You are on page 1of 9

Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jretconser

The impact of dynamic bundling on price fairness perceptions T


⁎,1
Wenjing Li , David M. Hardesty, Adam W. Craig
University of Kentucky, 550 S Limestone, Lexington, KY 40506, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: With the increased availability of consumer-specific data and the ease of changing prices, firms more frequently
Dynamic pricing use dynamic pricing where products are priced at an individual level based on individual consumer information.
Bundling Dynamic pricing can effectively extract consumer surplus and increase firm profitability. However, it also
Fairness and unfairness perceptions arouses consumer unfairness perceptions. Three studies demonstrate that the use of bundling in combination
Dynamic bundling
with dynamic pricing (dynamic bundling) can reduce consumer unfairness perceptions. The negative effects of
Transaction dissimilarity
Comparison intentions
dynamic pricing are mitigated by bundling. A bundle enhances perceived transaction dissimilarity thereby re-
ducing consumers’ comparison intentions leading to greater price fairness perceptions.

1. Introduction product launch. Consumers who paid full price were outraged by the
price drop. To comfort the livid consumers, Apple apologized and of-
Dynamic pricing, also called yield management, has been widely fered a $100 credit for Apple products (Mohammed, 2012). In July
practiced in the airline and hotel industries and has been more recently 2011, Netflix raised its price, but turned a blind eye to its customers’
adopted in other industries including sports and entertainment. It is a rage. Its stock price dropped more than two-thirds within three months
strategy in which prices are free to adjust across time, consumers, and/ of the price increase (Mohammed, 2012). Thus, firms face a dilemma.
or circumstances based on consumer-specific data (Haws and Bearden, They want to implement dynamic pricing to increase profitability.
2006). Dynamic pricing allows firms to price products at the individual However, they have concerns that this pricing strategy could alienate
level to extract consumer surplus (Grewal et al., 2004). Technology that their customers by arousing unfairness perceptions. Is it possible for
facilitates consumers’ individual viewing (e.g., Amazon's website) fur- retailers to utilize a pricing tactic that reaps the benefit of extracting
ther allows firms to specify a unique price for each individual. Elec- consumer surplus from using dynamic pricing while not arousing con-
tronics, clothing, jewelry, and household items can be priced at a level sumer unfairness perceptions? If so, what underlying mechanisms ex-
most likely to attract any particular consumer (Angwin and Mattioli, plain the process through which unfairness perceptions could be re-
2012). duced? The main objective of the present research is to provide firms a
While dynamic pricing can increase profitability up to 25% novel solution by combining bundling with dynamic pricing to create
(Garbarino and Lee, 2003; Petro, 2015), it also can cause problems for an alternative pricing strategy, dynamic bundling, defined as a pricing
firms. Consumers experience greater perceptions of unfairness and strategy in which the price of a product changes when the focal product
lower levels of trust when prices are different across consumers is bundled with additional products. More importantly, this is a distinct
(Garbarino and Lee, 2003; Grewal et al., 2004; Haws and Bearden, strategy from product bundling alone. The second objective is to assess
2006). Relying on its advanced information systems and vast customer the effectiveness of dynamic bundling vs. dynamic pricing in terms of
database, Amazon.com priced the same DVD movies differently to its impact on price fairness perceptions.
consumers based on their online profiles and previous purchasing be- In this paper, we conduct three studies to assess whether dynamic
haviors (Monroe, 2003; Grewal et al., 2004). When consumers found bundling can reduce consumer unfairness perceptions associated with
out about Amazon's dynamic pricing strategy, their complaints against dynamic pricing. We find that bundling not only mitigates the negative
the company soon filled the chat boards. Amazon had to publicly claim impact of dynamic pricing on fairness perceptions, but also results in
that they would no longer use dynamic pricing (Streitfeld, 2000). More fairness perceptions similar to those aroused by fixed pricing. In doing
recently, Apple and Netflix experienced similar situations. In September so, we advance knowledge in several ways. We are the first to introduce
2007, Apple dropped its iPhone price by $200 within three months of the combination of bundling and dynamic pricing as a new pricing


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: wenjing.li@uky.edu (W. Li), david.hardesty@uky.edu (D.M. Hardesty), adam.craig@uky.edu (A.W. Craig).
1
We would like to thank Bill Bearden for providing helpful feedback for this manuscript.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2017.10.011
Received 22 May 2017; Received in revised form 9 October 2017; Accepted 18 October 2017
Available online 06 November 2017
0969-6989/ © 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

strategy. By introducing this new pricing strategy, we demonstrate the 2007). As such, fixed pricing, that provides different consumers the
superiority of dynamic bundling relative to dynamic pricing on fairness same price, might not be an optimal pricing strategy. In fixed pricing,
perceptions. Unlike dynamic pricing, dynamic bundling helps firms consumers who are willing to pay more for a product will end up paying
increase their profitability without generating unfairness perceptions. less than what they are willing to pay. Dynamic pricing specifically
In addition, we offer a process explanation as to why dynamic addresses these variances among consumers’ reservation prices. It al-
bundling reduces price unfairness perceptions. Specifically, we estab- lows firms to price discriminate at the individual level based on cus-
lish a serial mediation model in which perceived transaction dissim- tomer profiles and previous purchasing behavior data (Kannan and
ilarity and comparison intentions mediate the effect of dynamic bund- Kopalle, 2001). Consumers who are willing to pay more will be charged
ling on fairness perceptions. Importantly, we find that perceived more. For consumers whose reservation prices are relatively low, they
transaction dissimilarity reduces comparison intentions thereby les- will be provided with prices that match their reservation prices as-
sening unfairness perceptions. suming these prices meet the firms’ minimum profit margins. Thus, by
Moreover, our research contributes to the bundling literature by extracting surplus and bringing in more business, dynamic pricing can
demonstrating another benefit of bundling: enhancing fairness per- help firms increase their profitability up to 25% (Garbarino and Lee,
ceptions. While bundling reduces searching, sorting, and processing 2003; Petro, 2015).
costs (Hayes, 1987), extracts consumer surplus (Janiszewski and Eager to boost their profitability, many firms implement dynamic
Cunha, 2004), increases consumers’ purchase intentions and perceived pricing with the help of advanced technology and the increasing
value (Johnson et al., 1999; Arora, 2008), and helps firms differentiate availability of vast consumer databases (Jayaraman and Baker, 2003).
their products and services (Dominique-Ferreira et al., 2016), previous While firms prefer to implement dynamic pricing, many of them are
research has not investigated how bundling impacts price fairness also weary of consumer unfairness perceptions often associated with
perceptions. And while some recent research found that unbundling this strategy.
may increase current revenue (Koschat and Putsis, 2002), potentially
reducing the utility of bundling in some conditions, our findings pro- 2.2. Dynamic pricing and consumers’ price fairness perceptions
vide firms a new factor to consider when deciding whether to imple-
ment bundling. 2.2.1. Social comparison theory and price fairness perceptions
Additionally, our proposed new pricing strategy has a wide appli- Price fairness perceptions refer to consumers’ judgments and asso-
cation and can be used for almost any product. In our present research, ciated emotions as to whether the price they paid is just, relative to the
we will focus on price bundling (vs. product bundling) as it has a wider prices other comparative parties paid (Xia et al., 2004). It is a com-
application than product bundling (Naylor and Frank, 2001; Gilbride parative concept and only evoked when consumers compare different
et al., 2008). The combination of dynamic pricing with bundling sug- prices (Monroe, 2003). Social comparison theory describes how people
gests the possibility of a broader strategy for retailers that uniquely fulfill their quest for self-knowledge by comparing themselves with
tailors offerings to each consumer in a way that reduces perceived si- others (Festinger, 1954). Further, comparison can help a person ap-
milarity and comparison intentions (see Fig. 1 for our conceptual praise their abilities (Trope, 1983, 1986). According to social compar-
model). ison theory, people have an automatic tendency to compare two entities
(usually people) that share some similarities (Corcoran et al., 2011), but
this principle can be applied to the comparison of transactions as
2. Theoretical background and hypotheses development consumers will be concerned with what benefit another customer re-
ceived (Bolton et al., 2003; Xia et al., 2004). Consumers tend to choose
2.1. Dynamic pricing transactions similar to theirs when judging the fairness of their own
transaction.
Dynamic pricing is defined as a strategy in which prices are free to The intention to compare similar entities is motivated by the need
adjust over time, consumers, and/or circumstances (Haws and Bearden, for accurate evaluations (Taylor et al., 1996). When compared entities
2006). In the current research, the dynamic component of dynamic are very similar or the same, consumers can simply evaluate the out-
pricing focuses on the consumer in that different consumers will be comes to determine the justness. For example, if a consumer wants to
charged different prices for the same product. The practice of dynamic know whether the price they paid for an airline ticket to Chicago is fair,
pricing is based on the premise that consumers are heterogeneous. they are likely to use the purchase of the same airline ticket as the
Different consumers usually have different maximum prices they are comparative reference. A comparison to a similar transaction can easily
willing to pay for a given product. This maximum price a consumer is reveal whether the price they paid is fair. Not only do people tend to
willing to pay for a product is called a reservation price (Wang et al., choose a similar transaction to compare, the presence of similarity
(between customers or transactions) also makes them pay more atten-
tion to it. This phenomenon is known as similarity bias in the social
comparison literature (Mussweiler, 2003). The focus on the similarities,
in turn, increases comparison intentions. In the current context, it is
possible that a reduction in comparison intentions or likelihood may
prevent unfairness perceptions.

2.2.2. Equity theory and price fairness perceptions


Firms that implement dynamic pricing sell the same products at
different prices. The high degree of similarity induces consumers to
selectively process information to further support the similarity
(Mussweiler, 2003). The enhanced perceptions of similarity increase
consumers’ comparison intentions. A comparison of two highly similar
transactions in the dynamic pricing setting reveals to consumers that
they receive the same amount of benefits, the same products, which, in
turn, arouses a strong entitlement to pay a similar price (Bolton et al.,
2003). However, under the practice of dynamic pricing, consumers pay
Fig. 1. Conceptual model.
different prices (different contributions) for the same product (same

205
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

amount of benefits). Equity theory suggests that people expect to re- (2010) confirm that bundling strengthens perceived value and increases
ceive the amount of benefits that is equal to what they have contributed consumers’ switching intentions to the bundle. Yan et al. (2014) results
(Adams, 1965). According to equity theory, consumers focus on the suggest that bundling can potentially reduce advertising expenses.
equality of their outcomes to judge the fairness of their transactions. In Dominique-Ferreira et al. (2016) find that bundling can help firms
line with social comparison theory, equity theory also implies a com- differentiate their products and services. According to Dominique-
parison with other comparative parties, other consumers, or different Ferreira (2017), salespersons can use bundling to improve their effi-
organizations to judge the outcome (Xia et al., 2004). When consumers ciency in approaching customers. However, to our knowledge, no one
compare their transactions with that of other consumers, they will has investigated the benefit of bundling in enhancing price fairness
realize that they have contributed differently for the same outcome perceptions, despite the possibility as suggested by Dominique-Ferreira
(Oliver and Swan, 1989), which violates equity theory. Unfairness et al. (2016). Thus, by using price bundling and demonstrating its ef-
perceptions are likely to arise. The consequences of unfairness per- fectiveness, we provide firms an easy-to-use tool for addressing the
ceptions can be costly. Consumers will demonstrate low satisfaction and problem of unfairness perceptions.
repurchase intentions and may even spread negative word of mouth or
boycott the firm (Campbell, 1999; Grégoire and Fisher, 2008). The
widespread use of social media makes the consequences of unfairness 2.4. Dynamic bundling
perceptions even more dire. Although digital media and the internet
make it very easy for marketers to practice dynamic pricing due to the Dynamic bundling is defined as a pricing strategy in which the price
volume of consumer-specific information, the transparency and strong of a product changes when the focal product is bundled with additional
connections among customers also make it more likely for customers to products. The prices of the products in each bundle may be determined
detect price discrepancies. As soon as consumers recognize price dis- based on consumer profiles and their previous purchasing behavior
crimination, the speed of transmission and the number of other con- (Kannan and Kopalle, 2001). By bundling products/services together,
sumers they can reach make the consequences of unfairness perceptions retailers create a new and different transaction. The transaction of
more damaging to firms. As a result, it is vital that the problem of purchasing an individual product is different from the transaction of
unfairness perceptions be avoided. purchasing a bundle of multiple products. For example, the transaction
of purchasing a single airline ticket is different from that of purchasing
2.2.3. Reducing comparison intention through transaction dissimilarity a bundled airline ticket and hotel room. As suggested by social com-
To make dynamic pricing more acceptable, firms may attempt to parison theory, consumers are less likely to compare two entities per-
reduce consumers’ comparison intentions as fairness perceptions are ceived as dissimilar (Corcoran et al., 2011). In the case of dynamic
inherently comparative. For example, modifying product features can bundling, as the perceived transaction dissimilarity is very high, con-
increase perceived dissimilarity among transactions and, as such, re- sumers’ comparison intentions will be very low. Since fairness percep-
duce comparison intentions. However, feature modifications may be tion is an inherently comparative concept and is only evoked when
too costly to implement. Price framing can also mitigate consumers’ consumers make a comparison (Fernandes and Calamote, 2016),
unfairness perceptions toward dynamic pricing (Weisstein et al., 2013). without comparison motivation, violation of equity theory will not
To reduce consumers’ negative reactions, retailers can frame the price occur and unfairness should not be involved. When firms create new
to price-disadvantaged consumers as a base price plus a discount (e.g., and unique products through bundling and apply dynamic pricing, they
$25 + 25% off), while framing the price to price-advantaged con- increase perceived dissimilarity among the transactions. The enhanced
sumers as a single price format (e.g., $15). While price framing is one dissimilarity among the transactions, in turn, reduces consumer's
way to reduce unfairness perceptions associated with dynamic pricing, comparison intentions making unfairness perceptions less likely to
we propose a new pricing strategy that combines bundling, a strategy occur. Thus, we propose:
known to extract consumer surplus, with dynamic pricing to create
H1. : Dynamic bundling results in higher fairness perceptions than
different transactions to increase perceived transaction dissimilarity
dynamic pricing.
thereby reducing consumers’ comparison intentions.
H2:. Dynamic bundling enhances fairness perceptions by increasing
2.3. Bundling perceived transaction dissimilarity and then reducing comparison
intentions.
Bundling is defined as the sale of two or more separate products in
one package (Stremersch and Tellis, 2002) that may refer to either
product bundling or price bundling. In a product bundle, different
3. Studies
products are integrated or complemented in a way that can provide
added value to consumers (Stremersch and Tellis, 2002). For example, a
3.1. Overview of studies
personalized diet plan and exercise training program are combined as
the bundle of these two products could better achieve consumers’
We test these predictions in three studies. In Study 1, we investigate
health goals than each of the products alone. For price bundling, a
the impact of dynamic bundling on fairness perceptions relative to
single price is presented for multiple products that are not integrated
dynamic pricing. We examine whether consumers in the dynamic
together (Soman and Gourville, 2001; Stremersch and Tellis, 2002). In
bundling condition perceive the price as fairer than those in the dy-
our present research, we will focus on price bundling as it has a wider
namic pricing condition (Hypothesis 1). In Study 2, we test the un-
application than product bundling. Bundling has been extensively in-
derlying mechanism in different industries (i.e., hotel and airline).
vestigated in both the economic and marketing literature. Early eco-
Specifically, we examine whether dynamic bundling will increase per-
nomic scholars focused on the financial benefit of bundling, such as
ceived transaction dissimilarity and then reduce consumers’ compar-
reducing cost (Hayes, 1987) and extracting consumer surplus (Adams
ison intentions thereby enhancing price fairness perceptions
and Yellen, 1976; Guiltinan, 1987). Marketing researchers have ex-
(Hypothesis 2). Finally, in Study 3, we include fixed pricing conditions
amined the impact of bundling on consumers’ perceptions and beha-
and directly compare dynamic bundling with fixed pricing to determine
viors (Ahmetoglu et al., 2014). Johnson et al. (1999), and Arora (2008)
their impact on consumer fairness perceptions (see Table 1 for a sum-
find that bundling can not only increase consumers’ purchase inten-
mary of the studies).
tions, but also enhance customer loyalty. Sheng and Pan (2009) de-
monstrate that bundling can help introduce a new brand. Andrews et al.

206
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

Table 1
Summary of studies.

Sampling method Research participants Methods and Objectives Results


techniques

Study 1 Convenience sample Undergraduate Experimental Design Test H1 Supported H1 - Dynamic bundling perceived as more fair
students
Study 2 Convenience sample Undergraduate Experimental Design Test H1 and H2 Supported H1 and H2 - dynamic bundling perceived as more
students fair; effect mediated by perceived dissimilarity and comparison
intentions.
Study 3 Convenience sample Undergraduate Experimental Design Compare dynamic bundling Dynamic bundling has a similar effect as fixed pricing on
students with fixed pricing. fairness perception.

3.2. Study 1 coat from the same store around the same time.
After reading the scenario, participants indicated how fair, just, and
The purpose of Study 1 is to provide an initial demonstration that reasonable they thought the price they paid for the coat was (1 =
dynamic bundling mitigates the negative impact of dynamic pricing on “extremely unfair/unjust/unreasonable,” 9 = “extremely fair/just/
price fairness perceptions. Specifically, we compare dynamic pricing reasonable) (Xia et al., 2004). These three items were combined into a
with dynamic bundling to assess their impact on price fairness per- “price fairness perceptions” measure (α = .92), which served as the
ceptions. dependent variable in all of our studies.
It is possible that consumers expect a discount when purchasing
bundled products (Kalwani and Yim, 1992) as firms often provide dis-
3.2.1. Method
counts for bundles (Janiszewski and Cunha, 2004). To control for the
A pretest was conducted with 36 participants from the same po-
effect of this expectation, we asked participants to indicate their
pulation as those in the main study to select a brand and a price for the
agreement with the statement “Consumers should receive a discount
tie-in product (jeans) used in the main study. We wanted to use a brand
when they buy a bundle of different products” (1 = “strongly disagree,”
our participants were familiar with. American Eagle, Gap, and J Crew
9 = “strongly agree”).
were assessed in the pretest in order to choose a brand to use in the
main study. American Eagle was the most familiar brand and the price
for a pair of high-end American Eagle jeans was estimated to be $89, on 3.2.2. Results
average. We also ran another pretest with 33 undergraduates to de- 3.2.2.1. Discount expectations. The mean for discount expectations was
termine whether our bundling manipulations change the quality per- 5.83 suggesting that participants did have some expectations for
ceptions of the main product. In the pretest, participants were randomly receiving a discount when purchasing a bundle. Pricing type did not
assigned to read one of the scenarios used in Study 1 and were asked to have a significant impact on discount expectations as participants in
indicate whether their quality perceptions of the main product (coat) both pricing conditions demonstrated similar discount expectations for
they purchased were similar to the one the other student purchased (1 a bundle (Mdynamic bundling = 5.94, Mdynamic pricing = 5.72, F (1, 58) =
= “very different,” 9 = “exactly the same”). Results from this pretest .16, p > .6).
indicated that there was no significant difference in the perceptions of
product quality between dynamic bundling (M = 7.88) and dynamic 3.2.2.2. Fairness perceptions. To assess price fairness perceptions
pricing (M = 7.13, F (1, 32) = 1.04, p > .3). Thus, our bundling ma- toward the coat, we ran a one-way ANCOVA with pricing type
nipulations did not impact the perceptions of product quality. (dynamic bundling vs. dynamic pricing) predicting price fairness
Sixty undergraduates completed the main study in return for partial perceptions, controlling for discount expectations. Our first
course credit. They were randomly assigned to one of the two condi- hypothesis predicts that consumers will perceive the price as fairer
tions (dynamic bundling vs. dynamic pricing). In the study, participants when dynamic bundling is used than when dynamic pricing is used. As
were provided with a scenario asking them to imagine being in a si- expected, participants assigned to the dynamic bundling condition
tuation in which they were working on a study-related task with some reported that they perceived the price they paid for the coat as fairer
fellow students (see Appendix A for the scenarios used). The scenario than those assigned to the dynamic pricing condition (Mdynamic bundling
indicated that one of the students in the group was wearing a new coat = 6.00, Mdynamic pricing = 4.99; F (1, 57) = 5.86, p = .02; R2 = .10).
that participants also have. Consistent with prior bundling manipula- Discount expectations were not significant as a control variable (F (1,
tions (Soman and Gourville, 2001; Yadav and Monroe, 1993) and our 57) = .05, p > .8). We re-ran all the analyses without discount
use of price bundling (Soman and Gourville, 2001), in the dynamic expectations as the control variable and all of the results still held.
bundling condition, participants were told that they paid $79 for the Study 1 provides evidence that dynamic bundling results in higher
coat and the fellow student paid $144 for the coat and a pair of high- fairness perceptions when compared with dynamic pricing (H1). In
end American Eagle jeans. Participants in the dynamic pricing condi- Study 1, H1 was tested in an industry where dynamic pricing has only
tion were told that they paid $79 for the coat, while the fellow student been recently introduced. Some research has indicated that consumers’
paid $55 for it. To be consistent with the dynamic bundling condition, acceptance of dynamic pricing increases as time goes by Kimes (2002).
the scenario also described the fellow student as purchasing a pair of It could be that dynamic bundling is only effective in those industries
high-end American Eagle jeans. We used the pretested price of $89 for a where dynamic pricing is new. Thus, in Study 2, to generalize our re-
pair of high-end American Eagle jeans to make the conditions eco- sults, dynamic bundling is assessed in the hotel and airline industries
nomically equivalent ($55 + $89 = $144). Thus, in our scenario, the where dynamic pricing has been practiced for a long time (Wirtz and
dynamic component of dynamic pricing is manipulated on the con- Kimes, 2007) and consumers have become more accepting of dynamic
sumer (Haws and Bearden, 2006). The same firm charges consumers pricing (Kimes, 2002). In Study 2, we will also examine the predicted
different prices for the same product. According to Haws and Bearden's serial mediation whereby dynamic bundling (vs. dynamic pricing) in-
(2006) research, temporal proximity will impact price fairness per- creases perceived dissimilarity among the transactions. In turn, this
ceptions such that temporally proximate price differences are perceived enhanced transaction dissimilarity reduces consumers’ comparison in-
as more unfair than temporally distant ones. To account for the factor of tentions and, ultimately, mitigates unfairness perceptions (i.e., pricing
temporal proximity, we told participants that they both purchased this strategy → perceived transaction dissimilarity → comparison intentions

207
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

Table 2
Correlations between different constructs.

Fair_ticket Fair_hotel Fair Comparison intentions Perceived dissimilarity Discount expectations


bundle

Fair_ticket 1.00 .716** .700** − .204** .208** − .024


Fair_hotel .716** 1.00 .795** − .125* .154** .028
Fair_bundle .700** .795** 1.00 − .190** .225** .043
Comparison Intentions − .204** − .125* − .190** 1.00 − .208** .132*
Perceived dissimilarity .208** .154** .225** − .208** 1.00 .114*
Discount expectations − .024 .028 .043 .132* .114* 1.00

** Correlation is significant at the .01 level (2-tailed).


* Correlation is significant at the .05 level (2-tailed).

→ fairness perceptions). purchased this airline ticket from Travelocity on the same day.
Although we will test our proposed model, two alternative ex- After reading the scenarios, they were asked to indicate their fair-
planations could potentially account for our results. First, our partici- ness perceptions (α = .93) toward the price they paid for the airline
pants could allocate a higher price for the main product in the bundle ticket and their price fairness perceptions of the hotel room (α = .97)
paid by the other consumers, resulting in enhanced fairness perceptions and the bundle (α = .97). Then, they responded to the measure of
for the price they paid for the main product. To account for this pos- comparison intentions (“I am unlikely to compare my purchase with the
sibility, we measure estimated prices for both the main product (airline other passenger's purchase.” anchored at 1 = “strongly disagree”, 9 =
ticket) and the tie-in product (hotel room) in Study 2. In addition, we “strongly agree”) (Xia and Monroe, 2005). This item was reverse coded
assess fairness perceptions for the tie-in product and the bundle to so that higher scores reflect higher comparison intentions. Next, they
determine the unique effects for each associated with dynamic bund- responded to three items assessing perceived transaction dissimilarity
ling. (“I think my purchase is different from the purchase of the other pas-
In addition, unlike participants in the dynamic pricing conditions senger sitting next to me,” “My purchase is unlike the purchase of the
who were told a specific price they paid for the main product, partici- other passenger sitting next to me,” and “The other passenger's pur-
pants in the dynamic bundling condition were only provided with a chase is not similar to mine.” anchored at 1 = “strongly disagree”, 9 =
total price for the bundle. Although the price for the tie-in product was “strongly agree”, α = .82) (Weisstein et al., 2013; Xia and Monroe,
based on a pretest, participants could still feel uncertain about the price 2005). We also asked participants to provide their estimated prices for
of the tie-in product, especially when the tie-in product was bundled this round-trip airline ticket and the hotel room and their confidence
with another product. This uncertainty in the price of the product in the levels about the estimated prices. Finally, their discount expectations
bundle could explain our results. As such, we ask participants to in- for the bundle were collected (see Table 2 for the correlations between
dicate their confidence levels for the estimated prices. constructs).

3.3. Study 2 3.3.2. Results


Two participants’ estimated prices for the airline ticket fell outside
3.3.1. Method three standard deviations above the mean leaving 347 usable responses.
A pretest with 33 undergraduates was conducted to determine a
price for a hotel room used in the main study. Participants were asked 3.3.2.1. Dynamic pricing manipulation check. To see whether
to provide an average price for a standard room for one night at the participants in the dynamic bundling condition perceived the price of
Holiday Inn near the Chicago airport. The average price was estimated the airline ticket as significantly different from the given price of $390,
to be $175 per night. we ran a one-sample T-test to compare the estimated price of the airline
Three hundred and forty-nine undergraduates participated in the ticket in the dynamic bundling condition with $390. The results from
study for course credit and were randomly assigned to one of two the T-test indicated that there was a significant difference between
conditions: dynamic bundling or dynamic pricing. As in previous stu- these two prices (M = $353.41, t (173) = − 4.86, p < .01). Thus, our
dies, the dynamic component of dynamic pricing was manipulated on participants in the dynamic bundling condition perceived the price of
the consumer dimension such that different consumers were charged the airline ticket as different from the given price of $390. These results
different prices for the same airline ticket. In the study, participants provided support for our dynamic pricing manipulation.
read instructions asking them to imagine that they were taking a trip to
visit a friend in Chicago for the weekend (see Appendix B for the sce- 3.3.2.2. Fairness perceptions. We conducted a MANCOVA with pricing
narios used). On the airplane, they were talking to the person sitting strategy (dynamic bundling vs. dynamic pricing) as the independent
next to them. In the dynamic bundling condition, participants were told variable and price fairness perceptions of the airline ticket, hotel room,
that they paid $390 for this round-trip airline ticket, while the person and bundle serving as the dependent variables, controlling for discount
sitting next to them paid $640 for both the round-trip airline ticket and expectations. The MANCOVA results revealed that pricing strategy had
a standard room for two nights ($175 * 2 = $350) at the Holiday Inn a significant impact on price fairness perceptions (Wilks's Lambda F (3,
near the airport. In the dynamic pricing condition, participants were 342) = 89.16, p < .01). Discount expectations were not significant as a
told that they paid $390 for this round-trip airline ticket, while the control variable (Wilks's Lambda F (3, 342) = .99, p > .3). Consistent
person sitting next to them paid $290 for the same airline ticket. The with the results of Study 1, participants in the dynamic bundling
pretested price of $175 per night for the hotel room was used to make condition perceived the price they paid for the airline ticket as
the conditions economically equivalent. To be consistent with the dy- significantly fairer than that of the dynamic pricing condition
namic bundling condition, the scenario also described this person as (Mdynamic bundling = 5.82, Mdynamic pricing = 2.79; F (1, 344) =
booking a standard room for two nights at the Holiday Inn near the 268.34, p < .01; R2 = .44). The results for price fairness perceptions
airport. Since the timing of booking an airline ticket and booking of the hotel room and the bundle followed the same patterns. The price
agency play crucial roles in determining the price of an airline ticket, of the hotel room was perceived as fairer in the dynamic bundling
we fixed these two variables by telling participants that both of them condition (M = 5.85) than in the dynamic pricing condition (M = 3.85;

208
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

fixed pricing conditions: fixed pricing with bundling and fixed pricing
without bundling (see Appendix C). In the fixed pricing conditions, the
prices both consumers paid for the airline ticket were the same. Ninety-
five undergraduate students participated for partial course credit. The
study used a 2 (pricing strategy: dynamic pricing or fixed pricing) × 2
(bundling type: bundling or without bundling) between-subject design.
Participants were randomly assigned to one of the conditions. In the
fixed pricing with bundling condition, participants were told that they
paid $390 for the round-trip airline ticket, while the person sitting next
to them paid $740 for both the round-trip airline ticket and a standard
room for two nights at the Holiday Inn near the Chicago airport. In the
fixed pricing without bundling condition, participants were told that
they paid $390 for the round-trip airline ticket and the person sitting
next to them paid $390 for the same ticket. To be consistent with the
dynamic/fixed bundling conditions, the scenario also described this
person as booking a standard room for two nights at the Holiday Inn
Fig. 2. Study 2 serial mediation results. Note: * = p < .05; ** = p < .01. near the Chicago airport. The timing of booking the ticket and the
booking agency were controlled at the end of these two scenarios as
F (1, 344) = 104.21, p < .01; R2 = .23). The same results were found they were in the two dynamic pricing conditions.
for the price fairness perceptions of the bundle (Mdynamic bundling = After reading the scenario, participants indicated their fairness
6.07, Mdynamic pricing = 3.94; F (1, 344) = 104.41, p < .01; R2 = .23). perceptions (α = .89) toward the price they paid for this airline ticket.
Thus, dynamic bundling not only enhanced the price fairness Then, they completed a manipulation check for the pricing strategy.
perceptions of the main product, but also that of the tie-in product They were asked to indicate how stable the price of the airline ticket
and the bundle. was on a nine-point scale (1 = “very unstable,” 9 = “very stable”).
Finally, their discount expectations for the bundle were collected.
3.3.2.3. Test of mediation. We then tested the predicted serial
mediation (pricing strategy → perceived transaction dissimilarity → 3.4.2. Results
comparison intentions → fairness perceptions of the airline) controlling 3.4.2.1. Manipulation check. Participants in the dynamic pricing
for discount expectations. A bootstrap analysis with 5000 samples conditions perceived the price of the airline ticket to be significantly
(Model 6, Preacher and Hayes, 2008) indicated that the full serial less stable (Mdynamic pricing = 4.04) than those in the fixed pricing
mediation model was significant (indirect effect = .01, SE = .01, 95% conditions (Mfixed pricing = 5.90; F (1, 93) =18.67, p < .01). These
CI = .0021–.0406) (see Fig. 2). Dynamic bundling increased perceived results supported our pricing strategy manipulations as the price in the
transaction dissimilarity. The enhanced transaction dissimilarity fixed pricing condition was deemed more stable than that in the
reduced our participants’ comparison intentions, while the decrease dynamic pricing condition.
in comparison intentions led to higher fairness perceptions.
To account for the potential alternative explanations associated 3.4.2.2. Fairness perceptions. We conducted an ANCOVA with the
with the price estimates of the airline ticket and the hotel room and the fairness perceptions as the dependent measure and pricing strategy
confidence participants have in each of these estimates, we ran a second (dynamic pricing vs. fixed pricing) and bundling type (bundling vs.
serial mediation controlling for these four factors on price fairness without bundling) as predictors, controlling for discount expectations.
perceptions. The results still revealed a significant indirect effect (in- Discount expectations were not significant as a control variable (F (1,
direct effect = .01, SE = .01, 95% CI = .0021–.0420) when controlling 90) = 1.00, p > .3). Both of the main effects of pricing strategy (F (1,
for these variables. 90) = 5.47, p = .02) and bundling type (F (1, 90) = 6.97 p = .01)
We also ran four additional simple mediation models (Model 4) with were significant. More importantly, the interaction between pricing
the estimated price of the airline ticket and the hotel room and their strategy and bundling type was significant (F (1, 90) = 19.55, p < .01;
confidence levels of the estimations each as the mediator, controlling R2 = .27) (see Fig. 3). Specifically, among participants in the dynamic
for discount expectations. None of these mediation models was sig- pricing conditions, those who are also in the bundling condition
nificant. perceived the price they paid for the airline ticket as fairer than those
The results of Study 2 provide further support for the effectiveness in the without bundling condition (Mbundling = 6.32, Mwithout bundling =
of dynamic bundling, as well as the underlying process associated with 3.92; F (1, 90) = 25.26, p < .01). In the fixed pricing conditions, there
the effect. Not only does dynamic bundling enhance fairness percep-
tions of the price of the main product, it also boosts the fairness per-
ceptions of the prices of the tie-in product and the bundle overall. More
importantly, we rule out several potential alternative explanations.
Thus far, we have only compared dynamic bundling with dynamic
pricing and shown that dynamic bundling results in higher fairness
perceptions than dynamic pricing. If we can demonstrate that dynamic
bundling leads to price fairness perceptions as fair as fixed pricing,
firms may feel more confident in implementing dynamic bundling. In
Study 3, we directly compare dynamic bundling with fixed pricing to
assess their relative impact on price fairness perceptions.

3.4. Study 3

3.4.1. Method
Fig. 3. Study 3 results. R2 = .27.
Study 3 used the same scenarios provided in Study 2, but added two

209
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

was no significant difference for fairness perceptions between the transaction dissimilarity to reduce fairness perceptions in a dynamic
bundling and without bundling conditions (Mbundling = 5.60, Mwithout pricing context. Further, previous research has not empirically de-
bundling = 6.21; F (1, 90) = 1.61, p > .1). monstrated the role comparison intentions play in a dynamic pricing
To directly compare dynamic bundling with fixed pricing, we ran an context.
additional ANCOVA with the following three conditions: dynamic pri- The current research focuses on price fairness perceptions that may
cing with bundling, fixed pricing with bundling, and fixed pricing ultimately impact long-term profitability. We contribute to the existing
without bundling, controlling for discount expectations. The results literature on bundling by demonstrating that it can be used with dy-
indicated that there was no significant difference in fairness perceptions namic pricing to mitigate unfairness perceptions associated with dy-
across these three conditions (F (1, 68) = 1.20, p > .3). Thus, dynamic namic pricing. We also provide a process explanation as to why
bundling leads to price perceptions as fair as those of fixed pricing. We bundling has this effect. The results from our studies provide evidence
re-ran all the analyses without discount expectations as the control that bundling alleviates unfairness perceptions by increasing perceived
variable and all of the results still held. transaction dissimilarity and, in turn, decreasing consumers’ compar-
The results of Study 3 replicate the results of our previous studies ison intentions.
that dynamic bundling leads to greater fairness perceptions than dy-
namic pricing. Additionally, in Study 3, we found that dynamic bund- 4.2. Managerial implications
ling and fixed pricing generate similar fairness perceptions. As such,
given that dynamic bundling can extract consumer surplus to help firms Our research provides insight as to how firms could implement
increase their profitability, firms should consider dynamic bundling as a dynamic pricing without fostering unfairness perceptions. When using
superior pricing strategy over fixed pricing. dynamic pricing, firms could combine it with bundling to alleviate the
negative effect on consumer fairness perceptions. Essentially, we pro-
4. General discussion vide firms a new pricing strategy, dynamic bundling. With the aid of the
Internet and digital media, consumers can easily compare and share
Although dynamic pricing helps increase firms’ profitability, it also price information. Our research provides marketers with a timely so-
can arouse consumer unfairness perceptions (Haws and Bearden, 2006; lution and an easy-to-implement tool.
Petro, 2015). The current research offers a solution for this problem by An additional practical implication of our research lies in the find-
recommending a new pricing strategy, dynamic bundling. The results ings that perceived transaction dissimilarity and comparison intentions
from three studies provide evidence that when compared with dynamic account for why dynamic bundling results in higher fairness percep-
pricing, dynamic bundling not only leads to higher fairness perceptions, tions. By bundling different products together, firms increase perceived
but also generates perceptions as fair as those of fixed pricing. This transaction dissimilarity among the transactions. The high level of
effect emerged across multiple types of products and scenarios. Our dissimilarity makes consumers less likely to compare their transactions.
studies also identify a novel underlying mechanism for pricing research, Thus, for firms who want to implement dynamic pricing, they should
while ruling out a number of alternative explanations. Dynamic bund- reduce consumers’ intentions to compare transactions. Customized
ling increases the perceived dissimilarity among transactions making coupons is another strategy firms can use to serve this purpose.
consumers less likely to make a comparison. In turn, the reduced Depending upon consumers’ profiles or interests, and their purchase
comparison intentions reduce the probability of creating unfairness history, different consumers will receive different types of coupons.
perceptions. We provide further support for the proposed mechanism These different coupons will increase perceived transaction dissim-
by addressing potential alternative explanations. Specifically, we de- ilarity thereby reducing consumer comparison intentions.
monstrate that dynamic bundling enhances fairness perceptions beyond Our results also provide a new factor for firms to take into account
the effect of consumers’ discount expectations for the bundles. Our when they decide whether to use bundling. Although previous research
studies further eliminate estimated prices of the products in the bundle suggests numerous reasons for using bundling, most highlight the
and uncertainty as to the external reference price of the tie-in product economic impact on current transactions. None has explored the impact
as alternative explanations. By proposing a new pricing strategy and of bundling on fairness perceptions, which may impact multiple eco-
establishing its effectiveness, we offer several important theoretical and nomic measures.
managerial implications.
4.3. Limitations and future research
4.1. Theoretical implications
Although we have demonstrated the superiority of dynamic bund-
Our research contributes to the dynamic pricing literature. We use ling on the impact of fairness perceptions relative to dynamic pricing,
social comparison and equity theory (Adams, 1965) to explain why there are some limitations associated with the current research. The
dynamic pricing is likely to arouse unfairness perceptions. We de- primary limitation of our research is that we use lab-based experiments
monstrate that the current practice of dynamic pricing leads to high to assess the effectiveness of dynamic bundling. Future field research is
perceived transaction similarity prompting consumers to compare their needed, especially to examine the impact of dynamic bundling on
transactions. By identifying the important roles of perceived transaction consumer surplus extraction. Both dynamic pricing and bundling have
dissimilarity and comparison intentions, we are able to introduce a new been found to be able to extract consumer surplus (Adams and Yellen,
pricing strategy to address the problem of unfairness perceptions. 1976; Venkatesh and Mahajan, 2009). Thus, we expect that dynamic
Our research also provides important theoretical implications for bundling, the combination of these two strategies, could extract con-
the literature on bundling. While previous research on bundling has sumer surplus beyond dynamic pricing. Future research should em-
found numerous benefits for using it, such as extracting consumer pirically test whether dynamic bundling has the additional benefit of
surplus (Venkatesh and Mahajan, 2009), increasing purchase intentions extracting consumer surplus beyond dynamic pricing. Perhaps panel
(Johnson et al., 1999; Arora, 2008), enhancing perceived value data could be used by future researchers to assess this and further ex-
(Andrews et al., 2010), introducing new products (Sheng and Pan, amine the role of social comparison by combining panel data with
2009), and differentiating products and services (Dominique-Ferreira consumer surveys.
et al., 2016), none of this research has introduced or measured the In addition, future research should investigate the need for cogni-
impact of dynamic bundling on price fairness perceptions. All of the tion as a boundary condition for the effectiveness of dynamic bundling.
previous research examined the impact of bundling alone on current Perhaps those whose need for cognition is high will not be aided by the
profitability. Additionally, none of the previous research utilized increased price fairness perceptions associated with dynamic bundling.

210
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

Another boundary condition future research can examine is consumer same round-trip airline ticket. You both purchased from Travelocity on
status (existing vs. new consumers). Fernandes and Calamote (2016) the same day.
found that new vs. existing clients and the advantaged vs. dis-
advantaged condition affect consumers’ price fairness perceptions. Ex- Fixed pricing without bundling condition
isting customers (vs. new customers) demonstrated the strongest un-
fairness perceptions when exposed to a disadvantaged price condition. Imagine that you are taking a trip to visit a friend in Chicago for the
Thus, future research could examine whether consumer status (existing weekend. When you talk with the person sitting next to you on the
vs. new) influences the effectiveness of dynamic bundling. Finally, fu- airplane, you find out that this person is about the same age and paid
ture researchers can assess whether dynamic bundling is even more $390 for this round-trip airline ticket to Chicago. This person has also
effective for unfamiliar brands. It is our hope that the introduction of booked a standard room for two nights at the Holiday Inn near the
the dynamic bundling strategy will spur future research into a greater airport. You paid $390 for the exact same round-trip airline ticket. You
understanding of its effectiveness both purchased from Travelocity on the same day.

Appendix A. Study 1 scenarios References

Dynamic bundling condition Adams, J.S., 1965. Inequity in social exchange. In: Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in
Experimental Social Psychology Vol. 2. Academic Press, New York, NY, pp. 267–299.
Adams, W.J., Yellen, J.L., 1976. Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly. Q. J.
Imagine that you are working on a study-related task with some Econ. 90, 475–498.
fellow students. One of the students in the group is wearing a new coat Ahmetoglu, G., Furnham, A., Fagan, P., 2014. Pricing practices: a critical review of their
you also have. When you talk with this student, you find out that you effects on consumer perceptions and behavior. J. Retail. Cons. Serv. 21 (5), 696–707.
Andrews, M.L., Benedicktus, R.L., Brady, M.K., 2010. The effect of incentives on customer
both purchased the coat from the same store around the same time. You evaluations of service bundles. J. Bus. Res. 63 (1), 71–76.
paid $79 for this coat. This student paid $144 for this coat and a pair of Angwin, J., Mattioli, D., 2012. Coming soon: toilet paper priced like airline tickets. Wall
high-end American Eagle jeans. Str. J. /SB10000872396390444914904577617333130724846〉.
Arora, R., 2008. Price bundling and framing strategies for complementary products. J.
Prod. Brand Manag. 17 (7), 475–484.
Dynamic pricing condition Bolton, L.E., Warlop, L., Alba, J.W., 2003. Consumer perceptions of price (un)fairness. J.
Consum. Res. 29, 474–491.
Campbell, M.C., 1999. Perceptions of price unfairness: antecedents and consequences. J.
Imagine that you are working on a study-related task with some
Mark. Res. 47 (May), 187–199.
fellow students. One of the students in the group is wearing a new coat Corcoran, K., Crusius, J., Mussweiler, T., 2011. Social Comparison: Motives, Standards,
you also have. When you talk with this student, you find out that you and Mechanisms in Theories in Social Psychology. Wiley-BlackWell, Oxford, UK, pp.
both purchased the coat from the same store around the same time. You 119–139.
Dominique-Ferreira, S., 2017. How important is the strategic order of product attribute
paid $79 for this coat. This student paid $55 for this coat. This student presentation in the non-life insurance market? J. Retail. Cons. Serv. 34, 138–144.
also purchased a pair of high-end American Eagle jeans. Dominique-Ferreira, S., Vasconcelos, H., Proença, J.F., 2016. Determinants of customer
price sensitivity: an empirical analysis. J. Serv. Mark. 30 (3), 327–340.
Fernandes, T., Calamote, A., 2016. Unfairness in consumer services: outcomes of differ-
Appendix B. Studies 2 scenarios ential treatment of new and existing clients. J. Retail. Cons. Serv. 28, 36–44.
Festinger, L., 1954. A theory of social comparison processes. Hum. Relat. 7 (2), 117–140.
Dynamic bundling condition Garbarino, E., Lee, O.F., 2003. Dynamic pricing in internet retail: effects on consumer
trust. Psychol. Mark. 20 (6), 495–513.
Gilbride, T.J., Guiltinan, J.P., Urbany, J.E., 2008. Framing effects in mixed price bund-
Imagine that you are taking a trip to visit a friend in Chicago for the ling. Mark. Lett. 19 (2), 125–139.
weekend. When you talk with the person sitting next to you on the Grégoire, Y., Fisher, R.J., 2008. Customer betrayal and retaliation: when your best cus-
tomers become your worst enemies. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 36 (2), 247–261.
airplane, you find out that this person is about the same age and paid Grewal, D., Hardesty, D.M., Iyer, G.K.R., 2004. The effects of buyer identification and
$640 for both this round-trip airline ticket and a standard room for two purchase timing on consumers' perceptions of trust, price fairness, and repurchase
nights at the Holiday Inn near the airport. You paid $390 for the exact intentions. J. Interact. Mark. 18, 87–100.
Guiltinan, J.P., 1987. The price bundling of services: a normative framework. J. Mark. 51,
same round-trip airplane ticket. You both purchased from Travelocity
74–85.
on the same day. Haws, K.L., Bearden, W.O., 2006. Dynamic pricing and consumer fairness perceptions. J.
Consum. Res. 33, 304–311.
Dynamic pricing without bundling condition Hayes, B., 1987. Competition and two-part tariffs. J. Bus. 60 (1), 41–54.
Janiszewski, C., Cunha, M., 2004. The influence of price discount framing on the eva-
luation of a product bundle. J. Consum. Res. 30, 534–546.
Imagine that you are taking a trip to visit a friend in Chicago for the Jayaraman, V., Baker, T., 2003. The internet as an enabler for dynamic pricing of goods.
weekend. When you talk with the person sitting next to you on the IEEE Trans. Eng. Manag. 50 (4), 470–477.
Johnson, M.D., Herrmann, A., Bauer, H.H., 1999. The effects of price bundling on con-
airplane, you find out that this person is about the same age and paid sumer evaluations of product offerings. Int. J. Res. Mark. 16 (2), 129–142.
$290 for this round-trip airline ticket to Chicago. This person has also Kalwani, M.U., Yim, C.K., 1992. Consumer price and promotion expectations: an ex-
booked a standard room for two nights at the Holiday Inn near the perimental study. J. Mark. Res. 29 (1), 90–100.
Kannan, P.K., Kopalle, P.K., 2001. Dynamic pricing on the internet: importance and im-
airport. You paid $390 for the exact same round-trip airline ticket. You plications for consumer behavior. Int. J. Electron. Commun. 5, 63–83.
both purchased from Travelocity on the same day. Kimes, S.E., 2002. Perceived fairness of yield management. Cornell Hotel Rest. A 43 (1),
21–30.
Koschat, M.A., Putsis Jr., W.P., 2002. Audience characteristics and bundling: a hedonic
Appendix C. Study 3 scenarios analysis of magazine advertising rates. J. Mark. Res. 39 (2), 262–273.
Mohammed, R., 2012. Why online retailers' new pricing strategy will backfire. Harvard
Fixed pricing with bundling condition Bus. Rev. Available at 〈https://hbr.org/2012/12/why-online-retailers-new-prici〉.
Monroe, K.B., 2003. Pricing: Making Profitable Decisions. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, Burr
Ridge, IL.
Imagine that you are taking a trip to visit a friend in Chicago for the Mussweiler, T., 2003. Everything is relative: comparison processes in social judgment.
weekend. When you talk with the person sitting next to you on the Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. 33 (6), 719–733.
airplane, you find out that this person is about the same age and paid Naylor, G., Frank, K.E., 2001. The effect of price bundling on consumer perceptions of
value. J. Serv. Mark. 15 (4), 270–281.
$740 for both this round-trip airline ticket and a standard room for two Oliver, R.L., Swan, J.E., 1989. Consumer perceptions of interpersonal equity and
nights at the Holiday Inn near the airport. You paid $390 for the exact

211
W. Li et al. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 40 (2018) 204–212

satisfaction in transaction: a field survey approach. J. Mark. 53, 21–35. Trope, Y., 1986. Self-enhancement and self-assessment in achievement behavior. In:
Petro, G., 2015. Dynamic pricing: which customers are worth the most? Amazon, Delta Sorrentino, R., Higgins, E.T. (Eds.), Handbook of Motivation and Cognition Vol. 2.
Airlines and Staples weigh in. Forbes. April. Available at 〈http://www.forbes.com/ Guilford, New York, NY, pp. 350–378.
sites/gregpetro/2015/04/17/dynamic-pricing-which-customers-are-worth-the-most- Venkatesh, R., Mahajan, V., 2009. The Design and Pricing of Bundles: A Review of
amazon-delta-airlines-and-staples-weigh-in/〉. Normative Guidelines and Practical Approaches. Handbook of Pricing Research in
Preacher, K.J., Hayes, A.F., 2008. Asymptotic and resampling strategies for assessing and Marketing. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA.
comparing indirect effects in multiple mediator models. Behav. Res. Methods 40 (3), Wang, T., Venkatesh, R., Chatterjee, R., 2007. Reservation price as a range: an incentive-
879–891. compatible measurement approach. J. Mark. Res. 44, 200–213.
Sheng, S., Pan, Y., 2009. Bundling as a new product introduction strategy: the role of Weisstein, F.L., Monroe, K.B., Kukar-Kinney, M., 2013. Effects of price framing on con-
brand image and bundle features. J. Retail. Cons. Serv. 16, 367–376. sumers’ perceptions of online dynamic pricing practices. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 41,
Soman, D., Gourville, J., 2001. Transaction decoupling: how price bundling affects the 501–514.
decision to consume. J. Mark. Res. 38 (1), 30–44. Wirtz, J., Kimes, S.E., 2007. The moderating role of familiarity in fairness perceptions of
Streitfeld, D., 2000. On the Web, price tags blur. Washington Post Online, September. revenue management pricing. J. Serv. Res. 9, 229–240.
Available at 〈http://www.wright.edu/~tdung/amazon.htm〉. Xia, L., Monroe, K.B., 2005. Comparison references and the effects of price unfairness
Stremersch, S., Tellis, G.J., 2002. Strategic bundling of products and prices: a new perceptions. In: Behavioral Pricing Conference Proceedings. University of Illinois,
synthesis for marketing. J. Mark. 66, 55–72. U.S.
Taylor, S.E., Wayment, H.A., Carrillo, M., 1996. Social comparison, self-regulation, and Xia, L., Monroe, K.B., Cox, J.L., 2004. The price is unfair! A conceptual framework of
motivation. In: Handbook of Motivation and Cognition. Guildford Press, New York, price fairness perceptions. J. Mark. 68, 1–15.
NY, pp. 3-27. Yadav, M.S., Monroe, K.B., 1993. How buyers perceive savings in bundle price: an ex-
Trope, Y., 1983. Self-assessment in achievement behavior. In: Suls, J., Greenwald, A. amination of a bundle's transaction value. J. Mark. Res. 30, 350–358.
(Eds.), Psychological Perspectives on the Self Vol. 2. Erlbaum, Hillsdale, NJ, pp. Yan, R., Myers, C., Wang, J., Ghose, S., 2014. Bundling products to success: the influence
93–121. of complementarity and advertising. J. Retail. Cons. Serv. 21, 48–53.

212

You might also like