You are on page 1of 42

Industrial Organization 02

Oligopoly

Marc Bourreau

Telecom ParisTech

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 1 / 42


Outline

Oligopoly, definition and examples


Cournot model, where firms compete in quantities
Bertrand model, where firms compete in prices
Bertrand paradoxe
From Bertrand to Cournot: capacity constraints
Cournot competition with n firms
Comparison of market powers: monopoly, Cournot, and Bertrand

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 2 / 42


Introduction

Introduction

Definition of an oligopoly
A market or industry in which a small number of firms compete.

Most markets fit this description: telecommunications, software industry,


but also mineral water industry, etc.
In an oligopolistic market, a firm cannot ignore the behavior of competi-
tors...
... and the reaction of competitors to its own decisions.
The theory of oligopoly aims at studying these strategic interactions.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 3 / 42


Introduction

An example

The oligopoly of mineral water producers in France:


Three firms (Danone, Nestlé, and Neptune) share around 80% of the mar-
ket.
Products are marketed under various brand names (Danone: Evian, Volvic,
...; Nestlé: Perrier, Contrex, ... ; Neptune (formerly Castel): Saint-Yorre,
Vichy, Cristalline, ...).
Emergence of the Castel group in 1993 following a decision of the European
Commission which authorized the acquisition of la Société des eaux minérales
du bassin de Vichy.
Differentiation between mineral waters (health, well-being), different types
of packaging, makes the price comparisons difficult.
Interdependancy of strategic decisions: if a firm increases the price of
mineral water, its competitors can chose to do the same or not to react,
hoping to capture a part of the customer base.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 4 / 42


Cournot model

Cournot model

Cournot model (1838), developed by Augustin Cournot, a French engineer.


Two firms produce identical (homogenous) goods ("perfect substitutes")
and compete in quantities.
The price is determined in the way that the entire quantity of produced
goods is sold. Therefore one sets p = P(Q) where Q = q1 + q2 is the total
quantity produced.
The marginal cost of producing each unit of the good is assumed constant
and identical for the two firms: c
Then, the profit function of the firm i is

Πi = (P(Q) − c)qi .

For simplicity, we assume that the inverse demand function is P(Q) = 1−Q.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 5 / 42


Cournot model

Cournot model

Each firm sets its quantity to maximize its profits, given the quantity set
by the other firm.
The first-order condition of the maximization problem is:

1 − (q1 + q2 ) − c − qi = 0.

We compute a symmetric equilibrium such that qi = q. Thus:

1−c
q? = .
3
and
(1 − c)2
Π? = .
9

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 6 / 42


Cournot model

Cournot model

The equilibrium profit is:


(1 − c)2
Π? = .
9

In Cournot competition, firms make profits!

However, the Cournot model seems somewhat unrealistic:


Few examples of markets where firms set quantities rather than prices;
We don’t know well how the price is set up on the market.

A model where firms set prices rather than quantities? → Bertrand model.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 7 / 42


Bertrand paradox The model

Bertrand model

Bertrand model (1883), developed by Joseph Bertrand, a French engineer.


Two firms produce identical goods ("perfect substitutes") and compete in
prices.
The demand function is q = D(p).
The marginal cost of production is constant and identical for both firms: c
We assume (not indispensable) that the market is split evenly if firms offer
the same price. We thus have:

if pi < pj
 

 D pi
Di (pi , pj ) =  if pi = pj .

 1 
2 D p i
if pi > pj

0

The profit function of firm i is:

Πi (pi , pj ) = (pi − ci )Di (pi , pj ).

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 8 / 42


Bertrand paradox Bertrand equilibrium

Bertrand equilibrium

We find the Nash equilibrium for this one-step game.

Bertrand paradox
The game has a unique Nash equilibrium such that firms set p∗1 = p∗2 = c. A the
equilibrium, we have Π∗1 = Π∗2 = 0 and W = W ∗ .

A strong result:
When the number of firms goes from one (monopoly) to two (duopoly),
the price decreases from the monopoly price to the competitive price and
stays at the same level as the number of firms increases further.
Two firms suffice to reach a perfectly competitive equilibrium.
Because this result is extreme and generally inconsistent with reality, it is
called the "Bertrand paradox".

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 9 / 42


Bertrand paradox Bertrand equilibrium

An example

The price war between Intel and AMD, chip manufacturers, in 2006.
AMD ended the year with a loss and Intel’s benefits dropped by 42% in
2006.

Interview with Mario Rivas (CEO of AMD, Source:


l’Expansion) :
"This price war with Intel was ridiculous. I wish I was
able to match my prices to the market rate (...). The
problem was that, despite the 2 billion dollars of stocks
we had, Intel had 7 factories to run at full capacity. They
cut the price and we have no choice but to follow their
pricing".

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 10 / 42


Bertrand paradox Bertrand equilibrium

Demonstration

If p∗1 > p∗2 > c:


Then firm 1 increases its profit by setting p∗1 = p∗2 − .

If p∗1 = p∗2 > c:


Then firm 1 increases its profit by setting p∗1 = p∗2 − , as for a small ,

D(p∗1 )(p∗1 − c)/2 < D(p∗1 − )(p∗1 − c − )

If p∗1 > p∗2 = c :


Then firm 2 increases its profit by setting p2 = p∗2 + .

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 11 / 42


Bertrand paradox Bertrand equilibrium

Bertrand competition with different marginal costs

Let’s assume that c1 < c2 .


If costs are close enough: c1 < c2 < pm (c1 )
There is a unique Nash equilibrium with p∗1 = c2 −  et p∗2 = c2 .
Only firm 1 makes profit: Π∗1 = (c2 − c1 )D(c2 ) et Π∗2 = 0.

If firm 1 is much more efficient than firm 2: c1 < pm (c1 ) < c2


There is a unique Nash equilibrium with p∗1 = pm (c1 ) and p∗2 = c2 .
Only firm 1 makes profit: Π∗1 = Πm
1
and Π∗2 = 0.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 12 / 42


Bertrand paradox Solutions to Bertrand paradox

Solutions to Bertrand paradox

Four important solutions to "Bertrand paradox", corresponding to four impor-


tant assumptions on which the model relies :
1 Products are homogeneous
2 Short-run competition (a static analysis of a one-step game)
3 Firms do not have capacity constraints
4 Consumers are perfectly informed

Relaxing one of these assumptions solves the paradox:


1 Product differentiation
2 Dynamic competition (repeated interactions)
3 Firms are capacity-constrained
4 Imperfect information

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 13 / 42


Bertrand paradox Solutions to Bertrand paradox

Product differentiation

Let’s assume, for instance, a geographic differentiation.


Two icecream vendors, 1 and 2, are located at the two extremities of a
beach
If p1 = c, is p2 = c +  > c possible?
Consumers close to vendor 2 can prefer buying a little more expensive
from 2 than moving to 1!
Horizontal and vertical differentiation theory: the Hotelling model...

In the presence of product differentiation...


A situation such as that pi > c can be an equilibrium.

→ See the lecture about differentiation.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 14 / 42


Bertrand paradox Solutions to Bertrand paradox

Dynamic competition

Bertrand competition model assumes that firms compete only during a


single period.
In this situation, as we start from p1 = p2 > c, a firm has strong incentives
to undercut its price.
In a more dynamic framework, what can happen?
In a dynamic situation, firms are going to take account the effect of its price
cut on its rival’s behavior in future periods.
If there is a "punishment" (price war...), it will compare the short-term and
long-term gains.

In a repeated interaction framework...


A situation with pi > c can be an equilibrium.

→ See the lecture about collusion.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 15 / 42


Bertrand paradox Solutions to Bertrand paradox

Capacity constraints

Bertrand model assumes that firms do not have capacity constraints.


If p1 = p2 = c, the two firms share the demand: D(c)/2
If firm 2 increases slightly its price, p2 = c + , we assumed that firm 1
meets the demand, that is D(c).
But firm 1 can be unable to meet the whole demand: capacity constraints
In that case, firm 2 can increase her price and still retain a part of the market

When firms face capacity constraints...


A situation with pi > c can be an equilibrium.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 16 / 42


Bertrand paradox Solutions to Bertrand paradox

Imperfect information

With imperfect information...


A situation with pi > c can be an equilibrium.

The Diamond paradox


Consumers are not informed about prices
Cost  to move from a store to another (search cost)
If p1 = p2 < pm then deviation is possible to p1 + /2

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 17 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints A model

Price competition with capacity constraints

We are going to study a price competition model when firms have constraints
in production capacity.

We consider the following model:


Two firms compete in prices, but are capacity-constrained
The demand function is linear, D(p) = 1 − p
The inverse demand function is: p = P(q1 + q2 ) = 1 − (q1 + q2 )
Firm i cannot produce more than its production capacity qi . Thus, we have
qi ≤ qi
The unit cost of acquiring capacity qi is c0 ∈ [3/4, 1].
There is no production cost (c = 0).

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 18 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints A model

Price competition with capacity constraints

We need to define a rationing rule.


The rationing rule determines "which consumers" are being served when
the firm cannot meet the entire demand.
We apply the "efficient" rationing rule: consumers with higher willingness to
pay are first served.
If p1 < p2 and q1 < D(p1 ) :
(  
e 2 p2  = D p2 − q1 if D p2  ≥ q1
D .
0 if D p2 < q1

Other possible rule: the "proportional" rationing rule

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 19 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints Results

Results

We obtain the following result:

Price competition with capacity constraints


The unique Nash equilibrium is such that the firms set the same price
 
p∗ = 1 − q1 + q2 .

Consequence: at the stage of defining their production capacities, firms have a


gross profit equal to:
g
h  i
Πi = 1 − qi + qj qi ,

That is? The profit function in the Cournot model.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 20 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints Results

Proof: preliminaries

First, given that c0 ∈ [3/4, 1], what is the upper bound for qi ?

To answer the question, what is the maximum profit of firm i ?

→ It is the monopoly profit!

As D(p) = 1 − p and c = 0, the monopoly price is equal to... ? 1/2

Thus the monopoly profit is... ? 1/4 − c0 qi

Therefore qi ≤ 1/3 because we have 1/4 − c0 qi ≥ 0.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 21 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints Results

Proof of existence

 
Now, let’s demonstrate that p∗ = 1 − q1 + q2 is a Nash equilibrium.

Observation: p∗ > c because q1 + q2 < 2/3.

Can firm i lower her price?


No, she would not increase her profit as she is already at the maximum of her
production capacity.

→ "Bertrand competition" does not work because firms face capacity con-
straints.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 22 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints Results

Proof of existence

If the firm i sets a higher price p > p∗ ?


Firm j captures the entire demand... up to the maximum of its production
capacity.
A fraction of the demand is not satisfied and firm i takes it back: we call it
the residual demand
The residual demand is equal to 1 − p − qj
Thus firm i makes profit:
   
p 1 − p − qj = 1 − q − qj q.

It is the Cournot profit! It is concave in q and its derivative in q = qi is

1 − 2qi − qj ≥ 0 as qi ≤ 1/3,

Therefore, the optimal value of q is q = qi .

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 23 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints Results

Proof of uniqueness
 
p∗ = 1 − q1 + q2 is the unique Nash equilibrium.
 
p1 = p2 = p > P q1 + q2 is not an equilibrium because at least one firm
does not reach its maximum production capacity. Therefore she can lower
her price.
 
p1 = p2 = p < P q1 + q2 is not an equilibrium. With pi = pi + , the firm
would sell the same capacity (its production capacity) at a higher price.
p1 < p2 not feasible, because firm 1 is encouraged to increase its price.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 24 / 42


Price competition with capacity constraints More general result

More general result

We consider a two-stage game in which:


First, firms choose simultaneously their production capacity;
Firms observe the chosen capacities and choose simultaneously their prices
(price competition).

Kreps and Scheinkman (1983): capacity + price = quantities


If the demand function is concave and we use the efficient-rationing rule, then
the equilibrium f the two-stage game is equivalent to the equilibrium of Cournot
competition (competition in quantities).

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 25 / 42


Cournot or Bertrand competition?

Cournot or Bertrand competition?

Which one is the best-suited model, Bertrand or Cournot?


Informal rule (rule of thumb)
If the production capacity can be easily adjusted, Bertrand competition model
better represents the duopoly competition. Otherwise, if it is difficult to adjust
the production capacity, the Cournot model is more appropriate.

Examples of markets where production capacity is not easy to adjust? → markets for
physical goods (car manufacturers, airplanes, cement industry...).

Examples of markets where production capacity is easy to adjust: → markets for


services (bank, insurance...)...

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 26 / 42


Cournot or Bertrand competition?

Bertrand or Cournot? The example of the recorded


music industry

Let’s consider the recorded music industry.

We observe an evolution in the distribution of recorded music:


from the sales of CDs in physical stores,
to digital files on web platforms such as iTunes,
and now to streaming platforms.

What type of competition model (Cournot, Bertrand) represents better the old
distribution model? And the new one?

What are the consequences we can predict from this change in the competition
model ?

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 27 / 42


Cournot or Bertrand competition?

The effect of the digitization: Britannica vs Encarta

Britannica: a 200-year-old encyclopedia, 1600 euros the full collection.


Encarta: a product launched by Microsoft in 1992 (acquisition of Funk and
Wagnalls) at 49,95 dollars/euros
Response of Britannica to Microsoft’s entry?
Online encyclopedia at 2000 euros per year
Drop in sales of Britannica to 50% between 1990 and 1996
Online encyclopedia at 120 euros/an
CD for 200 euros, then for less than 100 euros.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 28 / 42


Cournot competition with n firms

Cournot competition with n firms

Let’s assume a linear demand D(p) = 1 − p


n firms on the market compete in quantities (Cournot competition)
The cost fonction of firm i is Ci (qi ) = cqi
What is the equilibrium price?
What is the equilibrium profit?

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 29 / 42


Cournot competition with n firms

Cournot competition with n firms


The inverse demand function is P(Q) = 1 − Q, where
n
X
Q= qi .
i=1

The profit function of a firm i is


Πi = (P(Q) − c)qi .
The first order condition of the maximization problem is:
1 − Q − c − qi = 0.
We look for a symmetric equilibrium with qi = q. Thus
1−c
q= .
n+1
and
(1 − c)2
Π= .
(n + 1)2
Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 30 / 42
Cournot competition with n firms

Cournot competition with n firms

The equilibrium profit is:


(1 − c)2
Π= .
(n + 1)2

The more numerous firms are, the lower Cournot profit is.

If the number of firms is large, firms hardly any profit.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 31 / 42


Comparison in terms of market power

Comparison in terms of market power

Assumptions:
Let’s assume there are n firms,
With the same marginal cost of production, c.
We define Li = (pi − c)/pi the Lerner index for firm i.

Comparison: monopoly, Bertrand, Cournot


In a monopoly, we have?
1
. Li =

In Bertrand competition, we have? → Li = 0.
In Cournot competition, we have?
αi
Li = , where αi is the market share of firm i


Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 32 / 42


Comparison in terms of market power

Proof
Let P(Q) represent the inverse demand function, with Q = q1 + q2 the total
quantity produced
Then, firm i profit function is
   
P qi + qj − c qi

The FOC is :    
P qi + qj − c + qi P0 qi + qj = 0,
That is,
   
P−c qi P0 qi + qj qi P qi + qj Q
0
= − =−
P P Q P
qi Q
= − ,
Q PD0
ie.
αi
Li = .

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 33 / 42
An application: mergers

Merger in the French mobile telephony market

The French mobile telephony market had a client base of 71 million of


subscribers in March 2015 (according to ARCEP). (That is, a penetration
rate of 107%).
There are four principal operators: Orange (35,6%), SFR (28%), Bouygues
Télécom (14,2%) and Free (13,2%)
Mobile virtual network operators (La Poste, etc.) have low market shares
(8,7%).
There have been rumors of mergers between Bouygues Télécom and Free.
We are going to build a simple competition model to study the incentives
of Bouygues Télécom and Free to merge.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 34 / 42


An application: mergers

Merger in the French mobile telephony market

For simplicity, let’s assume that the mobile market presents 4 firms.
We thus ignore the competitive pressure coming from MVNOs.
We assume that these 4 firms produce homogeneous (identical) goods and
compete in quantities.
Let qi firm i’s quantity and Q = q1 + q2 + q3 + q4 the total quantity.
The demand function is D(p) = 50 − p.
Questions:
1 Determine the Nash equilibrium for a quantity competition game. Com-
pute the quantity and profit in equilibrium for each firm.
2 We assume that firms 3 and 4 merge (Bouygues and Free) and become a
new firm, BF. Compute again the equilibrium, the produced quantity and
equilibrium profit for firm BF, 1 and 2.
3 Are firms 3 and 4 better off merging? How do firms 1 and 2’s profits
evolve?

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 35 / 42


An application: mergers

Merger in the French mobile telephony market

1 Determine the Nash equilibrium for a quantity competition game. Com-


pute the quantity and profit in equilibrium for each firm.

The quantity in equilibrium for a Cournot model with n firms is:

50
q∗ (n) = .
n+1
The Cournot profit with n firms is:

2500
Π∗i (n) = .
(n + 1)2

Therefore, for n = 4, we have: q∗ (n) = 50/5 = 10 and Π∗i = 2500/25 = 100

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 36 / 42


An application: mergers

Merger in the French mobile telephony market

1 We assume that firms 3 and 4 merge (Bouygues and Free) and become a
new firm, BF. Compute again the equilibrium, the produced quantity and
equilibrium profit for firm BF, 1 and 2.

We move from an oligopoly with 4 firms to an oligopoly with 3 firms


Thus, for n = 3, we have: q∗ (n) = 50/4 and Π∗i = 2500/16 = 156.25

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 37 / 42


An application: mergers

Merger in the French mobile telephony market

1 Are firms 3 and 4 better off merging? How do firms 1 and 2’s profits
evolve?

Bouygues and Free are not well advised to merge because 156.25 < 100 *
2: their global profit decreases!
Whereas, Orange and SFR are better off: 156.25 > 100 !

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 38 / 42


An application: mergers

Merger in Cournot competition


Let’s consider a market with n > 1 firms
Marginal cost is constant and identical: c
Linear demand: P(Q) = a − bQ
In the equilibrium, we have:

1 (a − c)2
Π∗i (n) = .
b (n + 1)2

In case of a merger of k firms, n − k + 1 firms will be present on the market.


In that case, a merger is profitable if

Π∗i (n − k + 1) ≥ kΠ∗i (n)

Merger in Cournot competition


In a Cournot competition, a merger is profitable only if it involves more than
80% of firms in the market.
Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 39 / 42
An application: mergers

Merger in Bertrand

Let’s consider a market with n > 1 firms


Marginal costs are constant and identical: c
In the equilibrium, p∗1 = ... = p∗n = c and profits are 0.
If k < n firms merge, how the equilibrium is modified?
It is unchanged: the price stays equal to c and profits are 0.

Merger in Bertrand competition


In a Bertrand competition, a merger is profitable only if it involves all (100%)
of the firms in the market.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 40 / 42


An application: mergers

Conclusion on mergers

Merger decisions cannot be explained only by the incentives to reduce compe-


tition in the market.

Other dimensions to explain merger?


Synergies: cost cutting...
Becoming an industry leader (the competition model changes: Stackelberg
rather than Cournot)
Portfolio strategy: extending product range, economies of scale in sales
and marketing, incentives to bundle.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 41 / 42


Take-aways

Take-aways

Bertrand competition between identical firms leads to marginal-cost pric-


ing ("Bertrand paradox").
The Bertrand paradox is not verified anymore if we relax one of the 4
principal assumptions...
If capacity constraints can be easily adjusted in short term, it is more likely
that firms compete in Bertrand. If production capacity remains fixed in
medium term, firms compete in Cournot.
When n firms compete in Cournot, their profit is inversely proportional to
the number of firms playing in the market.
A merger is not always profitable in Cournot competition; it needs to
involve at least 80% of the firms in the market. In Bertrand competition, it
requires 100% of the firms in the market. Mergers cannot be only explained
by an incentive to reduce competition.

Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 02: Oligopoly 42 / 42

You might also like