By backward substitution or using the lag operator (text, 943)
y (t)  x(t)  x(t-1)   2 x(t-2) +... (ad infinitum)
+ (t)  (t-1)   2 (t-2) + ...
[ P must converge to 0 as P increases. Roots inside unit circle.]
Consider a one time shock (impulse) in the system,  =  2 in period t
Consider the effect of the impulse on y1 ( s ), s=t, t+1,...
Effect in period t is 0.  2 is not in the y1 equation.
 2 affects y2 in period t, which affects y1 in period t+1. Effect is 12  
In period t+2, the effect from 2 periods back is ( 2 )12  
... and so on.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 34/62]

Zivot’s Data
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 35/62]

Impulse Responses
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 36/62]

ARCH AND GARCH


MODELS
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 37/62]

GARCH Models: A Model for Time Series


with Latent Heteroscedasticity

Bollerslev/Ghysel, 1974
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 38/62]

ARCH Model
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 39/62]

GARCH Model
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 40/62]

Estimated GARCH Model


----------------------------------------------------------------------
GARCH MODEL
Dependent variable Y
Log likelihood function -1106.60788
Restricted log likelihood -1311.09637
Chi squared [ 2 d.f.] 408.97699
Significance level .00000
McFadden Pseudo R-squared .1559676
Estimation based on N = 1974, K = 4
GARCH Model, P = 1, Q = 1
Wald statistic for GARCH = 3727.503
--------+-------------------------------------------------------------
Variable| Coefficient Standard Error b/St.Er. P[|Z|>z] Mean of X
--------+-------------------------------------------------------------
|Regression parameters
Constant| -.00619 .00873 -.709 .4783
|Unconditional Variance
Alpha(0)| .01076*** .00312 3.445 .0006
|Lagged Variance Terms
Delta(1)| .80597*** .03015 26.731 .0000
|Lagged Squared Disturbance Terms
Alpha(1)| .15313*** .02732 5.605 .0000
|Equilibrium variance, a0/[1-D(1)-A(1)]
EquilVar| .26316 .59402 .443 .6577
--------+-------------------------------------------------------------
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 41/62]

MACROECONOMIC DATA
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 42/62]

Analysis of Macroeconomic Data


 Integrated series
 The problem with regressions involving nonstationary
series
 Spurious regressions
 Unit roots and misleading relationships
 Solutions to the “problem”
 Random walks and first differencing
 Removing common trends
 Cointegration: Formal solutions to regression models
involving nonstationary data
 Extending these results to panels
 Large T and small T cases.
 Parameter heterogeneity across countries
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 43/62]

Nonstationary Data
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 44/62]

Integrated Series
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 45/62]

Stationary Data
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 46/62]

Integrated Processes
 Integration of order (P) when the P’th differenced
series is stationary
 Stationary series are I(0)
 Trending series are often I(1). Then yt – yt-1 = yt is
I(0). [Most macroeconomic data series.]
 Accelerating series might be I(2). Then
(yt – yt-1)- (yt – yt-1) = 2yt is I(0)
Historic Hyperinflations
Interwar Germany, Hungary 1946, Zimbabwe 2007-2008
Money stock in hyperinflationary economies.
Price level in Venezuela in 2016 - 2017
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 47/62]

A Unit Root?
 How to test for  = 1?
 By construction: εt – εt-1 = ( - 1)εt-1 + ut
 Test for  = ( - 1) = 0 using regression?
 Variance goes to 0 faster than 1/T. Need a new
table; can’t use standard t tables.
 Dickey – Fuller tests
 This invokes the possibility of unit roots in
economic data. (Are there?)
 Nonstationary series
 Implications for conventional analysis
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 48/62]

Unit Root Tests

y t   0 y t 1    t  Ll1 l y t l   t
Different restrictions on parameters produce the model.
The parameter of interest is  0.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests:
Unit root test H0 :  < 1 vs. H1 :   1.
KPSS Tests:
Null hypothesis is stationarity. Alternative is broadly
defined as nonstationary.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 49/62]

KPSS Test-1
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 50/62]

KPSS Test-2
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 51/62]

Panel Unit Root Tests


Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 52/62]

Purchasing Power Parity


Cross country purchasing power parity hypothesis:
Ei,t  i  iPi,t  i,t
Ei,t  log of exchange rate country i with U.S.
Pi,t  log of aggregate consumer expenditure price ratio
Hypothesis of PPP is i  1.
Data on numerous countries (large N) and many periods (large T)
Standard simple regressions based on SUR model?
(See Pedroni, P., "Purchasing Power Parity Tests in Cointegrated
Panels," ReStat, Nov, 2001, p. 727 and related cited papers.)
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 53/62]

Application

“Some international evidence on price determination: a non-stationary


panel Approach,” Paul Ashworth, Joseph P. Byrne, Economic Modelling,
20, 2003, p. 809-838.

80 quarters, 13 OECD countries

log pi,t = β0 + β1log(unit labor costi,t)


+ β2 log(world price,t)
+ β3 log(intermediate goods pricei,t)
+ β4 (log-output gapi,t) + εi,t
Various tests for unit roots and cointegration
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 54/62]

Implications

 Separate analyses by country


 How to combine data and test statistics
 Cointegrating relationships across countries
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 55/62]

COINTEGRATION
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 56/62]

Cointegrated Processes:
Real DPI and Real Consumption

6967

5775

4582
Va ria b le

3390

2198

1006
0 41 82 123 164 205
Ob serv.#

REALDPI REALCONS
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 57/62]

Lack of Cointegration
Divergent Series?

2 1 .0 4

1 6 .8 5

1 2 .6 7
Va ria b le

8 .4 8

4 .3 0

.1 2
0 20 40 60 80 100
Ob serv.#

YT XT
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 58/62]

Cointegration
 X(t) and y(t) are obviously I(1)
 Looks like any linear combination of x(t) and y(t) will
also be I(1)
 Does a model y(t) = x(t) + u(t) where u(t) is I(0)
make any sense? How can u(t) be I(0)?
 In fact, there is a linear combination, [1,-] that is I(0).
 y(t) = .1*t + noise, x(t) = .2*t + noise
 y(t) and x(t) have a common trend
 y(t) and x(t) are cointegrated.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 59/62]

Cointegrated Variables?
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 60/62]

Cointegration and I(0) Residuals


2 .0 0

1 .5 0

1 .0 0

.5 0
ET

.0 0

-. 5 0

-1 . 0 0

-1 . 5 0
0 17 34 51 68 85 102
Ob serv.#
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 61/62]

Cointegrating Relationships

 Implications:
 Long run vs. short run relationships
 Problems of spurious regressions (as
usual)
 Problem for existing empirical
studies: Regressions involving
variables of different integration.
E.g., regressions of flows on stocks
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 62/62]

Money demand example


Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 63/62]

APPENDIX
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 64/62]

Autocorrelation in Regression
 Yt = b’xt + εt
 Cov(εt, εt-1) ≠ 0
 Ex. RealConst = a + bRealIncome + εt U.S. Data, quarterly, 1950-2000
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 65/62]

Autocorrelation
 How does it arise?
 What does it mean?
 Modeling approaches
 Classical – direct: corrective
 Estimation that accounts for autocorrelation
 Inference in the presence of autocorrelation
 Contemporary – structural
 Model the source
 Incorporate the time series aspect in the model
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 66/62]

Regression with Autocorrelation

 yt = xt’b + et, et = et-1 + ut


 (1- L)et = ut  et = (1- L)-1ut
 E[et] = E[ (1- L)-1ut] = (1- L)-1E[ut] = 0
 Var[et] = (1- L)-2Var[ut] = 1+ 2u2 + …
= u2/(1- 2)
 Cov[et,et-1] = Cov[et-1 + ut, et-1] =
= Cov[et-1,et-1]+Cov[ut,et-1]

=  u2/(1- 2) + 0
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 67/62]

OLS vs. GLS with Autocorrelation


 OLS
 Unbiased?
 Consistent: (Except in the presence of a lagged
dependent variable)
 Inefficient
 GLS
 Consistent and efficient
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 68/62]

+----------------------------------------------------+
| Ordinary least squares regression |
| LHS=REALCONS Mean = 2999.436 |
| Autocorrel Durbin-Watson Stat. = .0920480 |
| Rho = cor[e,e(-1)] = .9539760 |
+----------------------------------------------------+
+---------+--------------+----------------+--------+---------+----------+
|Variable | Coefficient | Standard Error |t-ratio |P[|T|>t] | Mean of X|
+---------+--------------+----------------+--------+---------+----------+
Constant -80.3547488 14.3058515 -5.617 .0000
REALDPI .92168567 .00387175 238.054 .0000 3341.47598
| Robust VC Newey-West, Periods = 10 |
Constant -80.3547488 41.7239214 -1.926 .0555
REALDPI .92168567 .01503516 61.302 .0000 3341.47598
+---------------------------------------------+
| AR(1) Model: e(t) = rho * e(t-1) + u(t) |
| Final value of Rho = .998782 |
| Iter= 6, SS= 118367.007, Log-L=-941.371914 |
| Durbin-Watson: e(t) = .002436 |
| Std. Deviation: e(t) = 490.567910 |
| Std. Deviation: u(t) = 24.206926 |
| Durbin-Watson: u(t) = 1.994957 |
| Autocorrelation: u(t) = .002521 |
| N[0,1] used for significance levels |
+---------------------------------------------+
+---------+--------------+----------------+--------+---------+----------+
|Variable | Coefficient | Standard Error |b/St.Er.|P[|Z|>z] | Mean of X|
+---------+--------------+----------------+--------+---------+----------+
Constant 1019.32680 411.177156 2.479 .0132
REALDPI .67342731 .03972593 16.952 .0000 3341.47598
RHO .99878181 .00346332 288.389 .0000
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 69/62]

Detecting Autocorrelation
 Use residuals directly (Durbin and Watson)
 d= Tt  2 (e t et 1 ) 2  / Tt 1et2   2(1  r )
 Assumes normally distributed disturbances, strictly
exogenous regressors
 Variable addition (LM test) (Godfrey)
 Based on yt = ’xt + (εt-1 + ut)
 Use regression residuals et and test  = 0 in
regression of et on xt and et-1
 Assumes consistency of b.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 70/62]

Reinterpreting Autocorrelation

Regression form
yt   ' xt  t , t  t 1  ut
Error Correction Form
yt  yt 1   '(xt  xt 1 )  ( yt 1   ' xt 1 )  ut , (    1)
 ' xt  the equilibrium
The model describes adjustment of y t to equilibrium when x t changes.

You might also like