You are on page 1of 40

CHAPTER 2.

RETURNS
2.1 Introduction

Let Pt be the price of an asset at time


t.

Assuming no dividends the net return


is
Pt Pt − Pt−1
Rt = −1=
Pt−1 Pt−1

1
The simple gross return is

Pt
= 1 + Rt
Pt−1

Example: If Pt−1 = 2 and Pt = 2.1


then
Pt 2.1
1+Rt = = = 1.05 and Rt = 0.05
Pt−1 2

2
The gross return over k periods (t − k
to t) is

1 + Rt(k) :=     
Pt Pt   Pt−1  Pt−k+1 
=  ··· 
Pt−k Pt−1 Pt−2 Pt−k
= (1 + Rt) · · · (1 + Rt−k+1)

3
Returns are

• scale-free, meaning that they do


not depend on monetary units (dol-
lars, cents, etc.)

• not unit-less — unit is time; they


depend on the units of t (hour, day,
etc.)

4
Example:

Time t−2 t−1 t t+1


P 200 210 206 212
1+R 1.05 .981 1.03
1 + R(2) 1.03 1.01
1 + R(3) 1.06

1+R:

1.05 = 210/200

.981 = 206/210

1.03 = 212/206
5
Example:

Time t−2 t−1 t t+1


P 200 210 206 212
1+R 1.05 .981 1.03
1 + R(2) 1.03 1.01
1 + R(3) 1.06

1+R(2): 1.03 = 206/200; 1.01 =


212/210

1+R(3): 1.06 = 212/200

6
Log returns

log prices:

pt := log(Pt)

log(x) = the natural logarithm of x

Continuously compounded or log re-


turns are logarithms of gross returns:
 
Pt 
rt := log(1+Rt) = log  = pt−pt−1
Pt−1
where pt := log(Pt)

7
Example: Suppose Pt−1 = 2.0 and
Pt = 2.06. Then 1 + Rt = 1.03, Rt =
.03, and rt = log(1.03) = .0296 ≈ .03

Advantage — simplicity of multiperiod


returns

rt(k)
= log{1 + Rt(k)}
n o
= log (1 + Rt) · · · (1 + Rt−k+1)
= log(1 + Rt) + · · · + log(1 + Rt−k+1)
= rt + rt−1 + · · · + rt−k+1

8
Log returns are approximately equal
to net returns:

• x small ⇒ log(1 + x) ≈ x

• therefore, rt = log(1 + Rt) ≈ Rt

• Examples:

* log(1 + .05) = .0488

* log(1 − .05) = −.0513

9
!"#

!"$

&'()$*%+
!!"$
%

!!"#

!!"# !!"$ ! !"$ !"#


%

Comparison of functions log(1 + x) and x.

10
Adjustment for Dividends

If a dividend (or interest) Dt is paid


prior to time t, then the gross return
at time t is defined as
Pt + Dt
1 + Rt = ,
Pt−1
and so the net return is
Pt + Dt
Rt = − 1,
Pt−1
and the log return is

rt = log(Pt + Dt) − log(Pt−1).

11
Behavior of returns

What can we say about returns?

• cannot be perfectly predicted — are


random.

Uncertainty in returns

At time t − 1, Pt and Rt are not only


unknown, but we do not know their
probability distributions.

12
Can estimate these distributions: with
an assumption

Leap of Faith:

• Future returns similar to past re-


turns

• So distribution of Pt can be esti-


mated from past data

13
Asset pricing models (e.g. CAPM)
use the joint distribution of cross-section
{R1t, . . . , RN t} of returns on N assets at
a single time t.

• Rit is the return on the ith asset at


time t.

Other models use the time series


R1, R2, . . . , Rt of returns on a single as-
set at a sequence of times 1, 2, . . . , t.
We will start with a single asset.
14
Common Model — IID Normal Returns

R1, R2, . . . = returns from single asset.

1. mutually independent

2. identically distributed

3. normally distributed

IID = independent and identically distributed


15
Two problems:

• The model implies the possibility of


unlimited losses, but liability is usu-
ally limited

– Rt ≥ −1 since you can lose no


more than your investment

16
• 1+Rt(k) = (1+Rt)(1+Rt−1) · · · (1+
Rt−k+1) is not normal

– sums of normals are normal but


not products

– but it would be nice to have nor-


mality, so math is simple

17
The Lognormal Model

Assumes: rt = log(1 + Rt) are IID and


normal

Thus,

• we assume that

log(1 + Rt) ∼ N (µ, σ 2)

18
• so that 1 + Rt = exp(normal r.v.) ≥
0

• so that Rt ≥ −1.

• this solves the first problem

19
For second problem:

• First,

1 + Rt(k) = (1 + Rt) · · · (1 + Rt−k+1)


= exp(rt) · · · exp(rt−k+1)
= exp(rt + · · · + rt−k+1).

• Therefore,

log{1 + Rt(k)} = rt + · · · rt−k+1

20
• Sums of normals are normal ⇒ the
second problem is solved

– normality of single period returns


implies normality of multiple pe-
riod returns.

21
Example:

• A simple gross return (1 + R) is


lognormal{0,(0.1)2}

– which means that log(1 + R) is


N {0, (0.1)2}

• What is P (1 + R < 0.9)?

22
Answer:

• Since log(0.9)= −0.1053605,

P (1+R < 0.9) = P {log(1+R) < log(0.9)}

= Φ{(−0.1053605−0)/0.1} = Φ(−1.05360

= 0.1460319.

• In R, pnorm(−1.053605);

plnorm(0.9,mean=0,sd=0.1)

23
Example:

• Assume again that 1 + R is


lognormal{0,(0.1)2}

• Find the probability that a simple


gross two-period return is less than
0.9

24
Answer:

• The two-period gross return is log


normal{0, 2(0.1)2} so this probabil-
ity is
 
log(0.9) 
Φ √ = Φ(−0.7450114)
( 2)(0.1) 

= 0.2281324

25
Let’s find a general formula for the
kth period returns:

Assume that

• 1 + Rt(k) = (1 + Rt) · · · (1 + Rt−k+1)

• log(1 + Ri) ∼ N (µ, σ 2) for all i

• the {Ri} are mutually independent

26
Then log{1 + Rt(k)} is the sum of k
independent N (µ, σ 2) random variables

• so that log(1 + Rt(k)) ∼ N (kµ, kσ 2)

• therefore
 

 log(x) kµ 
P {1 + Rt(k) < x} = Φ  √
kσ 

27
2.2 Random Walk

Let Z1, Z2, . . . be IID

• with mean µ and standard deviation


σ.

Z0 is an arbitrary starting point. Let

• S0 = Z0

• St := Z0 + Z1 + · · · + Zt, t ≥ 1.
28
S0, S1, . . . is called a random walk.

• E(St|Z0) = Z0 + µt

• Var(St|Z0) = σ 2t


• SD(St|Z0) = σ t

29
/0123-45067
*
-.01
% -.014849:
-.014!49:
)

'

"

&

!&
! " # $ % &!
+,-.

Mean and probability bounds on a


random walk with S0 = 0, µ = .5
and σ = 1. At any given time, the
probability of being between the
probability bounds (dashed curves)
is 68%.
30
Geometric Random Walk

Recall that log{1 + Rt(k)} = rt + · · · +


rt−k+1. Therefore
Pt
= 1+Rt(k) = exp(rt+· · ·+rt−k+1)
Pt−k
so taking k = t we have

Pt = P0 exp(rt + rt−1 + · · · + r1).

31
Skewed returns: if log returns are IID
N (µ, σ 2), then gross returns are
lognormal(µ, σ 2) and are skewed

• then {Pt : t = 1, 2, . . .} is exponential


of random walk

• such a process is a “geometric ran-


dom walk”

32
• median of R is exp(µ) − 1 since

P {R < exp(µ)−1} = P {1+R < exp(µ)}

1
= P {r < µ} = P {N (µ, σ 2) < µ} = .
2

• E(R) = exp(µ + σ 2/2) − 1 > median


(fact about lognormals)

33
• 1 + Rt(k) = exp{rt + · · · + rt−k+1} is
lognormal(kµ, kσ 2) and also skewed

• see the densities in the following Fig-


ure

34
Lognormal densities
0.7
!=0, !=1
!=1,!=1
0.6 !=0, !=1.2

0.5

0.4
density

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
0 2 4 6 8 10
x

Log normal densities.

35
The effect of the drift µ

• The geometric random walk model


does not imply that one cannot make
money

• since µ is generally positive, there is


an upward “drift”

• the log returns on the US stock mar-


ket as a whole have a mean of about
10% and a standard deviation of
about 20%
36
• next figure shows two independent
simulations of 25 years of a geomet-
ric random walk with these values of
µ and σ

37
• the prices start at 100

• the two series of log returns look


quite different

• the log prices and prices look much


more similar, reason is that they both
have µ = 0.1

– so the long run gives an upward


trend

• medians of the log returns, log prices,


and prices are also plotted
38
1'()*+,-*.2)0*+)34%#54%$6$6
#
789
789
&'()*+,-*.

!%"
:+;<0.

!!%"
! " #! #" $!
/+0*
?
789
789
&'()@*<A+

:+;<0.
>

=
! " #! #" $!
/+0*
$!!!
789
789
:+;<0.
@*<A+

#!!! :+0.

!
! " #! #" $!
/+0*

39
Questions: i) Are log returns really
normally distributed? ii) if not, what
stylized facts do them exhibit?

Homework: Exercises 1,4,7,10.

40

You might also like