You are on page 1of 34

Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey of Recent Literature

Eirik G. Furubotn; Svetozar Pejovich

Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 10, No. 4. (Dec., 1972), pp. 1137-1162.

Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28197212%2910%3A4%3C1137%3APRAETA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-V

Journal of Economic Literature is currently published by American Economic Association.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained
prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in
the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/journals/aea.html.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is an independent not-for-profit organization dedicated to and preserving a digital archive of scholarly journals. For
more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

http://www.jstor.org
Wed Jun 6 21:10:23 2007
Property Rights and Economic

Theory: A Survey of

Recent Literature

By EIRIKG. FURUBOTN
Texas A b M University
and
PEJOVICH
SVETOZAR
Ohio University

T h e writing of this paper was facilitated by a grant from


the National Science Foundation.

Asproduction ofandtheexchange
CRITICISM traditional theory of
has inounted
duced into the theory of production and ex-
change. First, an entirely new interpreta-
in the postwar period, increasing attention tion is given to the role of individual deci-
has been given to new analytical ap- sion makers within the productive organiza-
proaches that seek either to supplant classi- tion. The organizaion per se is no longer the
cal marginalism or to extend its scope. In central focus; rather, individuals are as-
the latter category is the important body of sumed to seek their own interests and to
literature that has grown up around the no- maximize utility subject to the limits estab-
tion of property rights structures. The con- lished by the existing organizational struc-
tributions here are quite diverse in style ture.,Second, account is taken of the fact
and content but are characterized by a that more than one pattern of property
common emphasis on certain basic ideas rights can exist and that profit (or wealth)
concerning the interconnectedness of own- maximization is not assured. By considering
ership rights, incentives, and economic be- the effects of various possible property
havior. The purpose of the present paper is rights assignments on the penalty-reward
to summarize the essential features of this system, detailed analysis of the interrela-
line of research, examine some of its impor- tions between institutional arrangements
tant areas of application, and discuss the and economic behavior becomes feasible.
promise the approach holds for improved Third, transactions costs are recognized as
understanding of economic problems. being greater than zero in virtually all cases
of practical importance. From a technical
I. Extension o f the Theory of Production standpoint, these new ideas have straight-
and Exchange forward application. The usual procedure is
The "property rights" literature begins to formulate an optimization model that is
with the presumption that modifications analogous to, but in general distinct from.
must be made in the conventional analyt- the traditional profit maximization case. In
ical framework if economic models having each instance, it is necessary to define the
wider applicability are to be developed. particular utility function that reflects the
Thus, several crucial changes are intro- decision maker's preferences, and to deter-
1138 Journal of Economic Literature

mine the actual set of options (penalties- envisioned, marginalism is not rejected; the
rewards) that is attainable by the decision standard techniques are merely extended to
maker. Then, the formal problem emerges new applications [37, Crew, et al, 1971 and
as one of maximizing the utility function 60, Johnson, 19661.
subject to the constraint imposed by the op- To engage in something more than
portunity set. Of course, the usefulness of purely formal discussion the utility function
any such model depends on how skillfully must be given specific interpretation.
the specification is made of the objective Boulding's general comments on the "sub-
function and the opportunity set. jectivist" position make this clear.
The rejection of profit maximization as If the firm will sacrifice "profits" ( n o matter how
the fundamental behavioral postulate ex- measured) for anything else, whether prestige, or
plaining the actions of decision makers in good public or labor relations, or a quiet life, or
the business sector represents a simple yet liquidity, or security, or what have you, then it is
important step1 For, the shift to utility as clearly not maximizing profits. And if it is not maxi-
mizing profits it must be maximizing "utility," which
the maximand opens up new possibilities for is simply a more elaborate way of saying that it does
studying different patterns of managerial what it thinks best. This can hardly be untrue, but
behavior, and permits greater insight into it is also not very helpful unless some content can
the operation of business firms in various be poured into the empty utility functions [20, 1960,
socio-economic environments 11, Alchian p 41.
and Kessel, 1962; 2, Alchian, 1965; 4, Al- Relative to this argument, the property
chian, 1969; 11, Averach and Johnson, 1962; rights approach can be understood as an at-
48, Furubotn, 1971; 49, Furubotn and Pejo- tempt to formulate empirically meaningful
vich, 1970; 52, Furubotn and Pejovich, optimization problems by associating the
1972; 83, Nichols, 1967; 90, Pejovich, 1969; utility function with the individual decision
122, Williamson, 1964 and 123, Williamson, maker and then introducing specific content
19631. This is so because regardless of the into the function. In this way, it becomes
number, character, or diversity of the goals possible to consider the behavior of the de-
established by an individual decision cision maker within the firm, government
maker, the goals can always be conceived bureau, or similar collective agency. The
as arguments in some type of utility func- other key idea in the analysis is that differ-
tion. And, as noted, the utility function can ent property rights assignments lead to
be maximized subject to appropriate con- different penalty-reward structures and,
straints. Significantly, each decision maker hence, decide the choices that are open to
is assumed to be motivated by self-interest decision makers. An important shift of
and to move efficiently toward the most viewpoint is evident here. Instead of treat-
preferred operating position open.2 It ing the firm as the unit of analysis and as-
follows, therefore, that under the conditions suming that the owners' interests are given
exclusive attention via the process of profit
'The analysis has also been extended to include
the behavior of the state. See [22, Buchanan, 1968; maximization, the utility maximizing model
24, Buchanan and Tullock, 1962; 38, De Alessi, emphasizes individual adjustment to the
1969; 75, McKean, 1971; 84, Niskanen, 1968 and economic environment and seeks to explain
85, Niskanen, 19711.
'The behavior of the firm ( o r other organiza- the behavior of the firm and other institu-
tion) is not interpreted in terms of the "satisficing" tions by observing individual actions within
hypothesis that has been advanced by some authors the organization. In effect, an analytical ba-
who also reject profit maximization [log, Shubik,
1961; 110, Simon, 1959, pp. 265-66; 118, Vickers, sis is provided for examining the linkage
1968, Ch. I ] . between the objectives of decision mak-
Furubotn and Pejovich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1139

ers and the particular strategies used to re- cussion throughout the paper. At this stage,
alize these objectives [123, Williamson, it is only necessary to emphasize one other
1963, pp. 1033401. The presumption is, of point. Though sometimes forgotten, there
course, that once human motivations are should be no confusion about the fact that
known, better understanding of the organi- both trade and production involve contrac-
zation's allocation and use of resources be- tual arrangements; these activities exist not
comes possible. so much to accomplish the exchange of
It is not difficult to accept the basic idea goods and services but to permit the ex-
that "property rights" tend to influence in- change of "bundles" of property rightse4
centives and behavior [35,Coleman, l w ] . Permission to do things with the goods and
The literature of the area, however, defines services is at issue.
the concept of property rights with some The value of any good exchanged de-
precision and this special usage deserves pends, ceteris paribus, on the bundle of
comment. A central point noted is that property rights that is conveyed in the
property rights do not refer to relations be- transaction. For example, the worth of a
tween men and things but, rather, to the house to an individual will be relatively
sanctioned behavioral relations among men greater if the bundle of property rights ac-
that arise from the existence of things and quired contains the right to exclude gaso-
pertain to their use. .Property rights assign- line stations, chemical plants, etc, from the
ments specify the norms of behavior with re- immediate vicinity of the house. I t follows
spect to things that each and every person that the set of various property rights held
must observe in his interactions with other over resources enters into the utility fnnc-
persons, or bear the cost for nonobservance. tion of the decision maker. Consequently, a
The prevailing system of property rights in change in the general system of property
the community can be described, then, as relations must affect the way people behave
the set of economic and social relations de- and, through this effect on behavior, prop-
fining the position of each individual with erty rights assignments affect the allocation
respect to the utilization of scarce re- of resources, composition of output, distri-
source~.~ bution of income, etc. In the limit, one can
From a practical standpoint, the crucial say, as Alchian, that:
task for the new property rights approach is .
. . In essence, economics is the study of property
to show that the content of property rights .
rights over scarce resources. . . The allocation of
affects the allocation and use of resources in scarce resources in a society is the assignment of
specific and predictable ways. For, without rights to uses of resources . . . the question of eco-
the latter assurance, there would be no pos- nomics, or of how prices should be determined, is
the question of how property rights should be de-
sibility of developing analytically signifi- fined and exchanged, and on what terms [3, Alchian,
cant and empirically refutable propositions 1967, pp. 2-31.
about the effects of various property rights
assignments on the level and character of This paper is concerned primarily with
economic activity in the community. The the effects of private property rights and
essential assumption that systematic rela- state ownership on the allocation and use of
tions exist between property rights and eco- resources. The right of ownership in an as-
nomic choices lies in the background of dis- set, whether by a private party or the state,
'Excellent discussion of the importance and
Roman Law, Common Law, Marx and Engels, content of contractual stipulations are found in
and current legal and economic studies basically S. Cheung [28, 19701 and S. MacCauley [66,
agree on this definition of property rights. 19631.
1140 Journal of Economic Literature

is understood to consist of the right to use or other advantage, accrue to those who can use
it, to change its form and substance, and to government. ... If income distribution and risk
allocation is a partial function of law (of property)
transfer all rights in the asset through, e.g., then the law is an object of control for economic or
sale, or some rights through, e.g., rental. other gain ... whether the instances be tariff pro-
However, even though this definition sug- tection, oil subsidies, real estate agents' attempts to
gests that the right of ownership is an ex- ban "for sale" signs on private homes or any other
clusive right, ownership is not, and can type of property rights [101, 1971, p. 4441.
hardly be expected to be, an unrestricted It follows, of course, that a theory of
right. The right of ownership is an exclusive property rights cannot be truly complete
right in the sense that it is limited only by without a theory of the state. And, unfortu-
those restrictions that are explicitly stated nately, no such theory exists at present. The
in the law as it is interpreted from time to ongoing research by J. Buchanan [24,
time. Such restrictions may range from the 19621, R. McKean [75, 19711, W. Niskanen
substantial to the minor. For example, on [84, 1968 and 85, 19711, D. North [86,
one hand, there is the serious case where an 19721, G. Tullock [115, 19711 and other
individual's right of ownership in an asset scholars gives promise of filling the gap, but
cannot be transferred for a price higher this general line of investigation is still at a
than the ceiling price stipulated by the gov- preliminary stage. Of special interest here is
ernment; on the other is the situation where the fact that understanding of bureaucracy
a land owner is constrained from building a and the state can be developed from con-
fence within two feet of the property line. sideration of individual utility maximizing
In general, then, it is important to recog- behavior. Professor North argues that the
nize that the attenuation of private (or state has frequently traded inefficient prop-
state) property rights in an asset, through erty rights (e.g., licence to operate in a
the imposition of restrictive measures, af- closed market) for revenue, and in doing so
fects the owner's expectations about the throttled economic growth. Indeed, it can
uses to which he can put the asset, the be argued that changes in the content of
value of the asset to the owner and to oth- property rights depend on the relationship
ers, and consequently, the terms of trade. between an ex ante estimate of benefits to
Because of these interrelations, the term at- the ruling elite from changing the existing
tenuation represents a significant concept; property rights assignments and the ex ante
when used in the paper, it will always sig- or even ex post estimates of the costs to be
nify the existence of some degree of restric- incurred in policing and enforcing the
tion on the owner's rights to: ( i ) change changed structure of rights. If this reason-
the form, place, or substance of an asset, ing is valid, the "efficient" size of the politi-
(ii) transfer all rights to an asset to others cal organization should be affected by the
at a mutually agreed upon price. size of markets and the state's military en-
Finally, the point must be stressed that dowment, excluding considerations of ex
most of the restrictions discussed here are ante errors or inoperable probabilities.
those imposed by the state. To argue for a An exchange economy and new weapons . . . made
change in the content of the right of owner- ...a long struggle with numerous contenders . . .
ship, therefore, is to argue for a change in not only from within historically unified political
the allocation of resources to which legal units but also from without. . .. The contenders
support is given. In other words, as Samuels were in competition with each other and the key to
success was the fiscal revenues that the contenders
has noted: could command. Each state therefore endeavored
. . . opportunities for gain, whether pecuniary profit to price its services (i.e., taxes) in such a way as to
Furubotn and Peiouich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1141
. .
maximize present value. . The degree of monopoly prices) that the most valuable will b e utilized.
power of the state in its contractual relationship Second, competition among potential contract par-
with constituents reflected the degree to which other ticipants and a resource owner's ability to transfer
contenders appeared likely to be able to provide the the right to use his resource reduce the cost of en-
same set of services. In short, the opportunity costs ..
forcing the stipulated terms in a contract. because
of the constituents lay behind the contractual rela- competing parties will stand by to offer or accept
tionships and changes in opportunity costs lead to similar terms [28, 1970, p. 641.
efforts to alter the contract [86, North, 19721.
In general, the logic of competition (i.e.,
While systematic discussion of these themes the heeding of alternative uses) suggests
cannot be attempted here, the basic hy- that a more complete specification of indi-
pothesis that changes in property rights are vidual property rights diminishes uncer-
triggered by man's search for greater utility tainty and tends to promote efficient alloca-
does seem worth exploring. tion and use of resource^.^ Study of effi-
ciency, then, necessarily involves under-
11. Private Property Rights and Resource
standing of the institutional background
Allocation
and the conditions under which transac-
The standard theory of production and tions take place. By implication, the limita-
exchange can be criticized for its somewhat tions of the traditional theory are traceable,
limited applicability, but the approach has in part, to the highly simplified assumptions
still been able to provide fundamental in- made in this area. Specifically, the standard
sights into the problem of scarcity. Perhaps competitive model envisions a special sys-
its most significant accomplishment has tem where one particular set of private
been to explain and assess the efficiency property rights governs the use of all re-
characteristics of competitive organization. sources, and where the exchange, policing
Welfare theorists, in particular, have car- and enforcement costs of contractual activi-
ried the discussion in useful directions and, ties are zero. While this conception of the
on the basis of certain restrictive assump- business environment need not prevent use-
tions, have been able to establish the pre- ful analysis, it does have the effect of nar-
cise relationship between Pareto optimality rowing the range of phenomena that can be
and competitive equilibrium [8, Arrow, explained.
1!362; 9, Arrow, 1951; 10, Arrow and De-
' Specification of property rights in goods is
breu, 1954; 39, Debreu, 1959; 98, Quirk more often than not triggered by a change in
and Saposnik, 19681. Property rights con- technology and productivity of resources. As Dem-
siderations have not ~ l a y e da major role in setz has observed: "Changes in knowledge result in
changes in production functions, market values, and
this literature, but understanding of the aspirations. New techniques, new wa s of doing the
structure of property rights has direct rele- same things, and doing new things-& invoke harm-
vance for the questions at issue. It can be ful and beneficial effects to which society has not
been accustomed. It is my thesis in this part of the
shown, for example, that privately owned paper that the emergence of new property rights
resources will always tend to be allocated takes place in response to the desires of the in-
to the highest valued uses. As Cheung has teracting persons for adjustment to new cost re-
put it:
. .
sponsibilities . the thesis can be restated in a
slightly different fashion: property rights develop
Competition for and transferability of the ownership to internalize externalities when the gains of inter-
right in the market place thus perform two main nalization become larger than the cost of internali-
zation. Increased internalization, in the main, results
functions for ,contracting. First, competition con-
from changes in economic values, changes which
glomerates knowledge from all potential owners- stem from the development of new technology and
the knowledge of alternative contractual arrange- the opening of new markets, changes to which old
ments and uses of the resource; and transferability property rights are poorly attuned" [42, 1967, p.
of property rights ensures (via flexible relative 3501.
1142 Journal of Economic Literature

For purposes of broad classification, the two parties are always involved in an exter-
cases that fall outside the scope of tradi- nality situation.
tional economic theory can be said to arise The question is commonly thought of as one in
because: ( i ) actual market solutions are in- which A inflicts harm on B and what has to be de-
consistent with the marginal equivalences cided is: how should we restrain A? But this is
required for the general social optimum, wrong. W e are dealing with a problem of a recipro-
cal nature. To avoid the harm to B would inflict
and ( i i ) traditional theory has failed to ac- harm on A. The real question that has to be de-
count for the effects of various types and cided is: should A be allowed to harm B or should
degrees of attenuation of private property 'B be allowed to harm A? The problem is to avoid
rights in resources. The term "externality" is the more serious harm [33, Coase, 1960, pp. 1-21.
associated with the first point while the sec- For social policy, the fundamental issue
ond refers to the behavior of firms that do reduces to this. At any moment of time,
not pursue the classical profit maximization there is n legally sanctioned structure of
objective. Property rights scholars have ad- property rights in existence; thus, if the pre-
dressed themselves to both types of prob- vailing structure is to be modified by social
lems, and the following sections of the pa- action designed to reduce or eliminate the
per will discuss the basic thrust of their at- effects of an externality, taxes must be im-
tempt to extend the scope and coverage of posed on those who will gain from the pro-
conventional microeconomics. It must be posed legal change, and compensation paid
emphasized, however, that research on the to those who will suffer capital loss or loss
economics of property rights is still in its of satisfaction as a result of the new law
initial stage. Some important contributions [108, Sherman, 19691. Presumably, agree-
have been made but a great many questions ment of the terms of the tax-compensation
remain to be explored. In particular, while scheme can be reached through a political
the general implications of alternative process, but the basic mechanism here is one
property rights assignments and their of "trade." In principle, an individual A
effects on the use of resources have been seeking to modify the behavior of another
developed in some detail, formal equilib- individual B (who is generating an exter-
rium conditions for many cases have yet to nality) can engage in trade with the latter
be worked out. ( B ) and, then, both can move to preferred
positions on a "contract curve" where Pa-
1. Externalities retoequilibrium holds. For example, in the
The concept of externality is central to classical case of factory smoke nuisance,
the theory of economic policy but only re- gains from trade are possible for A and B if
cently have concerted attempts been made B gives up some or all of his rights to operate
to give the notion rigorous analytical defini- a smoke producing factory in exchange for
tion [23, Buchanan and Stubblebine, 1962; appropriate monetary compensation. AS in
26, Cheung, 1969; 33, Coase, 1960; 40, other trading situations, the benefits ob-
Demsetz, 1964; 43; Demsetz, 1969; 79, tained by A are purchased from B at a
Mishan, 1971; 114, Stigler, 19611. As might "price." Buchanan and Stubblebine have
be expected, questions of ownership rights summarized the welfare significance of this
figure prominently in the new discussions. type of case as follows:
According to the argument advanced by The important implication to be drawn is that full
Coase, Buchanan and others, adequate as- Pareto-equilibrium can never be attained via the
sessment of all the social costs associated imposition of unilaterally imposed taxes and sub-
with externalities requires recognition that sidies until all marginal externalities are eliminated.
Furubotn and Pejo~ich:Property Rights and Economic Theory 1143

If a tax-subsidy method, rather than "trade," is to ers. The case turns on the fact that a cost is
be introduced, it should involve bilateral taxes (sub- incurred by B when he pays an indemnity
sidies). Not only must B's behavior be modified so
as to insure that he will take the costs externally im-
to A in order to produce another unit of
posed on A into account, but A's behavior must be output or when B foregoes a bribe by A de-
modified so as to insure that he will take the costs signed to induce B to limit production. In
"internally" imposed on B into account. In such a Coase's familiar illustration, the equilibrium
double tax-subsidy scheme, the necessary Pareto- output of cattle is unaffected by the prop-
conditions would be readily satisfied [23, 1962, p.
3831.
erty relations specified and the allocation of
resources remains
Such an interpretation of externality is, of . . . Whether the $3 is a payment which the cattle-
course, quite distinct and leads to conclu- raiser has to make if he adds the third steer to his
sions that are different from those reached herd (which it would be if the cattle-raiser was
in the traditional Pigouvian model [13, Ba- liable to the farmer for damage caused to the crop)
tor, 1958; 76, Meade, 1952; 79, Mishan, or whether it is a sum of money which he would
have received if he did not keep a third steer (which
1971; 103, Scitovsky, 19541. It is important it would be if the cattle-raiser was not liable to the
to reemphasize that property rights are cru- farmer for damage caused to the crop) does not
cial to this new line of a n a l y ~ i s the
; ~ justifi- affect the final result. In both cases $3 is part of the
cation for compensation to B rests, ulti- cost of adding a third steer, to be included along
mately, on the idea that, at any given time, with the other costs [33, 1960, p. 71.
individuals can have "rights" to create cer- The result just discussed is based on the
tain types of "diseconomies." Thus, an indi- assumption that transactions costs are zero,
vidual ( B ) who is undertaking a lawful ac- but this simplification is recognized as un-
tivity in good faith ( e . g . , generating realistic. In general, the property rights ap-
smoke) must be compensated if there is to proach places great emphasis on the idea
be a change in the law that will redefine that externalities are associated with the
property rights and reduce his welfare posi- costs of defining, exchanging, policing, or
tion. enforcing property rights [40, Demsetz,
Despite the significance of property 1964 and 41, Demsetz, 19661. Whenever
rights assignments for individual welfare po- the private terms of exchange fail to ac-
sitions, Coase has shown that, in the ab- count for some harmful or beneficial effects
sence of transactions costs, the composition to the contractual parties or to others, the
of output in the economy is independent of market solution will appear inconsistent
the structure of property rights-except in- with the social value of the bundIe of prop-
sofar as changes in the distribution of erty rights in the goods that are exchanged.
wealth affect demand patterns [33, 19601. And such private-social divergences tend to
More concretely, the composition of output arise because of high transactions costs, or
is said to be independent of whether or not because of the existence of legal restraints
the individual creating diseconomies bears on the use and exchange of resources.
the liability for the damages caused to oth- 'Coase's analysis has been extended to cover
many types of property rights problems. For
'For example, once the two-sidedness of the example, Demsetz has recently applied Coase's
problem is understood, it follows that the existence analysis to the reserve clause in organized baseball-
of an externality does not necessarily justify gov- an important property right to owners of base-
ernment action to eliminate it. The fact is that: ball clubs-and was able to show that "with or
"The internal benefits from carrying out the ac- without the reserve clause the player will locate
tivity, net of costs, may be greater than the external where the value he places on amenities plus the
damage that is imposed on other parties" [23, value of his baseball talent is greatest" [44,
Buchanan and Stubblebine, 1962, p. 3811. Demsetz, 1971, p. 101.
1144 Journal of Economic Literature

The effects that high transactions costs ment of externalities. The seemingly end-
exert on the utilization of resources can be less division of externalities by types and
seen in a variety of economic examples [19, the frequent attempts at reclassifications
Bottomley, 1963; 27, Cheung, 1968; 55, Gor- have, in fact, undermined some economists:
don, 1954; 74, McKean, 1964; 104, Scott, confidence in the usefulness of standard
1955; 116, Turvey, 19641. Thus these costs theory and have given a boost to ad hoc
prevent an adequate market accounting theorizing. By contrast, the property rights
for: the beneficial effects of apple blossoms literature points in the direction of integra-
on the productivity of bees, the harmful tion. Its theme is that a general theory of
effects of sparks from passing trains on externality can be developed by extending
nearby crops, the noise from that neighbor's the received doctrine. What is thought to
air conditioner, etc. Similar problems arise be needed is a careful analysis of the con-
in considering why theater seats in Europe tent of the property rights conveyed in any
show a greater range of prices than those in transaction; and the major achievements of
the United States, or why there may be re- the approach can be summarized as
luctance on the part of private firms to un- follows.
dertake the training of workers in underde- First, transactions costs are found to con-
veloped countries. Illustrations abound, but tribute both to greater use of nonmarket
a typical situation is found in the case forms of exchange and to prices that di-
where free parking is available at a shop- verge from the social values of the goods
ping center. Here, shoppers pay for the exchanged. In consequence, the problem of
maintenance of the lot through their pur- producing the socially optimal output mix
chases at the center and, thus, confer bene- is made more difficult. For example, if the
fits on non-shopping parkers. To use a mar- transactions costs of using the price mecha-
ket price to ration the parking space, the nism to ration the space for parking are
price would have to cover the cost of re- greater than the revenues the parking lot
sources needed to conduct transactions. owner can obtain, he will either ration the
The result could well be that the cost of space on a first come, first served basis or
selling parking space would exceed the erect a "no trespassing" sign. The result of
value of the parking lot to potential users. using a nonmarket mechanism to ration the
As Demsetz has observed: space is that the landowner gains less than
We may end up allocating more resources to the the value of the good to society. It follows,
provision of control of parking than had we allowed of course, that the use of land as parking
free parking because of the resources needed to con- space win 6e reduced even if the social
duct transactions. . . . Those who purchase mer- value of parking space exceeds the costs [7,
chandise and indirectly pay for parking space may
prefer to substitute the smaller total cost of con-
Alchian and Demsetz, 19721.
structing additional spaces to accommodate free- Assuming that the objective is to reduce
loaders rather than ration out the non-buying park- the difference between privately perceived
ers by paying the required exchange costs minus the gains and costs and total gains and costs,
savings of constructing fewer parking spaces [40, the implications are clear. The analysis of
1964, p. 141.
various forms of externalities suggests that
The fact that numerous situations exist The literature on externalities is enormous anci
where contractual stipulations do not cap- growing fast. V. Smith [ I l l , 19691 classified
ture all social costs and benefits explains mesh externalities, stock externalities, and crowding
externalities for fishery alone. J. Meade [76, 19521
the alleged inability of microeconomic the- classified externalities according to physical attri-
ory to provide a uniform analytical treat- butes. See also the article by Mishan [79, 19711.
Furubotn and Pejouich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1145
either a reduction of the costs of transac- ical process, may well result in an excess of
tion, or an increase in the value of the good net social costs over net social benefits.
will result in fuller specification of property Again, Demsetz's zero-priced parking exam-
rights in that good and, hence, in an im- ple is a case in point. What the theory im-
provement in the accuracy of private ac- plies, then, is that the market should not be
counting. Relative reduction in transactions faulted for the existence of all externalities,
costs depends, inter alia, on technical pro- nor should all be eliminated. The optimal
gress. Thus, in Demsetz's example, a device solution in the short-run always requires a
such as the parking meter would lower careful balancing of the marginal social
transactions costs and enable the owner to costs and benefits from reducing externali-
ration the parking space via market pricing. ties. Moreover, in making the cost-benefit
A number of examples can, in fact, be cited calculations, due regard must be shown for
where technical inventions have led to im- the two-sidedness of the externality relation
proved specification of property rights in and for the initial structure of legal prop-
traded goods9 a n d to the reduction, if not erty rights.
the elimination, of the divergences between The logic of the property rights analysis
private and social costs and benefits [42, leads to still another crucial question. For,
Demsetz, 1967, pp. 350531. It is difficult given the fact that resources are used in
to predict whether future technological de- ways that differ from those that would ob-
velopments will make the establishment of tain if social costs and benefits were accu-
property rights progressively easier, but the rately represented in the terms of trade, it is
logic of the theory suggests that, ceteris important to know how, and to what extent,
paribus, old extemalities have diminishing alternative property rights assignments af-
importance in a dynamic economy-though fect the use of resources and the output
new ones may be allowed to develop. mix. That is, obviously, a major topic and
Second, the property rights approach one having extensive theoretical ramifica-
calls attention to the question of how far an tions. Consequently, all that can be done in
individual or the community should go in the present paper is to provide a taste of
the correction of existing externalities. If the subject; and, for convenience, we shall
the short-run is defined as a period during concentrate on a recent work by Roland
which technical progress and innovation McKean [73, 19701. While the McKean pa-
cannot be expected to reduce or eliminate per is directed toward a relatively narrow
external effects, a relevant policy issue must problem, the method of analysis and the
be: What constitutes the optimal pattern of line of reasoning have general applicability.
correction for extemalities in the short run? McKean's point of departure is the asser-
Of course, the fact that the very existence tion that accidental damages result in a spe-
of a large class of externalities can be ex- cial case of externalities and that the right
plained by high transactions costs suggests to avoid liability is a valuable property
that to make contractual stipulations more right affecting the value of goods that are
complete must be a costly undertaking. It traded. Then, since transactions costs are
follows that any indiscriminate attempt to positive, different assignments of liability
do something about externalities, either for damages must influence production pro-
through the market mechanism or the polit- cesses, the allocation of resources, the op-
tions open to consumers, etc. The paper
e D. North [86, 19721 traced the development of
property rights in Medieval Europe to changes in considers several ~ossibleliability assign-
cost-benefit calculations. ments such as customer liability, producer
1146 Journal of Economic Lite~ature

liability with and without defect, and tax- accepted as saleable, the action of the mar-
payer liability. The argument shows that ket would have eventually put the right to
different liability systems can be expected frequencies into the hands of those who
to yield different patterns of resource use could use them most efficiently. Then, even
bedause each of -the respective systems though some redistribution of health would
tends to be associated with a different total have taken place in favor of the initial own-
transactions cost. The following passage ers, the final allocation of frequencies and
from McKean, discussing the effects of pro- the composition of output would have
ducer liability, suggests the nature of the tended to be the same as those that would
analysis. have emerged if the frequencies had been
With the customer facing a lower probability of turned over initially to the most productive
being liable, relatively hazardous designs would be users. The government, however, chose to
less inattractive to him, and the demand curve for decree that radio frequencies belong to no
such products would rise relative to the demand one and that they should be, as they still
curve for comparatively safe products. With the
producer facing a higher probability of being liable
are, allocated by the government to those
and with his either carrying liability insurance or who satisfy certain administratively im-
paying damages, relatively hazardous designs would posed criteria. The latter include consider-
b e more costly, and the supply curve would de- ation of the personal characteristics of the
crease. On the basis of this shift in liability assign- applicants seeking the right to broadcast,
ment by itself, there is no presumption that the
quantity of hazardous products sold would change,
concern with the types of programs to be
and while the consumer would pay a higher price to broadcast, etc. [6, Alchian and Allen, 1972;
the producer, he would simply be forced to buy in- 32, Coase, 1959; 77, Meckling, 1968; 78, Mi-
surance from the producer instead of having the nasian, 1964; 113, Steiner, 19611.
option of insuring himself. The only thing that would It follows that the highest valued uses of
happen to the consumer's position is that he would
b e denied the opportunity of taking the risk. Since
radio and television cannot be achieved un-
that option would be preferred by some consumers, der these conditions; specifically, programs
especially by the poor, this would mean in effect a that would be more valuable from the mar-
rise in the price of hazardous products relative to ket point of view tend not to be produced.
the price of "safe" products, resulting in the end in In this form of externality, of course, the
some shift toward safer products and working to the
detriment of the poor [73, McKean, 1970, p. 6231.
disparity between social and private bene-
fits and costs should be attributed not to
Finally, it should be noted that some ex- transactions costs in the usual sense but to
ternalities can be attributed to legal re- the fact that transactions costs are made
straint on the use and exchange of re- prohibitely high by l a t ~ . ' ~
sources, rather than to high transactions
costs alone. A classic example is that of radio 2. Attenuation of Private Property Rights
and television. In the 1920s, anyone was al- There is strong empirical evidence to
lowed to broadcast on any frequency of his
" A group of scientists has recently argued that
choice. To stop the chaos that ensued, the "The present management of the electromagnetic
courts began to specify that the first user of spectrum has aroused sufficient concern to justify
a frequency had ownership claims on it. experiments in turning a portion of the spectrum
over to the market allocation. . . . W e have arti-
This initial distribution of private property .
culated a property system in the spectrum that . .
rights in radio frequencies could not, except makes exchanges possible without undue trans-
by a low probability accident, allocate the action and enforcement costs .. . and we have
demonstrated that traditional policy supports the
available frequencies to the highest-valued release of government-controlled resources to the
users. Nevertheless, if the rights had been private sector" [45, DeVany, et al., 1969, p. 15591.
Furubotn and Pejovich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1147

suggest that the behavior of many types of reckon with a greater or lesser reaction
firms deviates from the profit maximizing from the owners.
ideal upon which the standard theory of the Some years ago, Coase [34, 19371 com-
firm is built. The question that arises, there- bined the idea of comparative advantage
fore, is whether the standard theory can be with the concept of positive costs of trans-
extended so as to include models that are actions across markets to explain both the
not based on profit maximization as well as advantage of organizing resources within
those that are. And, as indicated earlier, the the firm and the basis of the firm's optimal
property rights literature takes the affirma- size. A major conclusion was that:
tive position here. It is argued that in many . . . at the margin, the cost of organizing within the
cases where the behavior of business firms firm will be equal either to the cost of organizing in
cannot be rationalized by the simple profit another firm or to the costs involved in leaving the
maximization hypothesis, an explanation is transaction to be organized by the price mechanism
[34, 1937, p. 4041.
still ~ossiblewithin the general framework
of the standard theory. What is required is While the importance of transactions
that the concept of income or wealth maxi- costs for the existence and size of firms can
mization be replaced by that of utility max- hardly be ignored, such costs are not the
imization, and that the analysis take into only elements that need consideration. Ac-
account the effects of changes in the con- cording to Alchian and Demsetz, nonsepar-
tent of property rights in resources on the ability of the total product of several differ-
actions of decision makers. Under these ent inputs imposes on firms the very crucial
conditions, the behavior of managers be- problem of metering inputs and metering
comes the key for understanding the alloca- rewards [7, 19721. That is, the firm faces
tion and use of resources by corporations, the cost of detecting the marginal produc-
government bureaus, and other organiza- tivities of cooperating inputs; and accurate
tions. Ideally, the objective is to introduce assessments must be made because the rela-
greater empirical content into the theory of tive efficiency of team production depends
the firm. It is neces'sary to develop a refuta- on the firm's ability to bring changes in re-
ble theory by identifying those elements in wards to bear on those responsible for
the institutional structure that affect the changes in output. In the absence of a sen-
cost to managers of attenuating the nominal sitive reward system, the productivity levels
ownership rights in existence.ll In other of cooperating inputs will tend to be less
words, managers can, at some cost, engage than those that are potentially possible.
in discretionary behavior and divert a por- Such considerations lead directly to the
tion of the organization's resources to their integration of utility analysis into the theory
own ends. But by appropriating pecuniary of the firm. Granting that nonpecuniary
or nonpecuniary benefits for themselves, goods such as leisure, attractive working
the managers necessarily infringe on the in- conditions, time to converse with fellow
terests of the owners (the individuals pos- workers, etc., constitute arguments in an in-
sessing ultimate authority) and must dividual's utility function, and accepting the
existence of non-separability of the firm's
"The analysis has been extended to the factors
that affect the right of ownership in human cap- total product, the logic of economics sug-
ital and the corresponding effects on the demand gests that cooperating inputs will have in-
and supply of various categories of labor [5, Alchi- centives to shirk. It follows that shirking by
an, 1969; 15, Becker, 1957; 70, Martin, 1969; 71,
Martin, 1971; 91, Pejovich, 1970; 96, Porter, 1954; some inputs will result in a lower total out-
100, Rottenberg, 19621. put for the firm. At the same time, however,
1148 Journal of Economic Literature

the individuals who shirk will enjoy greater demand for the firm's output is infinitely
utility or satisfaction because the major cost elastic; and ( d ) the cost of policing the be-
of shirking (assuming it goes undetected) is havior of cooperating inputs is zero. Against
shifted to others. Thus, a critical problem of this background, profit maximization can be
control exists, and: rationalized and a confident prediction can
... The presence of different owners of the several be made about the kinds of inputs the re-
jointly used inputs in the 'team production process sidual claimant will tend to own. We know
heightens the problem of shirking-i.e., the unde- the law of demand governs the rate at
tected marginal productivities of each input that are which nonpecuniary goods are purchased.
reduced below the payments for their services. I n
sum, the information, detection, and transmission is
But the cooperating inputs find that the
more expensive [7, Alchian and Demsetz, 19721. cost of acquiring nonpecuniary goods
through shirking (or otherwise) is prohib-
Obviously, if shirking is to be checked, itive and, consequently, purchase none. The
someone must have both the right to moni- owner also finds the cost of purchasing non-
tor the performance of team members and pecuniary goods for himself to be prohib-
sufficient incentive not to shirk himself. To itively high. This condition prevails be-
this end, he must possess specific property cause, at equilibrium, he is assured of no
rights including: ( i ) the right to receive more than a survival profit. The result of
the residwzl after all other inputs have been these forces is, of course, the central em-
paid contractual amounts, (ii) the right, phasis on profit maximizing behavior. Fur-
however qualified, to terminate or revise ther, the owner's commitments to make
the membership of the team (i.e., the pos- payments to other inputs, together with the
sessor of these rights is a central party to a required saleability of his property rights,
set of bilateral contracts), and (iii) the imply that the owner's wealth will take the
right to sell those rights specified under ( i ) form of land, buildings, machines, etc.
and (ii).,This bundle of property rights de- That is, the owner will be led to those
fines, according to Alchian and Demsetz, goods that can be transferred to others and
ownership of the classical capitalist firm. whose market prices reflect expected eco-
Moreover, it is precisely the analysis of nomic developments.
changes in the content of these rights that
requires study. By considering how the at- 111. New Directions in the Theory
tenuation of basic property rights affects of the Firm
the actions of decision makers, it becomes Once the basic ideas underlying the
possible to secure new insight into the be- property rights approach are accepted, the
havior of various types of firms-corpora- way is open to establish a uniform method
tions, regulated firms, not-for-profit firms, of analysis that can be applied to a wide
etc. range of different firms. Thus, the themes
In the simplest application, the property that appear in the discussion of the classical
rights approach can be used to explain the capitalist firm are repeated, with certain
characteristic operating conditions of the variations, in other areas. By focusing on
classical firm. The demonstration is based such things as the form of contractual
on a number of familiar assumptions. Thus, agreements, and the trade-off relation be-
it is said: ( a ) The entrepreneur possesses tween nonpecuniary goods and income, it is
the basic ownership rights as defined above possible to bring out the points of similarity
in (i)-(iii); ( b ) each decision maker dis- and difference between business organi-
plays utility maximizing behavior; ( c ) the zations of quite different character, and to
Furubotn a n d Pejouich: Property Rights a n d Economic Theory 1149
make systematic statements about the prob- through its emphasis on the fundamental
able behavior of any firm. This section will interplay between institutional structure
be devoted to the application of the new and economic incentives.
methods to four distinct types of firms: (1) The modern corporation is distinctive be-
the modem corporation, ( 2 ) the regulated cause it differs in one essential respect from
firm, ( 3 ) the not-for-profit firm, and ( 4 ) the classical firm as defined by Alchian and
the socialist firm. Demsetz 17, 19721. Specifically, the owners
of a modern corporation have reduced abil-
1. The Modern Corporation ity to revise or terminate the membership of
Observation indicates that profit maxi- the team. Thus, the owners' bundle of prop-
mization is not the sole objective of the typ- erty rights in the corporation is attenuated
ical corporation and, hence, a question compared to that of the classical firm. Op-
arises as to why this traditional goal of the erationally, this attenuation of stockholders'
firm has been abandoned. It is often said rights in the firm takes the form of a re-
that the dispersion of stockholding com- duced ability of the owners to control the
bined with management's advantages in a decisions made by the managers. This is
proxy fight have led to a rise in the power significant, of course, because the managers'
of managers and have reduced their depen- decisions affect the present value of the
dence on the owners [16, Berle and Means, firm.

1968, Ch. 4-5 and 17, Berle, 1959, Ch. 21. It should be noted that the attenuation of
At the same time, the negatively sloped de- the stockholders' property rights in the firm
mand curve facing the corporation implies and the "rule of management" result not
a degree of monopoly power in the market from legal restraints on private property
and makes the managers' relative indepen- rights, but from the costs to the owners of
dence from the owners effective. The gen- detecting and policing managerial decisions
eral consequence is that the managers are and of enforcing wealth maximizing behav-
able to pursue their own goals within cer- ior [63, Larner, 1966, pp. 779 and 102, Samu-
tain limits and, thus, tend to direct the firm elson, 1966, pp. 89-90]. If, the attenuation
away from the profit maximizing position of stockholders' rights derives from the fact
that represents the owners' desideratum.12 that the costs of detecting, policing, and en-
This basic interpretation can be extended forcing appropriate managerial behavior
in various ways and, indeed, many new exceeds the expected benefits, it can be ar-
models have been developed to account for gued that widespread dispersion of stock is
different possible business goals.13The trou- damaging to the owners [62, Kaysen, 1965,
ble is that such models usually direct them- p. 431. For, the greater the dispersion of
selves to special situations and have rather stock ownership' in the firm, the higher will
limited applicability. By contrast, the prop- be the costs to stockholders of reassigning
erty rights approach attempts to provide a decision making authority, and the easier it
more general theoretica1 framework will be for management to substitute other
objectives for the goal of wealth maximiza-
"Two interesting papers are those by Hindley
tion. In short, the stockholders' willingness
[59, 19701 and Kamerschan [el, 19681. to tolerate reduced wealth is determined by
l 3 Examples of these ad hoc theories include: the costs required to keep managers faithful
Baumol's [14, 19591, Bronfenbrenner's 121, 19601, to the wealth maximization criterion [69,
Cooper's [36, 19491, Penrose's [95, 19591, Reder's
[99, 19471, Shubik's [log, 19611, and Weintraub's Marris, pp. 254-601.
[120, 19491. By conceiving of the basic ~ r o b l e mas
1150 Journal of Economic Literature

one involving trade-off relations, it is possi- Heyne, 1971 and 67, Manne, 1970, p. 81. In
ble to use conventional theory to infer the general, the greater the stockholders' dissat-
behavior of the corporation regardless of isfaction, the more shares relative to their
what the goals are. Management has the total number will be sold and the lower will
power to substitute away from profit be the price of the company's stock relative
(stockholders' interests) to gain other de- to that of other companies. The latter con-
siderata (managers' interests ). But man- dition, of course, presents a clear danger to
agement's efforts in this direction will be management. Thus, the owners' freedom to
constrained by the managers' own estimates sell shares in a market that reflects the capi-
of the stockholders' cost-benefit calculus. It talized value of current managerial deci-
follows that an important analytical ques- sions tends to set limits on the power of
tion is to consider the factors that affect this managers to pursue their own objectives at
managerial constraint; and, thence, to de- the expense of profit.
termine how well the market system pro- (ii) Managerial rewards. The fact that a
tects the stockholders' wealth. manager is paid to increase the wealth of
( i ) Market valuation. Insofar as stock stockholders suggests that the present value
prices reflect the present value of the ex- of his future rewards will be strongly cor-
pected future consequences of current related with his past and present perfor-
managerial policies, it would seem logical to mance. This understanding of the future
expect a lower bid price for stocks of corpo- demand for and cost of the manager's ser-
rations with dispersed ownership. This is so vices flows directly from the conventional
because market valuation should tend to theory of production and exchange. In any
protect stockholders from less diligent con- event, the manager considering the pursuit
cern by management for their wealth. of objectives other than profit maximization
There is, however, a lack of empirical evi- must be constrained by his own estimate of
dence to support this expectation, and one the possible cost of such action in terms of
possible explanation for the result is as lower expected future earnings [4, Alchian,
follows. Given the amount of information 1969, p. 3441. Presumably, his decision will
about investment alternatives, a person who be made by balancing the prospective ben-
buys a share of stock must voluntarily di- efits from independent behavior against this
vest himself from the control of his investa- cost.
ble funds to hire trained professionals whose (iii) Competition among managers. State-
investment judgment he believes is superior ments like "no group of stockholders will be
to his own. If the person chooses to sell that able under ordinary circumstances to mus-
stock, he is likely to be expressing his disap- ter enough votes to challenge the rule of
proval of the management of that firm; and management" [63, Larner, 1966, p. 7791 are
the fact that he "fires" the management frequently found in scholarly papers and
when he sells his share is not without conse- imply that management is a monolithic
quences even in a corporation with dis- group with common interests and no inter-
persed ownership. Any sale of a company's personal conflicts or rivalries. If such esti-
stock affects the stock's price in precise pro- mates were correct, it should be possible to
portion to the total number of shares sold. observe longer tenure of office for managers
In other words, the power a person has over in a corporation with dispersed ownership,
management is directly related to the greater compensation for managers, and
amount of wealth he invests in that corpo- smaller profits [4, 1969, p. 3411. But, again,
ration relative to other investors [58, the evidence to support these inferences is
Furubotn and Pejouich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1151

still to be presented. In the absence of em- tion on the board of directors were to dou-
pirical evidence, the conventional economic ble" [123, 1963, p. 1050].14
logic must be given some credence. That is, Following Becker's pathbreaking work on
according to theory, we should expect that: the Economics of discrimination [15, 19571
( a ) competition exists among managers, the manager's consumption of nonpecuni-
( b ) managers move to better jobs by supe- ary goods was incorporated formally into
rior performance on present jobs, and ( c ) the theory of production and exchange; and
managers have incentives to try to gain per- such consumption was recognized as a type
sonal advancement by eliminating "ineffi- of behavior that is completely rational and
cient" behavior in others connected with hence subject to systematic analysis. Becker
the firm's operations. It follows that the used a taste for discrimination as a device
stockholders stand to gain from this type of to introduce nonpecuniary goods into the
competition. manager's utility function [15, 1957, p. 341.
From what has been said, there are But, in general, the manager can be con-
grounds for believing that stockholders' ceived as purchasing any sort of desiderata
wealth has protection in modern corpora- for himself at the expense of stockholders'
tions. Yet it also seems true that the ob- wealth. The particular "goods" consumed
served behavior of managers does deviate might include such things as luxurious of-
from the pattern that would insure profit fices, beautiful receptionists, less efficient
maximization. To reconcile this "contradic- but more desirable employees, frequent
tion," the property rights approach focuses business trips to meetings in Las Vegas and
on the forms the deviations from profit Palm Beach, etc.
maximizing behavior take and, then, con- In this same vein, Williamson [122, 1964
siders the effects these various policies have and 123, 19631 made managerial objectives
on the vector of payments to managers and an integral part of the analysis of the firm
on the performance of the firm. The thrust and developed a number of models to ex-
of the argument is as follows. plore the implications of discretionary be-
First, the size of the firm has an important havior. Figure 1 gives a simplified geomet-
bearing on managerial compensation. ric presentation of the essential ideas.
Larger staff and gross assets tend to raise Curve AA shows the maximum profit ob-
the manager's salary because his marginal tainable by the firm with each level of staff
product depends on the size of the re- and discretionary spending. If the interests
sources affected by his decisions [72, Mayer, of the stockholders were the sole concern of
1960, pp. 189-951. Thus, the manager has the manager, "staff' would only be sought
reason to set expenditures on staff and in- in order to increase profit and equilibrium
vestment at levels that exceed those re- would be attained at K. But assuming the
quired by immediate profit considerations manager has a positive taste for "staff," in-
alone. As Williamson has noted, an impor- difference curves like UU become relevant.
tant and testable implication is that "high Curve UU reflects the manager's subjective
internal representation on the board of di- evaluation of different combinations of
rectors favors attention to managerial ob-
jectives, and this is manifested in a high "Williamson argues that a number of studies
earnings-retention rate" [123, Williamson, such as Gordon's [54, 19621 and Scott's [105,
1963, p. 10511. He estimates that "the re- 19621 have ~ i e l d e dresults that appear less "peculi-
ar" when interpreted within his analytical frame-
tained-earnings ratio would increase by work; that is, within the property rights approch
about 12 percent if the internal representa- framework.
1152 Journal of Economic Literature
Profit stant utility to the manager. Then the tangency of
.
the utility function with the feasibility function . .
would yield the solution values of profit and types of
nonpecuniary managerial benefits for the managers
[2, 1965, p. 381.

It would seem that the manager of a dis-


persed ownership corporation tends to re-
ceive a greater total return for his services
than managers in less dispersed firms. The
conventional wisdom, however, suggests
that competition for jobs that permit discre-
tionary spending by managers will act to
lower the pecuniary salaries attaching to
\ Staff
such positions. The property rights ap-
proach emphasizes another facet of the
case; and the analysis is largely indepen-
dent of the strength or weakness of the
market equalization process. Here, the im-
portant fact is that the consumption of non-
profit and "staff." In the figure, the best at- pecuniary goods is inferior to an equivalent
tainable operating position for the manager increase in money income-because money
is at L where he is maximizing his utility usually offers a greater range of choices [92,
function subject to the constraint of the op- Pejovich, 1971, pp. 145-471. For example,
portunity set AKLA. Then, the vertical dis- assume the manager of a dispersed owner-
tance between L and K represents the trans- ship corporation consumes a bundle of non-
fer of wealth from the stockholders to the pecuniary goods that costs the stockholders
manager that is made possible through the $100 but is worth only $20 to him. Then,
attenuation of the former's property rights even if competition lowers his pecuniary
in the firm. The transfer has to be equal to salary by $20 so that the manager is no bet-
or less than the cost to stockholders of en- ter off than managers in less dispersed
forcing a return t o K. Williamson provides firms, his vector of rewards is both diferent
a number of examples that indicate the or- and costlier.
ganizational and market circumstances in In general, the form of managerial com-
which various managerial objectives can be pensation in more dispersed corporations
realized and, in the process, suggests the implies greater outlays in such firms than in
general validity of his model. less dispersed firms. Nevertheless, the re-
Alchian is in general agreement with this turns to investors in the former group are at
line of analysis, but has argued that Wil- least as high as in the latter; and, thus, it
liamson's model could be improved by sep- must be inferred that the more dispersed
arating the pecuniary from the nonpecuni- ownership corporations possess some im-
ary income going to the manager. portant advantage that permits them to
finance the higher costs of the reward vec-
If quantities of these nonpecuniary benefits were
explicitly included in the utility function and also
tor going to management. Economic logic
indicated along one of the axes of the graph, we also suggests that consumers must be pay-
could draw iso-utility curves, showing continuations ing a higher price for output than they
of pecuniary and nonpecuniary goods that yield con- would be if the entire payment to managers
Furubotn and Pejouich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1153
were in the form of pecuniary income, but the owners' right to the residual [7, Alchian
still a price lower than the one that would and Demsetz, 19721.
exist if there were no dispersed ownership Given this form of attenuation of prop-
corporations [4, Alchian, 1969, p. 3451. The erty rights, the logic of the property rights
special productivity advantage dispersed approach suggests that stockholders will be
corporations seem to enjoy tends to moder- disposed to tolerate behavior in managers
ate the price level. that would be repressed under competition.
The question of what constitutes the With regulation, and an upper limit on
likely source of the productivity advantage profits, managers can pursue their own in-
is yet to be answered satisfactorily. Alchian, terests quite extensively without reducing
however, has suggested that the answer can the owners' wealth.
possibly be found by investigating the in- In effect, the managers find it virtually
tra-corporation allocation process. costless to translate the firm's potential
.
The internal capital and personnel market . . within profits over and above the "fair return" into
.
General Electric . . is superior to the atomistic, so- consumption of nonpecuniary goods [2, Al-
called, pure competitive market and is superior be- chian, 1965, pp. 30-41 and 92, Pejovich,
cause there are specialists within General Electric 1971, pp. 144481. The situation is such
who are rewarded more fully for collecting and
evaluating information . . . I conjecture that the
that the managers capture the benefits of
wealth growth of General Electric derives precisely higher profits and conceal the true profits
from its superiority of its internal markets for ex- from the regulatory agency by reporting
change and reallocation of resources-a superiority higher costs of doing business. This upward
.
arising from . . cheaper information. . . Many . adjustment in cost curves and the subse-
'knowledge effects' that would be externalistic in an
ordinary market are converted into beneficial in-
quent effects on the price-output solution
ternalities within the firm as incentives and rewards implies that the managers, rather than con-
to those producing them [4, 1969, p. 3491. sumers, appropriate the major if not the en-
tire share of the stockholders' loss of wealth.
2. Regulated Firms The works of Alchian and Kessel [I, 19621,
Regulating agencies impose a "fair re- Averach and Johnson [ l l , 19621, Becker
turn" criterion on firms such as public utili- [15, 19571, Eckert [47, 19681, Levine [64,
ties, telephone companies, etc. The regu- 19691, Sherman [107, 19701, etc. argue on
lating agency's basic objective is to ensure both logical and empirical grounds that the
that the actual return to a firm is at or close price of nonpecuniary goods is lower to the
to the "fair return" level; and to accomplish manager of a regulated firm than to his col-
this end, the agency is able to apply pres- league in a modern corporation and that
sure for upward or downward price adjust- the manager of the regulated firm consumes
ments as needed. Since entry into a regu- more of these nonpecuniary goods. The re-
lated industry is closed or carefully con- sults are directly related to the valuation of
trolled, the attainable residual of an exis- shares in a regulated industry. The attenua-
ting firm is likely to exceed the fair return tion of property rights in the residual means,
standard. However, the agency in its role as quite simply, that the market valuation of
guardian of the public interest is supposed the future consequences of current manage-
to pass on any such excess profits to the rial policies is less significant to the owner
consumer by way of a lower price. The at- of a regulated firm. Thus, an important fac-
tenuation of the bundle of property rights tor that raises the price of nonpecuniary
that defines ownership of the regulated firm goods to the manager of a normal corpora-
takes on a specific form: legal restraint on tion is absent.
1154 Journal of Economic Literature

3. Not-for-Profit Firms ter, 19681. For example, there exists a sig-


The types of firms belonging to this cate- nificant degree of similarity in the content of
gory are varied: universities [25, Buchanan the bundle of property rights defining own-
and Devletoglou, 1970 and 65, Levy, 19681, ership of the Soviet firm and the content of
mutual savings and loan associations [83, the bundle defining ownership of the mod-
Nicols, 19671, foundations, sports associa- ern capitalist corporation. In the latter or-
tions, hospitals [29, Clarkson, 1970; 82, ganization, we know that hired managers
Newhouse, 1970 and 106, Shalit, 19711, etc. have some freedom to pursue their own in-
Nevertheless, they have an important ele- dependent interests. Given the high detec-
ment in common. The crucial determining tion, policing, and enforcement costs, the
characteristic of all these diverse institu- manager of a dispersed ownership capitalist
tions is this: No one can claim the right to firm finds the "prices" of various types of
appropriate the residual [7, Alchian and utility producing behaviors to be relatively
Demsetz, 19721. In other words, the future low, and he "purchases" certain of these be-
consequences of current managerial deci- haviors at the expense of stockholders' in-
sions cannot be capitalized. Thus, manage- terests. Indeed, knowledge of the institu-
rial decisions are costly to evaluate and eco- tional structure makes it possible to predict
nomic theory suggests that, under such con- such specific practices as managerial con-
ditions, the managers will use potential sumption of nonpecuniary income, mainte-
profits to obtain more nonpecuniary sources nance of a ratio of retained earning to
of utility. In addition, some advantages are profits in excess of the stockholders' time
likely to be reaped from tie-in-sales (the preference, etc. But when the manager's
customer will get his loan approved if he position in the capitalist firm is viewed in
buys insurance from the company owned these terms, it is but a short step to the rec-
by the manager of the mutual savings and ognition that the Soviet manager occupies
loan association [83, Nicols, 1967, p. an essentially similar position in his firm.
304]), and artificial shortages (pricing a That is, the relationship between the Soviet
good below its equilibrium price [6, Alchian manager and the state is analogous to that
and Allen, 1972, pp. 144-473) can be cre- between the capitaIist manager and the
ated to permit the manager to trade favors. stockholders. The costs to the state of de-
That is, the margin between the artificially tecting, policing, and enforcing a desired
low price and the true cost can be used to pattern of behavior in the manager are ob-
bargain for an increment of utility. In gen- viously greater than zero and, in fact, can
eral, then, the management of the not-for- be substantial. Therefore, the Soviet man-
profit firm has unusual scope for increasing ager is able, within his own estimate of
its nonpecuniary income at the expense of these costs, to attenuate the state's owner-
the firm's customers and patrons. ship in the firm; or, what amounts to the
same thing, use some of the firm's resources
to increase his personal satisfaction
4. The Socialist Firm
(utility) at the expense of the government
The property rights approach has also objectives [52, Furubotn and Pejovich,
proved to be useful in interpreting the ob- 1972; 81, Moore, 1971; 89, Pejovich, 19691.
served behavior of the firm operating Observers of the Soviet economy have of-
within a socialist environment [30, Clayton, ten called attention to the tendency of man-
1971; 31, Clayton, 1972; 53, Furubotn, 1971; agers to violate Soviet regulations to protect
80, Moore, 1972; 81, Moore, 1971; 88, Nut- their own interests and gain some room for
Furubotn and Pejouich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1155
independent policy making.15 These so- Still another area of application for the
called "informal" activities, however, are property rights approach is found in the la-
easily incorporated into the standard theory bor-managed firm of Yugoslavia [48, Furu-
of production and exchange through the botn, 1971; 49, Furubotn and Pejovich,
use of the property'rights approach. Thus, 1970; 50, Furubotn and Pejovich, 19701.
the Soviet manager's desire for larger allo- Since the economic reform of 1965, the in-
cations of productive inputs (including la- stitutional structure has been such that the
bor), his interest in maintaining unreported employees of the Yugoslav firm o w n the re-
stocks of imputs and outputs, and his ten- sidual. Further, the workers, through a dem-
dency to understate the productive effi- ocratically elected Workers' Council, are
ciency of his plant can all be rationalized as empowered to revise or terminate contrac-
strategies to improve his personal position tual stipulations. Nevertheless, the content
[52, Furubotn and Pejovich, 19721. of the employees bundle of property rights
Formally, the problem can be understood in the firm differs from that of stockholders
as one where the manager seeks to maxi- in the West. Significantly, Yugoslav workers
mize his utility function subject to certain can neither sell their rights to others nor
technical and institutional constraints. Not take them away when they leave the em-
only does such a model offer a rational and ploy of the firm. For, under Yugoslav law,
systematic explanation of the observed be- an individual has no ownership rights in the
havior of the Soviet manager, but provides, firm's capital stock, merely the right of use
in addition, some insights into the effects of of that capital. Thus, a person acquires the
managerial decisions on the operation of right to a share in the residual by joining
the economic system as a whole. For exam- the firm and loses all his rights when he
ple, it can be shown that the utility maxi- leaves it. Moreover, the firm has a legal ob-
mizing behavior of the Soviet manager ligation to maintain the value of its capital
helps to reduce the waste and inefficiencies stock indefinitely (via depreciation and
of the central economic plan. That is, the other allocations from the residual).
Soviet government profits from the ability The situation of the employees of the Yu-
(and willingness) of the Soviet manager to goslav firm differs, then, from that of stock-
"misbehave" 193, Pejovich, 1972, pp. 75-
761. Moreover, contrary to the opinions of
most Western economists, it appears that For example: ". . . it remains true that the structure
of the Soviet economy does little effectively to
the Soviet manager has strong incentives to encourage the search for the new at the local level,
innovate provided he can choose the rate at and not a little to discourage it" [87, Nove, 1969,
which the effects of the technical improve- pp. 167-711; and ". . . Managers have, furthermore,
shown only slight interest in reducing cost-since
ments are made known to the state.16 each cost reduction is integrated into the subse-
quent plan" [112, Spulber, 1962, p. 681. On the
other hand, Furubotn and Pejovich (using the
zIThe literature on this point is simply too property rights approach) were led to the conclusion
voluminous to be quoted. For exam le, any col- that "There are forces within the Soviet economy
lection of readings such as BornsteinPs [18, 19701 that can promote innovative behavior. Despite the
and Prybyla's [97, 19691 contains at least several apparent lack of incentives at the micro eco-
articles on this problem. Probably the best treat- nomic level, the operation of managerial self-interest
ment of the nature of the relationship between the is sufficient to initiate change. The existence of this
Soviet government and the manager is Zaleski's innovative potential is important, of course, because
[124, 19671. it helps to explain how the Soviet economy can
"Most authors have missed this point because experience some economic advances in an environ-
the Soviet system provides no incentives to the ment that is ridden with waste and inefficiencies"
manager to innovate and announce his innovation. [52, 19721.
1156 Journal of Economic Literature

holders in the West on two major counts.17 "The confusion and inefficiency that this
First, the cost to Yugoslav workers of detect- (the differential between the rate of inter-
ing, policing, and enforcing an appropriate est on owned assets and the rate of return
mode of behavior in the manager can be as- from internal investment in non-owned cap-
sumed to be lower. There is some uncer- ital goods) will generate . . . will be easily
tainty here, however, because it is not en- recognized by anyone with even a rudimen-
tirely clear that the employees' limited tary training in economics" [117, 19711.
knowledge of business opportunities (com- It does not seem unreasonable to say that
pared to that of professionals in the West many phenomena observed in the Yugoslav
[80, Moore, 1972]), coupled with the ab- economy can be given plausible explana-
sence of market valuation in Yugoslavia of tion if the implications of the special
the future consequences of current manage- property rights structure are traced through
rial policies, is offset by their on-the-job ob- systematically. Our theory tells us that the
servations of the manager's behavior.18 Sec- content of the bundle of property rights
ond, the employees of the Yugoslav firm that defines ownership in the Yugoslav firm,
face two fundamentally different wealth-in- together with the absence of a system of
creasing alternatives: ( i ) the option to capital markets, will affect the workers'
leave a part of the residual with the firm to time preference and their choice of invest-
purchase additional capital goods, or (ii) ment alternatives [49, 1970 and 50, 19701.
the option to take the entire residual out as These conditions suggest, in turn, that the
wages and, then, to invest individually in banking system will tend to take on a cru-
savings accounts, jewelry, or in anything cial role in freeing the rate of investment
else the law allows. It is important to reem- from the limitations imposed by the rate of
phasize, however, that there is a significant voluntary savings [51, Furubotn and Pejo-
difference in the conditions of ownership un- vich, 1971; 57, Hanvonen, 1970; 121, White,
der ( i ) and (ii), and this difference affects 19711. Thus, it is possible to predict such
the comparison of returns in the respective events as the growing inflationary pressure,
areas [48, Furubotn, 1971 and 90, Pejovich, the serious liquidity crisis faced by firms,
19691. Since the return from the joint in- and the high rate of unemployment that
vestment in capital goods via retained earn- have characterized recent Yugoslav history.
ings is received in the form of incremental The property rights analysis also lends
wages and for only as long as the employee some inadvertent support to the position of
remains with the firm, the required internal those Yugoslavs who are opposed to the
rate of return on such investment must be rapid expansion of the market mechanism.
substantially higher than the rate of re- For, rather naively, the proponents of eco-
turn on fully owned assets to make cate- nomic reform in Yugoslavia seem to expect
gory ( i ) investment i referable to category the operation of market forces to yield pre-
(ii) . The "equalizing" differentia1 between cisely the same results there as in the West.
the two rates can be estimated and is And the reformers are caught by surprise
attributable, as noted, to differences in the when the results appear to be different.
content of property rights. To quote Vanek: Their position with the ruling elite in Yugo-
slavia is then weakened, while that of the
"The property rights approach is implicit in so-called "centralists" grows stronger. Yet,
Domar's [46, 19661 and Ward's [119, 19571 the problem posed is not really so puzzling.
analyses.
'*This point can easily be deduced from an Market forces work in quite normal ways in
excellent paper by Bajt [12, 19681. the Yugoslav system; the difficulty is that
Furubotn and Pejovich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1157
the reformers have failed to incorporate the tail for each case studied. By making opti-
behavioral effects of property relations into mization models more general, the property
the standard economic theory of production rights literature permits a greater range of
and exchange [94, Pejovich, 19731. institutional data to be considered and,
thus, widens the applicability of the theory
IV. Some General Observations of production and exchange.
The preceding sections have attempted ( 3 ) There is confidence that the market
to give a systematic account of the major logic can be applied fruitfully to a very
themes found in the property rights litera- great range of practical problems. Thus, the
ture that has grown up in the last few de- focus of discussion is on economic efficiency
cades. In a sense, it is somewhat artificial to and the conditions under which markets
think of the property rights contributions as should be, or should not be, extended into
falling into a distinct and separate area of new areas.
specialization. For, as we have seen, a great ( 4 ) Strong concern is shown for the indi-
variety of topics has been treated; and vidualist basis of choice; the preferences or
there is no absolute way to establish which values of an individual are assumed to be
works deserve inclusion in the property revealed only through his market or politi-
rights category and which do not. More im- cal behavior. Social welfare functions are,
portant, the property rights analysis tends therefore, either ignored or ruled out on
to build on and merge with the traditional grounds that such constructs have use only
theory so that, in the extreme, one might be when choices are to be made by some
tempted to say: microeconomic theory agency or group external to the individuals
prbperly developed is the property rights directly affected.
approach. But, whatever the deeper ques- ( 5 ) A central objective is to establish op-
tions of classification, there is some conve- erationally meaningful propositions about
nience in conceiving of a property rights lit- the economy. Theory and empirical study
erature and this body of writings does seem tend to be blended so as to develop hy-
to possess certain characteristic features. potheses that are subject to direct test and
The latter may be described as follows: verification.
( 1) Maximizing behavior is accepted as To say that the property rights literature
the norm; each decision maker is assumed has these distinguishing characteristics is,
to be motivated by self-interest and to of course, not to suggest that other ap-
move efficiently to the most preferred oper- proaches share none of the qualities noted,
ating position open. Thus, the individual, or that other lines of investigation are with-
whether he be a Soviet manager or a capi- out merit. Nevertheless, the property rights
talist entrepreneur, is supposed to pursue analysis does offer a fresh and useful way of
his own goals within the limits allowed by looking at economic problems. Substantial
the structure of the system in which he is advances have already been achieved and
operating and to reach an equilibrium posi- the literature gives evidence of continuing
tion where utility is as great as it can be. vitality and promise of future accomplish-
( 2 ) The institutional environment in ment.
which economic activity takes place tends
to be specified with precision. In particular, REFERENCES
the existing property relations and the ex- 1. ALCHIAN, A. AND KESSEL,R. "Competi-
change, policing, and enforcement costs of tion Monopoly and the Pursuit of
contractual activities are spelled out in de- Money" in NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECO-
1158 Journal of Economic Literature

NOMIC RESEARCH. Aspects of labor eco- 12. BAJT, A. "Property in Capital and in the
nomics. Princeton: Princeton Univer- Means of Production in Socialist Econ-
sity Press, 1962, pp. 157-75. omies," J. Law Econ., April, 1968, 11,
2. ALCHIAN, A. "The Basis of Some Recent pp. 1-4.
Advances in the Theory of Manage- 13. BATOR,F. "The Anatomy of Market
ment of the Firm," ]. Ind. Ecm., Nov. Failure," Quart. J. Econ., August 1958,
1965,14, pp. 30-41. 72, pp. 351-79.
3. - ,'Pricing and society. Occasional 14. BAUMOL,W. Business behavior, value
Paper No. 17. Westminster: The Insti- and growth. New York: Macmillan,
tute of Economic Affairs, 1967. 1959.
4. - , "Corporate Management and 15. BECKER,G. Economics of discrimina-
Property Rights" in H. MANNE, ed. Eco- tion. Chicago: University of Chicago
nomic policy and the regulation of cor- Press, 1957.
porate securities. Washington, D.C.: 16. BERLE,A. AND MEANS,G. The modern
American Enterprise Institute for Pub- corporation and private property. New
lic Policy Research, 1969, pp. 337-60. York: Harcourt, Brace and World,
5. - , "Information Cost, Pricing and 1968.
Resource Unemployment," Western 17. BERLE, A. Power without property.
Econ. I., June, 1969, 7, pp. 109-28. New York: Harcourt, Brace and
6. ALCHIAN, A. AND ALLEN,W. University World, 1959.
economics. Belmont: Wadsworth, 1972. 18. BORNSTEIN, M. AND FUSFELD,D. The
7. ALCHIAN,A. AND DEMSETZ, H. "Produc- Soviet economy: A book of readings.
tion, Information Costs and Economic Homewood, Illinois: Irwin, 1970.
Organization," Amer. Econ. Rev. (forth- 19. BOT~OMLEY, A. "The Effect of the Com-
coming). mon Ownership of Land upon Resource
8. ARROW,K. ''Economic Welfare and the Allocation in Tripolitania," Land Econ.,
Allocation of Resources for Invention" Feb. 1963,39, pp. 91-95.
in NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RE- 20. BOULDING, K. "The Present Position of
SEARCH. The rate and direction of inven- the Theory of the Firm" in K. E.
tive activity: Economic and social fac- BOULDING AND W. A. SPIVY,eds., Linear
tors. Princeton: Princeton University programming and the theory of the
Press, 1962, pp. 609-25. firm. New York: Macmillan, 1960, pp.
9. - , "An Extension of the Basic 1-17.
Theorems of Classical Welfare Eco- 21. BRONFENBRENNER, M. "A Reformulation
nomics" in J. NEYMAN, ed. Proceedings of Naive Profit Theory," Southern Econ.
of the Second Berkeley Symposium on J., April 1960, 26, pp. 300-09.
Mathematical Statistics and Probabil- 22. BUCHANAN, J. "Congestion on the Com-
ity. Berkeley, 1951, pp. 507-32. mon: A Case for Government Interven-
10. ARROW,K. AND DEBREU, G. "Existence tion," I1 Politico, 1968, 33, pp. 776-86.
of an Equilibrium for a Competitive 23. BUCHANAN, J. AND
STUBBLEBINE, C. "EX-
Economy," Econometrica, July 1954,22, ternality," Economica, Nov. 1962, 29,
pp. 265-90. pp. 371-84.
11. AVERACH, H. AND JOHNSON,L. "Be- 24. BUCHANAN, J. AND TULLOCK, G. The cal-
havior of the Firm under Regulatory culus of consent. Ann Arbor: Univer-
Constraint," Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. sity of Michigan Press, 1962.
1962, 52, pp. 1052-69. 25. BUCHANAN, J. AND DEVLETOGLOU, N.
Furubotn a n d Pejovich: Property Rights a n d Economic Theory 1159

Academia in anurchy: An economic C. "X-Theory Versus Management Dis-


diagnosis. New York: Basic Books, cretion Theory," Southern Econ. J.,
1970. Oct. 1971,38, pp. 173-84.
26. CHEUNG,S. "Transaction Costs, Risk 38. DE ALESSI,L. "Implications of Property
Aversion, and the Choice of Contrac- Rights for Government Investment
tual Arrangements," J. Law Econ., Choices," Amer. Econ. Rev., March
April 1969,12, pp. 23-42. 1969, 59, pp. 16-23.
27. - , "Private Property Rights and 39. DEBREU,G . Theory of value. New
Sharecropping," .J. Polit. Econ., Dec. York: Wiley, 1959.
1968,76, pp. 1107-22. 40. DEMSETZ,H. "The Exchange and En-
28. - , "The Structure of a Contract forcement of Property Rights," J. Law
and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Re- Econ., Oct. 1964, 7, pp. 11-26.
source," J. Law Econ., April 1970, 13, 41. - , "Some Aspects of Property
pp. 49-70. Rights," J. Law Econ., Oct. 1966, 9, pp.
29. CLARKSON, K. "Property Rights, Institu- 61-70.
tional Constraints, and Individual Be- 42. - , "Toward a Theory of Property
havior: An Application to Short-term Rights," Amer. Econ. Rev., May 1967,
Hospitals," Ph.D. Dissertation, Depart- 57, p p 347-73.
ment of Economics, University of Cali- 43. - , "Information and Efficiency:
fornia at Los Angeles, 1970. Another Viewpoint," 1. Lau; Econ.,
30. CLAYTON, E. "Property Rights under April 1969,12, pp. 1-22.
Socialism," 1971 (unpublished manu- 44. - , "When Does the Rule of Lia-
script). bility Matter," paper presented at the
31. - , "Price Appropriability and the Southern Economic Association Meet-
Soviet Agricultural Incentives," paper ing, November, 1971.
presented at National Convention of 45. DEVANY,A,; ECKERT,R.; MEYERS,C.;
the American Association for the Ad- O'HARA,D. AND SCOTT,R. 'A Property
vancement of Slavic Studies, March System for Market Allocation of Elec-
1972. tro-Magnetic Spectrum: A Legal-Eco-
32. COASE,R. "The Federal Communica- nomic-Engineering Study," Stanford
tions Commission," J. Law Econ., Oct. Law Rev., June 1969, 21, pp. 1499-
1959,2, pp. 1 4 0 . 1561.
33. - , "The Problem of Social Cost," 46. DOMAR,E. "The Soviet Collective
J. Law Econ. Oct. 1960,3, pp. 1-44. Farm," Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1966,
34. ---, "The Nature of the Firm," 56, pp. 73457.
Economica, Nov. 1937, 4, pp. 386405. 47. ECKERT,R. "Regulatory Commission
35. COLEMAN, J. "Reward Structures and Behavior: Taxi Franchising in Los An-
the Allocation of Effort" in P. F. geles and Other Cities," Ph.D. Disserta-
LAZARSFELD and N. W. HENRY,eds. tion, Department of Economics, Uni-
Readings in mathematical social sci- versity of California at Los Angeles,
ence. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1966, 1968.
pp. 159-73. 48. FURUBOTN,E. "Toward a Dynamic
36. COOPER, W. "Theory of the Firm: Some Model of the Yugoslav Firm," Can. J.
Suggestions for Revision," Amer. Econ. Econ., May 1971, 4, pp. 182-97.
Rev., Dec. 1949, 39, pp. 120422. 49. FURUBOTN, E. AND PEJOVICH, S. "Prop-
37. CREW,M.; JONES-LEE, M. AND RAWLEY, erty Rights and the Behavior of the
1160 Journal of Economic Literature

Firm in a Socialist State," 2, fur Na- 61. KAMERSCHEN, D. "The Influence of


tionulokon., Winter 1970, 30, pp. 431- Ownership and Control on Profit
54. Rates," Amer. Econ. Rev., June 1968,
50. - , "Tax Policy and Investment 58, pp. 432-47.
Decisions of the Yugoslav Firm," Nut. 62. KAYSEN, C. "Another View of Corpo-
Tax J., Sept. 1970,23, pp. 335-48. rate Capitalism," Quart. J. Econ., Feb.
51.- , "The Role of the Banking Sys- 1965, 79, pp. 41-51.
tem in Yugoslav Economic Planning, 63. LARNER,R. "The 200 Largest Non-
1946-1969" in D. DEMARCO, ed. Re- financed Corporations," Amer. Econ.
w e lnternutionule D'Histoire de la Rev., Sept. 1966, 56, pp. 777-87.
Banque, Vol. 4. Geneva, Librairie Droz, 64. LEVINE,M. "Landing Fees and the Air-
1971. port Congestion Problem," J. Law
52. -----, "The Soviet Manager and In- Econ., April 1969, 12, pp. 79-108.
novation: A Behavioral Model of the 65. LEVY, F. "Economic Analysis of the
Soviet Firm," Revue de L'Est, Jan. Non-Profit Institution-The Case of the
1972,3, pp. 2945. Private University," Thomas Jefferson
53. FURUBOTN, E. "Economic Organization Center for Political Economy, Public
and Welfare Distribution," Swedish J. Choice, Spring 1968, 4, pp. 3-17.
Econ., Dec. 1971, 73, pp. 409-16. 66. MACCAULAY, S. "Non-Contractual Re-
54. GORDON, M. The investment, financing lations in Business: A Preliminary
and valuation of the corporation. Study," Amer. Sociological Rev., Feb.
Homewood, Illinois: Irwin, 1962. 1963,28, pp. 55-67.
55. GORDON, S. "The Economic Theory of a 67. MANNE, H. "Good for General Motors,"
Common-Property Resource: The Fish- Barron's, May 18, 1970.
ery," J. Polit. Econ., April 1954, 62, pp. 68. ----, "The Parable of the Parking
124-42. Lots," Religion and Society, Feb. 1972,
56. GRAAFF, J. Theoretical welfare econom- 5, pp. 22-27.
ics. Cambridge: Cambridge University 69. MARRIS,R. The economic theory of
Press, 1957. managerial capitalism. New York: Free
57. HANVONEN, J. "Postwar Developments Press of Glencoe, 1964.
in Money and Banking in Yugoslavia," 70. MARTIN,D. "Claims to Work Oppor-
lnt. Monet. Fund Staff Pap., Nov. 1970, tunity: An Economic Analysis of Alter-
17, pp. 563-601. native Configurations of Hiring Rights,"
58. HEYNE,P. "The Free Market System Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Eco-
is the Best Guide for Corporate Deci- nomics, University of California at LOS
sions," Financial Analysts J., Sept.-Oct. Angeles, 1969.
1971. 71. - , "Job Property Rights and Job
59. HINDLEY, B. "Separation of Ownership Defections," J. Law Econ., Forthcom-
and Control in the Modem Corpora- ing.
tion," J. Law Econ., April 1970, 13, pp. 72. MAYER, T. "The Distribution of Ability
185-221. and Earnings," Rev. Econ. Statist., May
60. JOHNSON, H. "Graphic Analysis of Mul- 1960, 42, pp. 189-95.
tiple-Goal Firms: Development, Cur- 73. MCKEAN, R. "Products Liability: Impli-
rent Status and Critique," Pennsylvania cations of Some Changing Property
State University, Occasional Paper, No. Rights," Quart. J. Econ., Nov. 1970, 84,
5, 1966, pp. 1-36. pp.611-26.
Furubotn and Pejouich: Property Rights and Economic Theory 1161

74. - ,"Divergences Between Individ- tive government. Chicago: Aldine Pub-


ual and Total Cost Within Govern- lishing Company, 1971.
ment," Amer. Econ. Rev., May 1964,54, 86. NORTH,D. "The Creation of Property
pp. 24349. Rights in Western Europe 900-1700
75. ----, "Property Rights Within Gov- A.D.," 1972 (unpublished manuscript).
ernment and Devices to Increase Gov- 87. NOVE,A. The Soviet economy. New
ernment's Efficiency," pap.er presented York: Frederick A. Praeger, 1969.
at the Southern Economic Association 88. NUTTER,W. "Markets Without Prop-
Meeting, November 1971. erty: A Grand Illusion" in N. BEADLES
76. MEADE,J . "External Economies and and A. DREWRY, eds. Money, the mar-
Diseconomies in a Competitive Situa- ket, and the state. Athens, Georgia:
tion," Econ. J., March 1952, 62, pp. 54- Georgia University Press, 1968, pp. 137-
67. 45.
77. MECKLING, W. "Management of the Fre- 89. PEJOVICH,S. "Liberman's Reforms and
quency Spectrum," Washington Uni- Property Rights in the Soviet Union,"
versity Law Quart., Winter 1968, pp. J. Law Econ., April 1969, 12, pp. 155-
26-34. 62.
78. MINASIAN,J. "Television Pricing and 90. - - , "The Firm, Monetary Policy

the Theory of Public Goods," J. Lau: and Property Rights in a Planned


Econ., Oct. 1964, 7, pp. 71-80. Economy," Western Econ. I., Sept.
79. MISHAN,E. "The Postwar Literature on 1969, 7, pp. 193-200.
Externalities: An Interpretative Essay," 91. ---, "Fiscal Policy and Investment
J . Econ. Lit., March 1971, 9, pp. 1-26. in Hunlan Capital," Rev. Soc. Econ.,
80. MOORE,J. "Discretionary Behavior in a March 1970, 28, pp. 53-59.
Worker-Managed Enterprise," paper 92. -- , "Towards a General Theory of
presented at National Convention of Property Rights," 2, fur Nationalokon.,
the American Association for the Ad- Spring 1971, 31, pp. 141-55.
vancement of Slavic Studies, March 93. ---, "Economic Reforms in the
1972. Soviet Union: Their Causes and Pur-
81. - , "On Incentives in Socialist En- pose," Modern Age, Jan. 1972, 16, pp.
terprises," paper presented at Southern 68-76.
Conference on Slavic Studies, October 94. ---, "The Banking System and the
1971. Investment Behavior of the Yugoslav
82. NEWHOUSE,J. "Toward a Theory of Firm" in M. BORNSTEIN, ed. Plan and
Nonprofit Institutions: An Economic market. New Haven: Yale University
Model of a Hospital," Amer. Econ. Press, 1973.
Rev., March 1970, 60, pp. 64-74. 95. PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth
83. NICOLS,A. "Stock VS. Mutual Savings of the firm. New York: J . Wiley and
and Loan Associations: Some Evidence Sons, 1959.
of Differences in Behavior," Amer. 96. PORTER,A. Job property rights. New
Econ. Rev., May 1967, 57, pp. 337-46. York: King Crown Press, 1954.
84. NISKANAN,W. "Nonmarket Decision 97. PRYBYLA, J. Comparative economic sys-
Making: The Peculiar Economics of tems. New York: Appleton-Century-
Bureaucracy," Amer. Econ. Rev., May Crofts, 1969.
1968, 58, pp. 293-305. 98. QUIRK, J. AND SAPOSNIK, R. Introduction
85. - , Bureaucracy and representa- to general equilibrium theory and wel-
1162 Journal of Economic Literature

fare economics. New York: McGraw- 112. SPULBER, N. The Soviet economy. New
Hill, 1968. York: Norton, 1962.
99. REDER,M. "A Reconsideration of Mar- 113. STEINER,P. "Monopoly and Competi-
ginal Productivity Theory," J. Polit. tion in Television: Some Policy Issues,"
Econ., Oct. 1947, 55, pp. 450-58. Manchester School Econ. Soc. Stud.,
100. ROTENBERG,S. "Property in Work," May 1961,29, pp. 107-31.
Ind. Lab. Relat. Rev., April 1962, 15, 114. STIGLER,G. "The Economics of Infor-
pp. 402-05. mation," J. Polit. Econ., June 1961, 69,
101. SAMUELS, W. "Interrelations Between pp. 213-25.
Legal and Economic Processes," J. Law
115. TULLOCK, G. The logic of the law. New
Econ., Oct. 1971, 14, pp. 435-50.
York: Basic Books, 1971.
102. SAMUELSON, P. Economics. 7th Edition.
New York: McGraw Hill, 1966. 116. TURVEY, R. "Optimization and Subopti-
103. SCITOVSKY, T. "Two Concepts of Exter- mization in Fishery Regulation," Amer.
nal Economies," J. Polit. Econ., April Ecalz. Rev., March 1964,54, pp. 64-76.
1954, 62, pp. 70-82. 117. VANEK,J. "Some Fundamental Consid-
104. SCOTT,A. "The Fishery: The Objectives erations of Financing and the Right of
of Sole Ownership," J. Polit. Econ., Property Under Labor-Management,"
April 1955, 63, pp. 116-24. 1971 (unpublished manuscript ) .
105. Scorn, M. "Relative Share Prices and 118. VICKERS, D. The theory of the firm: Pro-
Yields," Oxford Econ. Pap., Oct. 1962, duction, capital, and finance. New
14, p p 218-50. York: McGraw-Hill, 1968.
106. SHALIT,S. "Barriers to Entry in the 119. WARD,B. "Workers Management in
American Hospital Industry," Ph.D. Yugoslavia," J. Polit. Econ., Oct. 1957,
Dissertation, Chicago: University of 65, pp. 373-86.
Chicago, 1971. 120. WEINTRAUB, S. Price themy. New York:
107. SHERMAN,R. "The Design of Public Pitman, 1949.
Utility Institutions," Land Econ., Feb.
121. WHITE,W. "Money, Information and
1970, 46, pp. 51-58.
Socialism," paper presented at the
108. SHERMAN, R. (with THOMASD. WIL-
Western Economic Association Meet-
L E ~, "Externality,
) Regional Develop-
ings, August, 1971.
ment, and Tax-Subsidy Combinations,"
Nut. Tax J., June 1969, 22, pp. 291-98. 122. WILLIAMSON, 0. The economics of dis-
109. SHUBIK,M. "Objective Functions and cretionary behavior: Managerial ob-
Models of Corporate Optimization," jectives in a theory of the firm. Engle-
Quart. J. Econ., August 1961, 75, pp. wood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall,
345-75. Inc., 1964.
110. SIMON,H. "Theories of Decision-Mak- 123. ---, "Managerial Discretion and
ing in Economics and Behavioral Sci- Business Behavior," Anler. Econ. Rev.,
ence," Amer. Econ. Reu., June 1959, Dec. 1963, 53, pp. 1032-57.
49, pp. 253-88. 124. ZALESKI,E. Planning reforms in the
111. SMITH,V. "On Models of Commercial Soviet Union, 1962-1 966. Chapel Hill :
Fishing," J. Polit. Econ., March 1969, The University of North Carolina Press,
77, pp. 181-98. 1967.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 1 of 7 -

You have printed the following article:


Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey of Recent Literature
Eirik G. Furubotn; Svetozar Pejovich
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 10, No. 4. (Dec., 1972), pp. 1137-1162.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28197212%2910%3A4%3C1137%3APRAETA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-V

This article references the following linked citations. If you are trying to access articles from an
off-campus location, you may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR. Please
visit your library's website or contact a librarian to learn about options for remote access to JSTOR.

[Footnotes]

1
Implications of Property Rights for Government Investment Choices
Louis De Alessi
The American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 1. (1969), pp. 13-24.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%281969%2959%3A1%3C13%3AIOPRFG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S

2
Theories of Decision-Making in Economics and Behavioral Science
Herbert A. Simon
The American Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 3. (Jun., 1959), pp. 253-283.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28195906%2949%3A3%3C253%3ATODIEA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

5
Toward a Theory of Property Rights
Harold Demsetz
The American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-ninth
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1967), pp. 347-359.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196705%2957%3A2%3C347%3ATATOPR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

6
Externality
James M. Buchanan; Wm. Craig Stubblebine
Economica, New Series, Vol. 29, No. 116. (Nov., 1962), pp. 371-384.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0427%28196211%292%3A29%3A116%3C371%3AE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M
NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 2 of 7 -

8
On Models of Commercial Fishing
Vernon L. Smith
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77, No. 2. (Mar. - Apr., 1969), pp. 181-198.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28196903%2F04%2977%3A2%3C181%3AOMOCF%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I

8
External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive Situation
J. E. Meade
The Economic Journal, Vol. 62, No. 245. (Mar., 1952), pp. 54-67.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28195203%2962%3A245%3C54%3AEEADIA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-O

8
The Postwar Literature on Externalities: An Interpretative Essay
E. J. Mishan
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 9, No. 1. (Mar., 1971), pp. 1-28.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28197103%299%3A1%3C1%3ATPLOEA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-%23

12
The Influence of Ownership and Control on Profit Rates
David R. Kamerschen
The American Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 3, Part 1. (Jun., 1968), pp. 432-447.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196806%2958%3A3%3C432%3ATIOOAC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-%23

13
Theory of the Firm: Some Suggestions for Revision
W. W. Cooper
The American Economic Review, Vol. 39, No. 6. (Dec., 1949), pp. 1204-1222.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28194912%2939%3A6%3C1204%3ATOTFSS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M

13
A Reconsideration of the Marginal Productivity Theory
M. W. Reder
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 55, No. 5. (Oct., 1947), pp. 450-458.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28194710%2955%3A5%3C450%3AAROTMP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 3 of 7 -

17
The Soviet Collective Farm as a Producer Cooperative
Evsey D. Domar
The American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 4, Part 1. (Sep., 1966), pp. 734-757.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196609%2956%3A4%3C734%3ATSCFAA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

17
Workers' Management in Yugoslavia
Benjamin Ward
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 65, No. 5. (Oct., 1957), pp. 373-386.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28195710%2965%3A5%3C373%3AWMIY%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

References

10
Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy
Kenneth J. Arrow; Gerard Debreu
Econometrica, Vol. 22, No. 3. (Jul., 1954), pp. 265-290.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28195407%2922%3A3%3C265%3AEOAEFA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

23
Externality
James M. Buchanan; Wm. Craig Stubblebine
Economica, New Series, Vol. 29, No. 116. (Nov., 1962), pp. 371-384.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0427%28196211%292%3A29%3A116%3C371%3AE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M

27
Private Property Rights and Sharecropping
Steven N. S. Cheung
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 6. (Nov. - Dec., 1968), pp. 1107-1122.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28196811%2F12%2976%3A6%3C1107%3APPRAS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 4 of 7 -

34
The Nature of the Firm
R. H. Coase
Economica, New Series, Vol. 4, No. 16. (Nov., 1937), pp. 386-405.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0427%28193711%292%3A4%3A16%3C386%3ATNOTF%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

36
Theory of the Firm: Some Suggestions for Revision
W. W. Cooper
The American Economic Review, Vol. 39, No. 6. (Dec., 1949), pp. 1204-1222.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28194912%2939%3A6%3C1204%3ATOTFSS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M

38
Implications of Property Rights for Government Investment Choices
Louis De Alessi
The American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 1. (1969), pp. 13-24.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%281969%2959%3A1%3C13%3AIOPRFG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S

42
Toward a Theory of Property Rights
Harold Demsetz
The American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-ninth
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1967), pp. 347-359.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196705%2957%3A2%3C347%3ATATOPR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

46
The Soviet Collective Farm as a Producer Cooperative
Evsey D. Domar
The American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 4, Part 1. (Sep., 1966), pp. 734-757.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196609%2956%3A4%3C734%3ATSCFAA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

55
The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery
H. Scott Gordon
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 62, No. 2. (Apr., 1954), pp. 124-142.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28195404%2962%3A2%3C124%3ATETOAC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-L

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 5 of 7 -

61
The Influence of Ownership and Control on Profit Rates
David R. Kamerschen
The American Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 3, Part 1. (Jun., 1968), pp. 432-447.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196806%2958%3A3%3C432%3ATIOOAC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-%23

63
Ownership and Control in the 200 Largest Nonfinancial Corporations, 1929 and 1963
Robert J. Larner
The American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 4, Part 1. (Sep., 1966), pp. 777-787.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196609%2956%3A4%3C777%3AOACIT2%3E2.0.CO%3B2-A

74
Divergences between Individual and Total Costs within Government
Roland N. McKean
The American Economic Review, Vol. 54, No. 3, Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-sixth
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1964), pp. 243-249.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196405%2954%3A3%3C243%3ADBIATC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

76
External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive Situation
J. E. Meade
The Economic Journal, Vol. 62, No. 245. (Mar., 1952), pp. 54-67.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28195203%2962%3A245%3C54%3AEEADIA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-O

79
The Postwar Literature on Externalities: An Interpretative Essay
E. J. Mishan
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 9, No. 1. (Mar., 1971), pp. 1-28.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28197103%299%3A1%3C1%3ATPLOEA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-%23

82
Toward a Theory of Nonprofit Institutions: An Economic Model of a Hospital
Joseph P. Newhouse
The American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 1. (1970), pp. 64-74.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%281970%2960%3A1%3C64%3ATATONI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-T

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 6 of 7 -

83
Stock Versus Mutual Savings and Loan Associations: Some Evidence of Differences in
Behavior
Alfred Nicols
The American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-ninth
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1967), pp. 337-346.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196705%2957%3A2%3C337%3ASVMSAL%3E2.0.CO%3B2-2

99
A Reconsideration of the Marginal Productivity Theory
M. W. Reder
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 55, No. 5. (Oct., 1947), pp. 450-458.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28194710%2955%3A5%3C450%3AAROTMP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

103
Review: [Untitled]
Reviewed Work(s):
International Economic Papers
Tibor Scitovsky
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 62, No. 1. (Feb., 1954), p. 70.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28195402%2962%3A1%3C70%3AIEP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-V

104
The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership
Anthony Scott
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 63, No. 2. (Apr., 1955), pp. 116-124.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28195504%2963%3A2%3C116%3ATFTOOS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-R

110
Theories of Decision-Making in Economics and Behavioral Science
Herbert A. Simon
The American Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 3. (Jun., 1959), pp. 253-283.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28195906%2949%3A3%3C253%3ATODIEA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 7 of 7 -

111
On Models of Commercial Fishing
Vernon L. Smith
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77, No. 2. (Mar. - Apr., 1969), pp. 181-198.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28196903%2F04%2977%3A2%3C181%3AOMOCF%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I

114
The Economics of Information
George J. Stigler
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 69, No. 3. (Jun., 1961), pp. 213-225.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28196106%2969%3A3%3C213%3ATEOI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-D

116
Optimization and Suboptimization in Fishery Regulation
Ralph Turvey
The American Economic Review, Vol. 54, No. 2, Part 1. (Mar., 1964), pp. 64-76.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196403%2954%3A2%3C64%3AOASIFR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-G

119
Workers' Management in Yugoslavia
Benjamin Ward
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 65, No. 5. (Oct., 1957), pp. 373-386.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28195710%2965%3A5%3C373%3AWMIY%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

123
Managerial Discretion and Business Behavior
Oliver E. Williamson
The American Economic Review, Vol. 53, No. 5. (Dec., 1963), pp. 1032-1057.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28196312%2953%3A5%3C1032%3AMDABB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-T

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.

You might also like