You are on page 1of 12

Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

Corporate governance and firm performance in Russia:


an empirical study$
William Q. Judgea,*, Irina Naoumovab,1, Nadejda Koutzevolc,2
a
College of Business Administration, 411 Stokely Management Center,
University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-0545, USA
b
College of Business Administration, 408 Stokley Management Center,
University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-0545, USA
c
Department of Management, Kazan State University, Kremlevskaya 18, Kazan 420008, Russia

Abstract

Using the agency and institutional perspectives, this study advances several hypotheses about the board structure–firm
performance relationship within Russia. We tested these hypotheses using survey data. Despite a relatively small sample size,
predictions from both theoretical perspectives were supported. Specifically, we found a negative relationship between
‘‘informal’’ CEO duality and firm performance. This finding is noteworthy given the 1996 Russian Federal law which prohibits
the CEO from also serving as board chair. Also, we found that the more vigorously the firm pursues a retrenchment strategy, the
more negative the relationship between proportion of inside directors and firm performance. Overall, these findings suggest that
effective corporate governance may be essential to firm performance in Russia.
# 2003 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Russia; Firm performance; CEO duality; Board composition; Retrenchment

1. Introduction One of the ways that governance is judged to be


effective is through the systemic collection of data
Effective governance is critical to all economic by the government and the publication of this data for
transactions, especially in emerging and transitioning outside sources to review and analyze. Unfortunately,
economies (Dharwadkar, George, & Brandes, 2000). in transitioning economies, much of this data are
not collected or published, and what data that are
$
published are not reliable or valid.
An earlier version of this paper was presented at the To address this void, we collected and analyzed
Gorbachev Foundation Conference on Corporate Governance in
Transition Economies held at Northeastern University in Boston,
primary data within a globally important transition
Massachusetts in April, 2003. economy—Russia. Specifically, we administered sur-
*
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ1-865-974-1668; veys to Russian managers located in the industrial
fax: þ1-865-974-3163. heartland of Russia in December, 2002. While these
E-mail addresses: judge@utk.edu (W.Q. Judge), data were not subjected to psychometric rigor, these
nvi2000@mail.ru (I. Naoumova),
nadezhda_k@inbox.ru (N. Koutzevol).
data do provide a glimpse into the perceptions of mid-
1
Tel.: þ1-865-974-3161; fax: þ1-865-974-3163. to high-level managers who are ‘‘in the trenches’’ and
2
Tel.: þ7-8432-315-507; fax: þ7-8432-364-304. have little to gain or lose from sharing their current

1090-9516/$ – see front matter # 2003 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jwb.2003.08.023
386 W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

understanding of their board’s governance structure To strengthen our theoretical argument, however,
and overall firm performance. we also employ insights from the institutional per-
spective (North, 1990). Recent research suggests that
the institutional perspective holds great promise for
2. Theoretical development describing and explaining what happens in transition
economies because these economies by definition are
2.1. Theoretical perspectives trying to shed their former institutions and replace
them with new ones (Peng, 2003).
There is a long and developed research tradition that Although the institutional perspective is relatively
examines the relationship between boards of directors’ untested in the area of corporate governance research,
composition (i.e., proportion of insider directors) and it has shown great promise in the study of other key
leadership (i.e., CEO/chairperson roles held jointly or organizational processes within transition economies.
separately) with firm performance within Anglo- For example, Peng (2003) revealed how ‘‘deinstitu-
American firms. The notion here comes from the tionalization’’ in transition economies fundamentally
agency perspective which is concerned that the inter- impacts strategic choices at the firm level. Relatedly,
ests of owners and managers may not coincide (Jensen Newman (2000) argued that extremely high and low
& Meckling, 1976). levels of institutional change thwart organizational
The agency perspective asserts that the delegation change within transition economies. Hoskisson, Eden,
of managerial responsibilities by principals (owners) Lau, and Wright (2000) argued that institutional the-
to agents (managers) requires the presence of mechan- ory is particularly relevant for understanding strategy
isms that either align the interests of principals and formation in transition economies. Therefore, this
agents or monitors the performance of managers to study will employ the logic and insights from both
insure that they use their delegated power to generate the agency and the institutional perspectives to better
the highest possible returns for the principals. Stated understand the board structure–firm performance rela-
another way, the owners of the firm bear residual risk tionship as it exists today in transition economies.
efficiently, but only to the extent that their collective
interests are safeguarded by effective governance 2.2. Research context: Russia
mechanisms (Baysinger & Hoskinson, 1990). It has
been argued that weak governance and limited protec- Russia is one of the largest, most complex, and
tion of minority shareholders intensify the traditional dynamic of the transition economies (Litwak &
principal–agent problems in transitioning economies Sutherland, 2002). Furthermore, economic develop-
(Dharwadkar & associates, 2000). ment varies considerably from region to region with
Despite the fact that the agency perspective is Moscow the most advanced (and the most federal
central to research on the board structure–firm per- government intervention) and the rest of the country
formance relationship in developed economies, it has less advanced but quickly catching up. Finally, there is
been criticized extensively for being incomplete and/ considerable variation in corporate governance prac-
or unrealistic (Band, 1992; Cannella & Monroe, tices in Russia (Black, 2001) and there are many
1997). Nonetheless, theories on the problems asso- lessons to be learned from Russia’s ‘‘governance
ciated with the separation of ownership and control are fiascoes’’ (Fox & Heller, 2000). Thus, Russia was
central to transition economies. Indeed, recent chosen as the research focus for this empirical study
research suggests that there is not only a principal– which seeks to better understand the relationship
agent problem in transition economies, but also prin- between corporate governance and firm performance
cipal–principal (i.e., majority–minority shareholder) within transition economies.
problems (Young, Peng, Ahlstrom, & Bruton, 2002).
Since the board of directors is a primary mechanism 2.3. Board leadership and firm performance
within the corporate governance literature and agency
theory is a prevailing theory, we will cautiously build One key monitoring mechanism advocated by the
upon that literature in this study. agency perspective is the separation of the roles of
W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396 387

CEO from chairperson. When there is no separation, scenes, boardroom dealings are more important than
the CEO also serves as chairperson. This situation, formal structural arrangements.
known as ‘‘CEO duality,’’ is problematic from an This phenomena is particularly true for transition
agency perspective where the CEO chairs the group economies experimenting with Western forms of gov-
of people in charge of monitoring and evaluating the ernance and market mechanisms. We simply do not
CEO’s performance. know what the power of the CEO is to control the board
Most of the empirical studies of this relationship in transition economies; nor do we know what the
between CEO duality and firm performance have relationship between board leadership structure and
focused on large corporations within America. Dalton, firm performance is. However, North (1990) argued
Daily, Ellstrand, and Johnson (1998) performed a that when formal institutions are in flux, informal
meta-analysis of 69 samples (containing data on norms dominate personal and organizational behavior.
12,915 organizations) that examined board leadership It is logical to assume that given the enormous
structure and its relationship with firm performance. complexity of the changes in Russia and the need
They found no systematic relationship between these to separate ownership from control, ‘‘two heads may
two constructs, even after exploring moderator ana- be better than one’’ from an agency perspective needs
lyses exploring the impact of firm size and the nature to be tested. From the institutional perspective, it is
of the financial performance indicator (e.g., account- reasonable to predict that informal norms will take
ing versus market-based measures). precedence over formal structures. Anecdotal evi-
In a more recent and separate study, Rhoades, dence, agency theory, and institutional theory suggest
Rechner, and Sundaramurthy (2001) performed a that when the CEO also ‘‘informally’’ controls the
meta-analysis of 22 samples (containing data on board for firms in transition economies, firm perfor-
5,751 companies) and found a weak, but significant mance will likely suffer. As discussed previously, even
relationship between board leadership structure and when the CEO and chairperson roles are formally
firm performance. In sum, even the meta-analyses are separated, the CEO sometimes still controls the board
equivocal on the relationship between board leader- through informal means, what we refer to as ‘‘informal
ship and firm performance within American firms. CEO duality.’’ This suggests the following hypothesis:
Nonetheless, there have been some limited empiri-
cal studies of non-American boards suggesting that Hypothesis 1: Informal CEO duality will be nega-
these boards are structured and function quite differ- tively related to firm performance within the Russian
ently from their American counterparts. For example, economy.
Dalton and Kesner (1987) found that CEO duality is
most common in the fifty largest firms in the USA 2.4. Board composition and firm performance
(82%); it is less common in the fifty largest firms in the
UK (30%), and least common in the largest Japanese A second common monitoring mechanism advo-
firms (11%). cated by the agency perspective is a board composed
Demb and Neubauer (1992) argue that two-tier of a majority of independent directors. These non-
boards prevalent in Western European nations are executive or ‘‘outside’’ directors are believed to provide
theoretically more independent than Anglo-American superior benefits to the firm as a result of their inde-
one-tier boards. However, Massan and Van den Bosch pendence from firm management. Under this organiza-
(1999) report in their study of 50 large Dutch firms, tional design, conflicts of interest can be avoided and
that Dutch directors by-pass formal structures by executive leaders can be evaluated more objectively.
means of informal and semi-formal arrangements In their recent meta-analysis of the relationship
to avoid true board independence from execu- between board composition and firm performance,
tive directors. An institutional perspective suggests Dalton and associates (1998) reviewed 54 empirical
that the board leadership structure outside of the studies (159 samples, n ¼ 40,160). Once again, they
USA might be more varied and, hence, may have a found no systematic relationship between these two
different relationship with firm performance. This constructs studied within large American firms. More
perspective also suggests that informal behind the recently, Rhoades and associates (2001) examined 59
388 W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

published and unpublished empirical studies (37 sam- much the board actually contributes to or hinders
ples, n ¼ 7,644). They found a small, but significant MOL’s performance (Corporate Governance, 1998).
negative relationship between proportion of insiders In sum, agency theory predicts that an inherent
on the board and firm performance. More specifically, conflict of interest is present when insiders dominate
board composition explained less than 1% of the the board’s composition and as a result, firm perfor-
variance in firm performance in large American firms. mance is likely to suffer. Furthermore, from an insti-
Nonetheless, firms outside of the USA are com- tutional perspective, insider directors are more likely
posed of different individuals and have different than outside directors to resist change due to institu-
institutional expectations than American boards, tional inertia. This suggests the following hypothesis:
and this institutional context may lead to a different
relationship with firm performance. For example, in Hypothesis 2: The board’s proportion of inside direc-
their study of the fifty largest firms in USA, UK, and tors will be negatively related to firm performance
Japan, Dalton and Kesner (1987) found that the within the Russian economy.
proportion of insiders of boards varied significantly
between these three countries (30%, 34%, and 49%, 2.5. Moderating influence of strategic decision
respectively). The institutional context and make-up context
of corporate boards vary considerably around the
world. In their meta-analysis of board leadership structure
Regardless of board composition, non-executive and firm performance, Rhoades, Rechner and Saun-
directors may or may not function independently of daramurthy (2000) argued that decision context was a
executive management in non-US companies. For clear moderator of the board structure–firm perfor-
example, Clifford and Evans (1997) found that even mance relationship. Specifically, they found that the
though Australian boards are composed of a majority relationship between board leadership structure and
of non-executive directors, 35% of those non-execu- firm performance was different when certain compen-
tive directors were involved with financial transactions sation arrangements and anti-takeover situations were
which potentially threaten their independence. They considered. They encourage future researchers to
conclude that a combination of insider and affiliated examine the contingent nature of these relationships
outside directors would constitute a majority of board in other situations, such as restructuring situations
members in almost all Australian firms. versus growth situations.
Within developing and transition countries, board This study refines and extends previous research by
composition and functioning is particularly important examining the contingent impact of the strategic deci-
for bringing in badly needed foreign direct investment sion context on board structure and firm performance.
and managing scarce domestic investment wisely and One way to characterize strategic decision context is by
efficiently (Rueda-Sabater, 2000). For example, Mal- considering the firm’s grand strategy. Grand strategy
lin and Jelic (2000) report that Hungary has pushed the denotes an overall strategy for achieving a firm’s major
farthest and fastest in corporate restructuring and goals. The focus is on the entire firm’s goals rather than
adoption of internationally applauded corporate board those of a single division or unit (Glueck, 1980). The
structures as compared to Poland and the Czech four types of grand strategy are (1) stability, (2) internal
Republic, but all three countries are struggling to growth, (3) external acquisitive growth, and (4)
resurrect their banking systems admidst a plethora retrenchment. Several previous studies have found that
of non-performing loans. grand strategy moderates the relationship between
Gillies, Leimann, and Peterson (2002) hold up distinctive competencies and firm performance (e.g.,
Estonia as a relatively successful transition economy, Hitt & Ireland, 1985; Hitt, Ireland, & Stadter, 1982) as
and they point to a relatively corruption-free corporate well as prior performance and enterprise strategy scope
governance system for overseeing that process. In the (e.g., Judge & Krishnan, 1994).
well performing Hungarian oil company known as Of the four grand strategies, the retrenchment strat-
MOL, seven of the eleven board members are non- egy is the one that is most relevant to proper board
executive directors. However, little is known just how functioning within transition economies. Because
W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396 389

these economies are quickly trying to restructure to avoid the painful cost reductions that are necessary
existing organizations to become globally competi- to be globally competitive.
tive, many institutional practices that were common- In light of the communist legacy where the top
place in a centralized economy must be eliminated or leaders were often unchallenged in their directives and
revised (Hoskisson and associates, 2000; Peng, 2003). frequently self-serving in their motives, we expect that
Furthermore, previous research in Western organiza- firms pursuing the retrenchment strategy within Rus-
tions has shown that the when a firm is retrenching, sian firms to operate similarly. Indeed, numerous
firm performance is usually declining and firm survi- examples of governance dysfunction have been docu-
val is often in question. Retrenchment is typically mented in Russian enterprises (e.g., Fox & Heller,
achieved through cost or asset reductions, or both, and 2000). Furthermore, the more aggressively the firm
these actions really test the officers and directors of the retrenches without outsider checks and balances, the
firm (Robbins & Pearce, 1992). less likely that the retrenchment activity will lead
More specifically, as organizations restructure or to superior firm performance (e.g., Black, 2001).
retrench, they often experience dysfunctional beha- This combined theory and research suggest the fol-
vior. For example, Cameron, Whetton, and Kim lowing moderated relationships within retrenchment
(1987) found that organizational decision making situations:
often becomes more centralized, and as a result, turf
protection and competitive behavior within the orga- Hypothesis 3: The greater the emphasis placed on
nization all increases. In addition, retrenchment often retrenchment, informal CEO duality will be more
causes individuals to respond to the threat of down- negatively related to firm performance in the Russian
sizing through more rigid behavior and restriction of economy.
information flow (Sutton & D’Aunno, 1989). Typi-
cally, retrenchment leads to the disempowering and Hypothesis 4: The greater the emphasis placed on
downsizing of middle management and frontline retrenchment, the proportion of inside directors will be
workers (Krau, 1995). Most pertinent to this study, more negatively related to firm performance in the
the final arbiter of successful retrenchment decisions Russian economy.
is the board of directors (Johnson, Hoskisson, & Hitt,
1993).
Once again, not much is known about how the 3. Methodology
retrenchment strategy is addressed by boards in transi-
tion economies. Using the agency and strategic change 3.1. Research design
perspectives, Filototchev, Buck, and Zhukov (2002)
found that outside shareholding failed to effectively In December, 2002, surveys were personally dis-
counterbalance managerial opportunism when faced tributed to 116 Russian managers from the three
with retrenchment situations. Furthermore, manage- centrally located industrial regions of Russia (e.g.,
ment ownership was negatively related to extent of Tartarstan, Bashkortostan and Moscow regions). This
retrenchment, counter to the agency perspective but was a convenience sample of Russian managers inter-
consistent with the institutional perspective. ested in or already attending the Federal Program of
Anecdotal evidence suggests that organizational Retraining Managers (FPRM). FPRM was launched in
dysfunction is as prevalent in retrenching firms within 1997 by Presidential decree during the Yeltsin admin-
transition economies as it is in developed economies. istration. Its aim was to increase the quality of man-
Crow (1998) indicated that substantial retrenchment agement expertise throughout Russia to help its
activity was only pursued by the Russian oil industry competitiveness in the global economy. Its network
when faced with the shock of the 1998 Asian financial consists of the Secretariat in Moscow and 80 Regional
crisis and that this activity was producing mixed commissions and it is supported by a consortium of 16
results. Furthermore, Horvath and Zsamboki (2000) foreign nations. The program is open, competitive,
reported that when Hungarian banks started to and free of charge for managers. The State pays for all
retrench due to foreign competition, they have tended academic costs, and local governments and sponsoring
390 W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

firms cover the student’s costs. The program is adver- of their boardroom dynamics in order to complete the
tised through a website (www.informika.ru), as well as survey. For this sub-sample, the average respondent
newspaper and television advertising. was 30.7 years old and had been working for their
The primary criteria for selecting managers to current firm for 6.2 years. The government had an
participate in FPRM are (1) current involvement with ownership stake in only 10 of the 45 firms (22%)
a viable business, (2) within the age range of 25–40 studied. Furthermore, the average firm age was 27.8,
years old, (3) language proficiency in one of the 16 but firms ranged in age from 5 to 103 years old.
affiliated nations as demonstrated by a written exam- Regarding board structure and functioning, the
ination, and (4) openness to new ideas as demonstrated average board size was 9.6 members and the average
by responses to a psychological instrument coupled proportion of inside directors was 51%. Notably,
with an interview by a panel of psychologists. respondents indicated that in 16% of the firms, the
Over the past four years, 19,000 trainees graduated CEO functioned as the board chairman, even though
from courses in management, marketing and finance at these two positions have been separated by Federal
Russian educational and training institutions. In addi- law enacted by the Duma on January 1, 1996.
tion, more than 5,800 managers have completed man-
agement internships in 15 foreign countries. Notably, 3.2. Variables and measures
new private companies have been created by 8.2% of
the graduates, and 65% of the companies that sent 3.2.1. Dependent variable
executives to these training courses report enhanced To obtain a robust measure of our dependent vari-
economic performance. So while this is a convenience able (i.e., firm performance), retrospective data were
sample that is not randomly selected, it does capture collected from the respondents on eight items. These
essential management perspectives from diverse items were obtained from (Dess & Robinson, 1984)
industries and geographic locations within Russia. and they ranged along five-point Likert scales ranging
Completed surveys were collected from respon- from ‘‘performs much worse than the competition’’ to
dents from 113 firms yielding an effective response ‘‘performs much better than the competition.’’ The
rate of 98%. As can be seen from Table 1, complete precise eight items used in this study are listed in the
data was collected from 45 of those firms because we Appendix. Because these measures were highly inter-
required the respondents to have first-hand knowledge correlated, we factor analyzed them and they all

Table 1
Descriptive statistics of the Russian managers and their organizations (N ¼ 45)

Demographic variable Mean Standard deviation Low value High value

Manager characteristics:
Manager’s age 30.7 2.2 27 35
Manager’s organizational tenure 6.2 2.8 1 11
Board characteristics:
Board size 9.6 4.2 5 17
Proportion of insiders (%) 50.7 28.0 6 100
Informal CEO duality (%) 16 36.7 0 100
Organizational characteristics:
Organizational size (emps.) 13,492.2 18,550.7 250 55,000
Organizational age (years) 27.8 18.8 5 103
Governmental ownership (%) 22 42 0 100
Strategies:
Maintain strategy (%) 43.3 17.9 5 90
Internal growth strategy (%) 23.7 11.1 5 60
External growth strategy (%) 15.2 10.7 0 50
Retrenchment strategy (%) 17.8 10.0 0 40
W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396 391

Table 2 measure was computed by dividing the number of


Factor analysis of firm performance (N ¼ 45)
inside directors by the total number of board members,
Variables Factor loading Cum eigenvalue similar to the majority of previous studies on board
Financial profitability 0.424 47.37
structure (Dalton & associates, 2000).
Growth in size/assets 0.587 65.06 The ‘‘grand strategy’’ variable asks respondents to
Customer satisfaction 0.784 76.15 characterize the strategic emphasis within the firm in
Product/service quality 0.757 83.89 our 2002 survey. Following Judge and Krishnan (1994),
Capacity utilization 0.777 90.16 we described each grand strategy type and asked the res-
Process improvements 0.843 94.75
pondents to place 100 points amongst the four strategic
Employment stability 0.786 98.10
Employee training 0.384 100.00 types to best capture the convergence or divergence of
strategic emphasis within the firm. For exact wording of
the four strategy types, please refer to the Appendix.
loaded positively on a single factor. As can be seen in With this approach, we were able to not only
Table 2, the factor loadings for these items ranged identify the primary strategic thrust, but also get a
from a low of 0.38 to a high of 0.84. Consequently, we feel for the overall strategic focus, or lack thereof, by
computed relatively robust factor scores representing the firm. In this way, each grand strategy type ranged
firm performance for each of the organizations in our in value from 0 to 100, and all four strategy types
study. The Cronbach alpha for this factor was 0.83, added to 100. For this study, the retrenchment strategy
which indicates more than acceptable reliability. represents the relative emphasis of retrenchment activ-
ities with respect to the other three grand strategies.
3.2.2. Independent variables
In 1996, Russian Federal law required all Russian 3.2.3. Control variables
firms to separate the roles of CEO and board chair. Previous research has repeatedly shown that organi-
Thus, the ‘‘formal’’ CEO duality measure for each and zation size has an impact on firm performance. To
every Russian firm since that time is that the Chair- control for size, we collected data from the respondents
person’s position is occupied by a separate person in on the number of employees currently working for the
all cases, and that this person is supposed to function firm. To address non-normality concerns with residuals,
independent of the CEO. However, many Russian we transformed this variable using the logarithmic
firms have responded formally to this legal require- transformation, similar to most of the board struc-
ment, but not all firms operate with an independent ture–firm performance literature (e.g., Dalton and
board chair. Hence, the ‘‘informal’’ CEO duality associates, 1998; Rhoades and associates, 2001).
varies from firm to firm. In addition to organizational size, we also collected
As a result, we asked respondents to indicate if the data on whether the Russian government had an own-
board chair functioned independently of the CEO or ership stake in the firm. Previous research on transition
not in our survey in recent board deliberations. When economies, particularly in Russia, indicate that govern-
they did function independently, the duality measure ment ownership changes the governance situation dra-
was recorded as a ‘‘0.’’ When the two individuals did matically (Che & Qian, 1998). As a result, if the firm
not function independent of each other and the CEO had any governmental ownership, we provided a con-
effectively controlled the board, then the duality mea- trol variable that was dummy coded as a ‘‘0’’ for no
sure was coded as a ‘‘1.’’ With this approach, we governmental ownership or ‘‘1’’ for some governmental
captured the essence of the agency argument even ownership.
though it may not reflect the formal legal situation.
The ‘‘insider proportion’’ measure was also col-
lected from our Russian respondents in the survey who 4. Results
were familiar with their board structure and function-
ing. We asked them to provide the size of the board of The descriptive statistics for this study are shown in
directors, and to inform us as to the number of insider Table 3. Notably, we had complete records of data for
or executive directors also serving on the board. This only 45 organizations so our sample size shrunk near
392 W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

Table 3
Descriptive statistics (N ¼ 45)

No. Variable Mean Standard deviation 1 2 3 4 5 6

1 Firm performance 0.00 1.00 1.00


2 Organizational size 8.32 1.69 0.28 1.00
3 Government ownership 0.22 0.42 0.16 0.18 1.00
4 Informal CEO duality 0.16 0.37 0.23 0.40 0.08 1.00
5 Insider proportion 0.51 0.28 0.26 0.81 0.03 0.20 1.00
6 Retrenchment strategy (%) 17.8 10.0 0.13 0.11 0.12 0.06 0.28 1.00

Note. ‘‘Organizational size’’ in this exhibit represents the logarithmic transformation of the number of employees in 2002.

p < 0:05;  p < 0:01.

60% from our original sample. There was a rather Table 4 contains the results of our analysis. Recall
large and significant inter-correlation between orga- that Hypothesis 1 predicted a negative relationship
nizational size and proportion of insiders suggesting between informal CEO duality and firm performance.
that the larger the organization, the less likely that As can be seen in Model 2 of Table 4, this relationship
insiders dominate the board’s composition. While this was empirically supported by our data (t ¼ 2:58,
relationship was interesting, it could pose a potential p < 0:01). For Hypothesis 2, we predicted a negative
problem of multicollinearity. relationship between insider proportion and firm per-
We investigated potential multicollinearity pro- formance. Model 2 reveals that our data did not
blems by examining variance inflation factors (VIFs). support this second hypothesis.
The maximum VIFs obtained from the three models As can been seen from Model 3 of Table 4, the
(presented in Table 4) were 4.2 for organization size retrenchment strategy was positively related to firm
and 3.9 for insider proportion, well below the rule-of- performance (t ¼ 2:24, p < 0:01) suggesting that
thumb cutoff of 10.0 for multiple regression models retrenchment has a distinct impact on firm perfor-
(Neter, Wasserman, & Kutner, 1985: 392). Thus, we mance within Russian firms, separate and distinct
can conclude that the regression estimates for our from the board context. This result, while not hypothe-
theoretical variables were not adversely affected by sized, is an interesting one and will be discussed
the presence of multicollinearity. further in the next section.

Table 4
Regression analyses on firm performance (N ¼ 45)

Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Beta t-value Beta t-value Beta t-value

Constant 1.05 1.24 2.15 1.21 1.26 0.68


Organizational sizea 0.15 1.71þ 0.24 1.44þ 0.23 1.38þ
Government ownershipb 0.27 0.76 0.29 0.83 0.11 0.30
Informal CEO dualityc 1.10 2.58 1.61 2.05
Insider proportion 0.09 0.10 1.27 1.00
Retrenchment strategy 0.10 2.24
Retrenchment  CEO duality 0.05 1.14
Retrenchment  insider proportion 0.09 1.92
Unadjusted R2 0.09 0.23 0.33
Adjusted R2 0.05 0.15 0.21
F-value 2.05 2.96 2.64
a
This variable represents the logarithmic transformation of the number of employees in 2002.
b
This variable is ‘‘0’’ if no government ownership, and ‘‘1’’ if some or all of the organization is owned by the government.
c
This variable is ‘‘0’’ for non-duality situations, and ‘‘1’’ when informal duality is present (e.g., CEO functions as chairman).
þ
p < 0:10;  p < 0:05;  p < 0:01.
W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396 393

Hypothesis 3 predicted that the retrenchment strat- balances in the form of an independent board appear to
egy would moderate the relationship between informal be even more critical when the Russian firm is
CEO duality and firm performance due to increased engaged with downsizing and restructuring.
centralization pressures. Our data did not support this Third, we found that the retrenchment strategy was
relationship as the interaction term was in the pre- positively related to overall firm performance. This
dicted direction, but not significant. However, Hypoth- suggested that those Russian firms that cut unproduc-
esis 4 predicated that the relationship between tive costs and assets from the firm experienced quick
proportion of insiders on the board and firm perfor- and robust performance results. This is an encouraging
mance would be more negative within a retrenchment finding that implies that when a Russian firm is led
context. Clearly, our data supported this fourth capably with proper oversight from outsiders, the firm
hypothesis (t ¼ 1:92, p < 0:05). can restructure itself to become more competitive.
Interestingly, our data did not support the notion
that the proportion of inside directors, in and of itself,
5. Discussion and conclusions is negatively related to firm performance. There are
two possible explanations for this result. First, our data
Two of our four hypotheses were supported by the showed that the proportion of inside directors is
data. First, we found consistent evidence suggesting associated firm performance only when the firm is
that informal CEO duality was negatively related to pursuing a retrenchment strategy. It may be that the
firm performance. This is especially noteworthy given board composition has little influence on firm perfor-
the fact that Russian law formally prohibits the CEO mance when the enterprise is stable or growing in
from also occupying the chairman’s role. While this typical Russian firms. A second possible explanation
finding is tentative and needs further examination, our is that another variable that somewhat approximates
data suggest that allowing CEOs to informally manip- the insider/outsider distinction has yet to be identified
ulate their board chair represents a conflict of interest in the governance literature. One possibility might be
and hinders firm performance. Thus, agency predic- organizational commitment; another might be leader-
tions (e.g., Jensen & Meckling, 1976) that a moral ship expertise. Clearly, field research would be helpful
hazard exists when the CEO effectively leads the in uncovering what that missing variable might be.
entity responsible for evaluating his or her perfor- Also, we did not find that the retrenchment strategy
mance has been strongly supported in our Russian moderated the informal CEO duality and firm perfor-
data set. mance relationship. This suggests that the CEO’s
While this relationship has been found to be unclear power inside of the board is not influenced by the
in the developed economies, there is a strong and firm’s strategic context. This may be relatively unique
pronounced negative relationship between informal to Russian culture with its historical tendency to
CEO duality and firm performance in this Russian conflate the leader with the overall country (Service,
sample. Perhaps this lends further support to those 1997). Alternatively, this finding may be an artifact of
who argue that we need to employ more field research our relatively small sample size as the beta coefficient
on persons directly involved with actual boardroom for our data was nearly significant and in the hypothe-
dynamics than relying primarily on archival proxies to sized direction. Clearly, it would be valuable to test
really understand corporate governance (Judge & this finding on a larger sample of Russian firms.
Zeithaml, 1992; Schmidt, 1975). Furthermore, it would be fascinating to explore this
Second, we found evidence suggesting that the relationship in China which is also a transition econ-
more that Russian firms engage in retrenchment activ- omy, but the role of the leader is viewed differently.
ities, the more negative the relationship between Despite these provocative findings, our results must
proportion of inside directors and firm performance. be taken with some caution. First, the generalizability
This implies that inside directors’ interests generally of our sample may or may not apply to transition
align with the owners’ interests, except when con- economies outside of Russia, as the previous discus-
fronted with personal loss through such things as sion and institutional theory suggests. Clearly, addi-
a retrenchment situation. Thus, outside checks and tional research is needed to test these findings in firms
394 W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

operating in other economies emerging from the boardroom dynamics yielded important and interesting
constraints of a centrally-controlled economy. insights. However, our data only explained 21% of the
Also, our sample size is relatively small. As such, adjusted variance in firm performance and the data was
larger sample sizes may reveal that some relationships retrospective. Nonetheless, the movement toward more
are supported that are not statistically supported in this independent and active boards appears to a trend that
study. For example, the retrenchment-informal CEO needs to be encouraged within the Russian economy,
duality interaction was not significant with a t-value of and perhaps in all transition economies.
1.14, but the direction of the relationship was con-
sistent with our hypothesis and it was nearly signifi-
cant. Thus, a larger sample size would contain more Appendix A
‘‘power’’ and may have revealed this hypothesis to be
significant. Finally, this study is cross-sectional in I. Descriptions of the four grand strategy types used
nature. While we hypothesize that firm performance in the survey
is the dependent variable, it may be the other way Please read the following four strategies and indi-
around. Additional research is needed where these cate what percentage of effort your firm places on each
relationships are regressed against a lagged perfor- strategy. The four entries should add up to 100%:
mance factor to more firmly assert causality. Firm continues to serve customers in the same
Despite these limitations, we believe that our find- or similar product/market domain, has its main deci-
ings refine and extend the corporate governance lit- sion focus on incremental improvement of functional
erature into transition economies. Most notably, this performance, and continues to pursue the same or
study reveals that even with a law formally separating similar objectives year by year.
the roles of CEO and board chair, informal activities Firm emphasizes growth predominantly through
can undermine the law and firm performance. For this internal development from within the company.
study of Russian firms, it appears that properly func- Firm emphasizes growth predominantly from
tioning corporate boards are important for navigating acquisition or merger, or joint ventures with other firms.
the ‘‘deinstitutionalization’’ of the Russian economy. Firm tries to improve performance by scaling
In general, it appears that checks and balances on the down the level and/or scope of its product/market
CEO’s power by separating the roles of CEO and objectives by cutting back in costs and by reduction
Chairman is a productive step toward making the firm in the scale of operations through divestment of some
more competitive when the chairman operates inde- units or divisions.
pendently from the CEO. And given a retrenchment II. Descriptions of eight firm performance items
situation, proper governance in the form of a majority used in survey
of outside directors also appears to add value. Please rate the following performance attributes of
Clearly, surveys administered by trusted third parties your organization relative to your industry average
and filled out by managers with first-hand knowledge of (please circle one of the numbers for each attribute):

Performance Well below Somewhat below About the Somewhat Well above
dimension the industry the industry same as the above industry industry
average average industry average average average
Financial profitability 1 2 3 4 5
Growth in size or assets 1 2 3 4 5
Customer satisfaction 1 2 3 4 5
Product or service quality 1 2 3 4 5
Capacity utilization 1 2 3 4 5
Process improvements 1 2 3 4 5
Employment stability 1 2 3 4 5
Employee training 1 2 3 4 5
W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396 395

References strategy and industry type. Strategic Management Journal, 3:


315–330.
Band, D. (1992). Corporate governance: Why agency theory is not Horvath, A., & Zsamboki, B. (2000). Implementation of European
enough. European Management Journal, 10(4): 453–460. banking directives in the Hungarian banking sector. Russian
Baysinger, B., & Hoskinson, R. (1990). The composition of boards and East European Finance and Trade, 36(3): 31–63.
of directors and strategic control: Effects on corporate strategy. Hoskisson, R., Eden, L., Lau, C., & Wright, M. (2000). Strategy in
Academy of Management Review, 15(1): 72–87. emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3):
Black, B. (2001). Does corporate governance matter? A crude test 249–267.
using Russian data. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial
149(6): 2131–2150. behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of
Cameron, K., Whetton, D., & Kim, M. (1987). Organizational Financial Economics, 3: 305–350.
dysfunctions of decline. Academy of Management Journal, Johnson, R., Hoskisson, R., & Hitt, M. (1993). Board of director
30(1): 126–138. involvement in restructuring: The effects of board versus
Cannella, A., & Monroe, M. (1997). Contrasting perspectives on managerial controls and characteristics. Strategic Management
strategic leaders: Toward a more realistic view of top managers. Journal, 14: 33–50.
Journal of Management, 23(3): 213–237. Judge, W. Q., & Krishnan, H. (1994). An empirical investigation of
Che, J., & Qian, Y. (1998). Insecure property rights and the scope of a firm’s enterprise strategy scope. Business &
governmental ownership of firms. Quarterly Journal of Society, 33(2): 167–190.
Economics, 1113(2): 467–496. Judge, W. Q., & Zeithaml, C. (1992). Institutional and strategic
Clifford, P., & Evans, R. (1997). Non-executive directors: A question choice perspectives on board involvement in the strategic
of independence. Corporate Governance, 5(4): 224–231. decision process. Academy of Management Journal, 35(4):
Corporate Governance. (1998). Case study: MOL Hungarian oil 766–794.
and gas company limited—the report of the supervisory board, Krau, E. (1995). Disempowering and downsizing middle manage-
6(2): 112–115. ment? The International Journal of Sociology and Social
Crow, P. (1998). Russian retrenchment. Oil and Gas Journal, Policy, 15(1–3): 91–120.
96(47): 39. Litwak, J., & Sutherland, D. (2002). OECD economic surveys,
Dharwadkar, R., George, G., & Brandes, P. (2000). Privitization in 2001–2002: Russian federation. New York: OECD.
emerging economies: An agency perspective. Academy of Mallin, C., & Jelic, R. (2000). Developments in corporate
Management Review, 25(3): 650–669. governance in central and eastern Europe. Corporate
Dalton, D., Daily, C., Ellstrand, A., & Johnson, J. (1998). Meta- Governance, 8(1): 43–51.
analytic reviews of board composition, leadership structure, and Massen, G., & Van den Bosch, F. (1999). On the supposed
financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 19: independence of two-tier boards: Formal structure and reality in
269–290. the Netherlands. Corporate Governance, 7(1): 31–37.
Dalton, D., & Kesner, I. (1987, Fall). Composition and CEO duality Neter, J., Wasserman, W., & Kutner, M. (1985). Applied linear
in boards of directors: An international perspective. Journal of statistical models (2nd ed.). Homewood, IL: Irwin.
International Business Studies: 33–42. Newman, K. (2000). Organizational transformation during insti-
Demb, A., & Neubauer, F. (1992). The corporate board, tutional upheaval. Academy of Management Review, 25(3):
confronting the paradoxes. New York: Oxford University Press. 602–619.
Dess, G., & Robinson, R. (1984). Measuring organizational North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic
performance in the absence of objective measures. Strategic performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Management Journal, 26(3): 467–488. Peng, M. (2003). Institutional transitions and strategic choices.
Filatotchev, I., Wright, M., Buck, T., & Zhukov, V. (2002). Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 275–296.
Downsizing in privatized firms in Russia, Ukraine, and Belarus. Rhoades, D., Rechner, P., & Sundaramurthy, C. (2000). Board
Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 286–304. composition and financial performance: A meta-analysis of the
Fox, M., & Heller, M. (2000). Corporate governance lessons from influence of outside directors. Journal of Managerial Issues,
Russian enterprise fiascoes. New York Law Review, 75(6): 12(1): 76–91.
1720–1780. Rhoades, D., Rechner, R., & Sundaramurthy, C. (2001). A meta-
Gillies, J., Leinmann, J., & Peterson, R. (2002). Making a successful analysis of board leadership structure and financial perfor-
transition from a command to a market economy: The lessons mance: Are ‘‘two heads better than one’’? Corporate
from Estonia. Corporate Governance, 10(3): 175–186. Governance, 9(4): 311–319.
Glueck, W. (1980). Business policy and strategic management. Robbins, D. K., & Pearce, J. (1992). Turnaround: Retrenchment
New York: McGraw Hill. and recovery. Strategic Management Journal, 13(4): 287–303.
Hitt, M., & Ireland, R. D. (1985). Corporate distinctive compe- Rueda-Sabater, E. (2000). Corporate governance and the bargain-
tence, strategy, and industry performance. Strategic Manage- ing power of developing countries to attract foreign investment.
ment Journal, 6: 273–293. Corporate Governance, 8(2): 117–124.
Hitt, M., Ireland, R., & Stadter, G. (1982). Functional importance Schmidt, R. (1975). Does board composition really make a
and company performance: Moderating effects of grand difference? Conference Board Record, 12(10): 38–48.
396 W.Q. Judge et al. / Journal of World Business 38 (2003) 385–396

Service, R. (1997). Russia: A history of the twentieth century. Young, M., Peng, M., Ahlstrom, D., & Bruton, G. (2002).
London: Penguin Books. Governing the corporation in emerging economies: A princi-
Sutton, R., & D’Aunno, T. (1989). Decreasing organizational size: pal–principal perspective. Academy of Management Best
Untangling the effects of money and people. Academy of Papers Proceedings. BPS Division: E1–E7.
Management Review, 14(2): 194–212.

You might also like