You are on page 1of 9

Received: 16 June 2020 Revised: 3 August 2020 Accepted: 5 August 2020

DOI: 10.1002/pa.2360

ACADEMIC PAPER

Risk preferences for financial decisions: Do emotional


biases matter?

Ritika | Nawal Kishor

School of Management Studies, Indira Gandhi


National Open University, New Delhi, India The aim of this article is to evaluate the effect of emotional biases (namely over-
confidence bias, self-control bias, loss aversion bias, and regret aversion bias) on risk
Correspondence
Ritika, School of Management Studies, Indira preferences of individual investors. A structured questionnaire is developed by taking
Gandhi National Open University, 93, Maidan
excerpts from various existing studies to evaluate emotional biases and the construct
Garhi Road, Maidan Garhi, New Delhi, Delhi
110068, India. of risk preferences is adopted from “domain specific risk-taking scale” (DOSPERT).
Email: ritikaaneja.aneja@gmail.com
The data are analyzed using structural equation modeling. The findings reveal that
overconfidence bias and self-control bias have significant positive relationship with
risk preferences, whereas with loss aversion bias and regret aversion bias, a signifi-
cant negative relationship of the risk preferences is found. The study contributes to
the existing literature by examining the effect of feelings and emotions on risk. The
findings of the study further confirm that risk is influenced by emotions and feelings.
The results of this study will be of great use to policy makers, investment consultants,
retail investors, regulators, and various other stakeholders associated with preparing
and suggesting investment strategies for their own or for others.

1 | I N T RO DU CT I O N value of possible gains and losses without considering the final


outcome.
The standard finance is based on the assumption that investors take Investors employ various heuristics to evaluate the gains and
all investment decisions rationally after analyzing all the available losses of their financial decisions. Empirical evidence suggests that
information (Kumar & Goyal, 2015). It also assumes that the risk risk preferences of investors are affected by various emotions such as
preferences of the investors are according to the norms as described anger, worry, and others (Campos-Vazquez & Cuilty, 2014; Kugler,
by expected utility theory and mean variance analysis. It augments Connolly, & Ordóñez, 2012). But the role of emotional biases in decid-
that investors perceive their risk correctly and their risk preference ing the risk preferences of the investors is less known. Also, it is cru-
is not influenced by heuristics or behavioral biases. But behavioral cial to understand about the emotional forces leading to biased
finance researchers view risk taking from a different angle as com- investment decisions. The present research aims to bridge this gap
pared to traditional finance researchers. The proponents of behav- related to the effect of emotional biases on risk. The study contributes
ioral finance have time and again showed that people employ to the existing literature concerned with “risk as feeling hypothesis”
heuristics in taking decisions under situation of risk or uncertainty put forth by Loewenstein, Weber, Hsee, and Welch (2001).
(Antony, 2020; Barnes, 1984; Schwenk, 1984; Strong, 2007). Deci-
sions under risk and uncertainty in the field of behavioral finance are
examined with the help of prospect theory advocated by Kahneman 2 | LI T E RA T U R E RE V I E W A N D
and Tversky (1979). This theory departs from the assumption of HY P O T H E S E S D EV E L O P M EN T
complete rationality (as devised by classical economic theories) and
focuses on cognitive and emotional limitations of decision makers 2.1 | Heterogeneity of risk
(Edwards, 1995; Olsen, 1997; Ricciardi, 2005). According to this the-
ory, human beings are risk averse in case of profits and risk takers Risk is defined as the possibility of happening of undesirable events
regarding losses. They make financial decisions keeping in mind, the (Sitkin & Pablo, 1992). Risk can be defined along various dimensions

J Public Affairs. 2020;e2360. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/pa © 2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 1 of 9
https://doi.org/10.1002/pa.2360
2 of 9 RITIKA AND KISHOR

namely risk tolerance, risk propensity, risk-taking ability, risk prefer- the interpretation of information, it may affect the risk preferences of
ence, risk attitude, and risk propensity. The terms such as risk propen- the individuals (Barnes, 1984; Schwenk, 1984). Due to presence of
sity, risk-taking ability, risk attitude, and risk preference are used some behavioral biases, individuals mark down the uncertainty and
interchangeably in the academic literature (Baker & Ricciardi, 2014). negative outcomes related to their decisions and thus underestimate
There is no universally accepted definition of risk preferences the associated risk (Cooper, Woo, & Dunkelberg, 1988; Shaver &
(Baker & Ricciardi, 2014). Risk preference is generally defined as the Scott, 1992).
tendency of an individual to take or avoid risk (Sitkin & Pablo, 1992). The academic literature shows the effect of various emotions
This concept illustrates what an individual chooses in between a risky (fear, happiness, surprise, disgust, and anger) on probability weighing
and a safer alternative. This differs from an individual to another indi- (Baker & Nofsinger, 2002; Fehr-Duda, Epper, Bruhin, &
vidual because what is “undesirable” can be different for different Schubert, 2011; Kliger & Levy, 2008; Rottenstreich & Hsee, 2001).
individuals. The researchers of behavioral finance use risk preferences Fear leads to higher risk aversion. Academic literature supports that
to explain the financial and investment behavior. risk preferences of an investor are affected by external stimuli
Risk preference of the investors is difficult to generalize as it is (Bateman, Islam, Louviere, Satchell, & Thorp, 2011; Roszkowski &
based upon various subjective and objective factors which affect the Davey, 2010). For example, situations leading to pessimism (such as
judgments of individuals regarding various investment options and Covid-19) may lead to a reduction in the risk tolerance of investors.
financial services (Thaler & Johnson, 1990). The opinions and judg- Fundamentally, the effect of emotions on risk preferences is evident
ments of human beings regarding financial decision making are shaped but still underrated (Chang, 2007). Studies suggest that people having
by various factors such as family background, education, personal less emotional biases (ones who are emotionally stable) take decisions
understanding, profession, and others (Grable & Roszkowski, 2008; on the basis of expected utility theory (Charupat, Deaves, Derouin,
Olsen, 2000; Olsen & Cox, 2001). Risk seekers prefer less safety mea- Klotzle, & Miu, 2013).
sures (like keeping money for precautionary purpose) as compared to
risk averters (Sciortino, Huston, & Spencer, 1987). Risk preferences
vary from an individual to another individual and from one country to 2.2.1 | Overconfidence bias and risk taking
another country (Weber & Hsee, 1998).
Overconfidence can be defined as supreme faith in one's own abilities
(Odean, 1998). Overconfidence stems from illusion of knowledge and
2.2 | Emotional biases and risk taking optimism (Russo & Schoemaker, 1992). Due to illusion of knowledge,
investors think themselves to be “better than average” in intelligence,
The proponents of behavioral finance apply theories from psychology stock picking, and risk-taking abilities (Ricciardi & Simon, 2000;
and sociology to financial decisions (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; Strong, 2007). They feel that due to their knowledge and abilities,
Ricciardi, 2008; Thaler & Johnson, 1990). Various studies have they can control the risk of their portfolio and can easily escape the
explored the role of cognitive aspects on financial risk taking negative consequences arising due to their choices. Optimist investors
(Edwards, 1995; Olsen, 1997; Ricciardi, 2005). But the effect of emo- feel that only good will happen to them, leading them to underestima-
tions on investment decisions is less explored. A remarkable work in tion of costs and over stating of gains. So, they feel themselves to be
this regard is “risk -as- feelings” hypothesis (Loewenstein et al., 2001) invulnerable to various risky situations. This bias leads to misinterpre-
in which the authors state that tation and lower perception of risk by the investors (Barnes, 1984;
Nofsinger, 2017; Russo & Schoemaker, 1992). So, they take end up
Feelings play a much more prominent role in risk taking more risk (Barber & Odean, 2001).
decision-making than they are given credit for by the
cognitive-consequentialist tradition of judgment and H1 Overconfident investors prefer to take more risks.
decision-making research.

Also, they argue that, 2.2.2 | Loss aversion bias

The decision-theoretic approach to decision-making Traditional finance is based on expected utility and measures invest-
under risk has largely ignored the role played by emo- ment risk with the help of skewness and kurtosis (Olsen, 2000). But
tions… very little attention has been given to the the tenets of behavioral finance relate investment risk to perceived
impact of emotions (p. 280) risk and assume that investors are loss averse and they take less risk
in order to avoid the losses. Prospect theory rests on the assumption
Psychological researchers assert that “emotional reactions” occur of loss aversion, which refers to the tendency of people to avoid
prior to “cognitive evaluations” (LeDoux, 1996; Zajonc, 1980). Judg- losses (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). People susceptible to this bias
ment and decision making is guided by perceptions which are framed give more importance to losses as compared to gains. Academic litera-
by emotional aspects (Damasio, 1994). Since behavioral biases effect ture reports that losses bother the investors twice as compared to an
RITIKA AND KISHOR 3 of 9

equivalent gain (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). Loss averse investors Wood, 2006; Prosad, Kapoor, & Sengupta, 2015; Weber, Blais, &
avoid investing in portfolios with high risk in order to minimize the Betz, 2002). The statements were evaluated on a five-point Likert
probability of loss (Duxbury & Summers, 2004). Evidence also sug- scale extending from 1 (strongly disagree) to 5 (strongly agree).
gests that emotions affect loss aversion thus affecting the risk toler- Traditional finance takes into consideration the objective measures
ance (Dhar & Wertenbroch, 2000). of risk using stock beta, variance, standard deviation, and CAPM (capital
asset pricing model). Behavioral finance scholars measure subjective
H2 Investors susceptible to loss aversion bias prefer to take less risk. (psychological) aspects of risk using various multidimensional variables.
When taking a decision under situation of risk, an investor looks upon
the measurement of financial risk as well as the indicators of behavioral
2.2.3 | Regret aversion bias risk (Ricciardi, 2008). The measure of risk preference used in this study
is, “domain specific risk-taking scale (DOSPERT)” formulated by Weber
Academic literature shows that regret leads to negative emotions et al. (2002). DOSPERT is a measure which assesses the self-reported
(Fogel & Berry, 2006; Summers & Duxbury, 2012). The feeling of risk-taking ability of individuals in five areas. The construct related with
regret stems from a bad outcome and the awareness that a better investment risk taking was adopted from this scale to measure the risk
outcome could have been achieved with a different choice (Fogel & preferences of the investors. Participants were asked to rate the possi-
Berry, 2006). Regret aversion bias is a bias which states that people bility of engaging in the risk-taking behavior on a scale extending from
avoid taking decisions in order to keep away from the regret of mak- 1 (extremely unlikely) to 5 (extremely likely). In order to check the con-
ing bad decisions (Connolly & Zeelenberg, 2002). Due to this bias, tent validity of the questionnaire, it was sent for pretesting to three
people make very conservative investment choices due to the regret behavioral finance experts, two academicians and three experienced
associated with poor results on risky investment choices made in the investors. The reviewers were asked to report the flaws in the ques-
past (Pompian & Wood, 2006; Thaler & Johnson, 1990). Regret aver- tionnaire. Minor revision was done in the questionnaire based on the
sion bias affects the foreign exchange risk (Steil, 1993). feedback from the reviewers.

H3 Investors susceptible to regret aversion bias take less risk.


3.2 | Data collection and methods used

2.2.4 | Self-control bias To have a better perspective of the valuation process, research on
risk must focus on the individual decision makers (Cooley, 1977). So,
Self-control bias is the behavioral propensity of investors to save less the current study is based on the individual investors investing in the
for future in order to spend more today (Pompian & Wood, 2006). financial markets. All the respondents for the current study were indi-
According to traditional finance, rational investor takes all necessary vidual investors residing in Delhi. Data were collected from a sample
measures in order to fulfill their long-term objectives. But it has been consisting of 720 investors selected using a combination of judgmen-
reported in the literature, people even after knowing that is necessary tal and snowball sampling technique from investors residing in Delhi
for them, fail to save adequately for their long-term goals (such as for and having investment in financial markets. In the initial phase, pilot
retirement purposes; Pompian & Wood, 2006). Due to this bias, inves- study was conducted using responses from 60 investors and the reli-
tors invest in more risky securities such as equity as compared to ability and content validity of the instrument was assessed. In the next
bonds and debentures because they feel unable to control their and final phase, the responses were collected from 720 investors hav-
behavior. They take more risk in order to get more money for spend- ing investment in financial markets. The data were collected in the
ing (Lusardi & Mitchell, 2007). Higher risk-taking behavior is associ- form of a field survey during the period from July 2019 to February
ated with lower self-control (Samuels et al., 2004; White et al., 1994). 2020. The data were sorted and analyzed using the Statistical Package
for the Social Science (SPSS) 20 and AMOS 20 (Analysis of Moment
H4 Investors susceptible to self-control bias take more risk. Structures) softwares. Table 1 shows the demographic profile of the
respondents. The results showed that most of the respondents were
males, aged 20–35 years, having postgraduation degree, a permanent
3 | M E TH O DO LO GY job, and income up to 5,00,000 rupees.

3.1 | Instrument design and refinement


4 | RE SU LT S
The purpose of the study is to evaluate the effect of emotional biases
on the risk preferences of individual investors. So, statements related This study employs SEM (structural equation modeling) to analyze the
to various emotional biases in the study were taken from existing effect of emotional biases on risk preferences of individual investors.
studies and then modified and used for this study (Baker, Kumar, SEM is utilized here because of its privilege of concomitantly testing
Goyal, & Gaur, 2019; Jain, Walia, & Gupta, 2019; Pompian & all the variables hypothesized in the model (Westland, 2010).
4 of 9 RITIKA AND KISHOR

TABLE 1 Demographic profile of the respondents

Demographic characteristics Measures Frequency Valid percentage


Age 20 years–35 years 466 64.7
35 years–50 years 159 22.1
50 years–65 years 56 7.8
Above 65 years 39 5.4
Gender Male 535 74.3
Female 185 25.7
Marital status Married 395 54.9
Unmarried 325 45.1
Educational qualification Below graduation 12 1.7
Graduation 122 16.9
Postgraduation 472 65.6
Finance professional (CA, CFA, CMA, etc.) 114 15.8
Annual income (in Rs.) Up to 5 lakhs 275 38.2
5 lakhs–10 lakhs 256 35.6
10 lakhs−15 lakhs 88 12.2
15 lakhs–20 lakhs 45 6.3
Above 20 lakhs 56 7.8
Occupation Permanent employee 309 42.9
Business/self employed 150 20.8
Financial expert 38 5.3
Retired 223 31.0

4.1 | Measurement model results. So, the developed constructs could be used to test the
hypothesized structural model.
Cronbach's α {CA(α)} of each construct was used to evaluate the reli- The results of the measurement model indicate that the model is
ability and internal consistency. The responses collected on negatively valid and reliable. So, the developed constructs of this measurement
worded items were coded reversely during the analysis. All constructs model could be used to check the structural model and the related
achieved more than .70 value of Cronbach's α, thus justifying them- hypotheses.
selves to be used for basic research (Table 2; Nunnally &
Bernstein, 1967; Fornell & Larcker, 1981).
Confirmatory factor analysis was conducted on 21 variables. The 4.2 | Structural model
convergent validity of every factor is evaluated by using the values of
critical ratio (CR) and average variance explained (AVE). The CR and AVE Different indices of the measurement model used in the study pro-
value of all the factors lie above 0.5 and 0.7, respectively, and hence, all vided different values as (CMIN/df) value of 2.680 (p < .05), compara-
factors indicate convergent validity. All the items loaded significantly tive fit index (CFI) = 0.969, normed fit index (NFI) = 0.918, goodness
with a factor loadings value of more than 0.6 (Bagozzi & Yi, 1988). These of fit index (GFI) = 0.917, and root mean square error of approxima-
results demonstrate the convergent validity of the measures used. tion (RMSEA) = 0.087. The model successfully explained the changes
The discriminant validity of the factors is ascertained by using the in risk preferences caused by emotional biases of individual investors.
statistical toolkit furnished by Professor Gakingston. The values of Since all the measurement indices showed acceptable values, the
AVE, ASV (average shared variance), and MSV (maximum shared vari- model is a good fit (Bagozzi & Yi, 1988).
ance) of all the five constructs are compared. Since, for all the con- According to the results, risk preferences showed a significant
structs, the value of AVE is higher than ASV as well as MSV, all negative relationship with loss aversion bias (β = −.53, t = −11.594;
constructs have proven to possess discriminant validity (Hair, Black, p < .001) and regret aversion bias (β = −.13, t = −2.769, p < .01). So,
Babin, Anderson, & Tatham, 2006). The measurement model of the Hypotheses H2 and H3 are fully and strongly supported (Table 4). The
study shows valid results for discriminant validity (Table 3). results also indicated that self-control bias (β = .30, t = 6.533,
Various indicators used to estimate the validity and reliability of p < .001) and overconfidence bias (β = .17, t = 3.691, p < .001) have a
various constructs of the measurement model gave satisfactory significant positive relationship with risk preferences of individual
RITIKA AND KISHOR 5 of 9

investors. Thus, the Hypotheses H1 and H4 are supported by the theoretical base by examining the impact that various emotional
results. The results are presented in Table 4 and Figure 1. biases lay on the risk and uncertainty preferences of the individual
investors.
The results of the study are in line with the earlier studies show-
5 | DISCUSSION ing that emotional biases affect the risk preferences of individuals
(Ackert, Deaves, Miele, & Nguyen, 2019; Aspara & Tikkanen, 2008).
Building on the new field of behavioral economics and behavioral The outcome extracted from the current study demonstrates that
finance, the purpose of this article is to provide valuable insights into emotional biases namely “loss aversion bias,” “overconfidence bias,”
the impact of emotional biases in the behavioral decision making of “risk aversion bias,” and “self-control bias” influence the decision mak-
individual investors. Although there are some studies in the behavioral ing of Indian investors. The findings show that loss aversion bias is the
finance literature focusing on the effect of various emotions on the most important predictor of the risk preferences. The result is akin to
risk perception of investors, the current study tries to extend the the landmark theory of behavioral finance named as “prospect theory”
(Duxbury & Summers, 2004; Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; Sitkin &
Pablo, 1992). The findings illustrate that the preferences for risk of
the individual investors are most likely to be influenced by their atti-
TABLE 2 Results of measurement model tude of avoiding losses. Individual investors who want to avoid poten-
Construct Items Factor loadings Cronbach's α tial losses prefer to take less risk even in situations of probable gain.
The strong impulse of the investors to avoid losses leads them to
Overconfidence bias OC1 0.933 .96
dwell more on risk avoidance. Indian investors who can afford to lose
OC2a 0.937
and are willing to take financial risks would have favorable attitudes
OC3 0.953
toward investment and are more likely to invest.
OC4 0.950
Contrary to some of the previous studies stating that over-
Loss aversion bias LA1a 0.884 .873
confidence has no effect on risk preference on an individual basis
LA2 0.924 (Evans, Holcomb, & Chittenden, 1989; Houghton, Simon, Aquino, &
LA3 0.945 Goldberg, 2000), the findings demonstrate that overconfidence bias
LA4 0.928 has a significant positive relationship with risk preferences. This
Regret aversion bias RA1 0.687 .867 shows that due to having supreme faith in one's abilities and the out-
RA2 0.887 look that they can control the outcome of their investment decisions,
RA3 a
0.792 overconfident investors discount the unknown risks present in various
RA4 0.916 securities and thus, end up in taking more risk. The findings are in

RA5 0.893
RA6 0.788 TABLE 4 Results of structural model and hypotheses testing
Self- control bias SC1 0.896 .874
Path β t-Value Hypotheses Results
SC2a 0.908
OC ! RP 0.17 3.691* H1 Supported
SC3a 0.867
LA ! RP −0.53 −11.594* H2 Supported
SC4 0.890
RA ! RP −0.13 −2.769** H3 Supported
Risk preferences RP1 0.944 .882
SC ! RP 0.30 6.533* H4 Supported
RP2 0.949
RP3a 0.942 Abbreviations: LA, loss aversion bias; OC, overconfidence bias; RA, regret
aversion bias; RP, risk preferences; SC, self-control bias.
a *
The items were negative in sense and were reverse coded for the p < .001.
**
analysis. p < .01.

TABLE 3 Results of validity measures

Construct CR AVE MSV ASV Convergent validity Discriminant validity


Overconfidence bias 0.8895 0.6950 0.1552 0.0452 Yes Yes
Loss aversion bias 0.9706 0.8920 0.0188 0.0061 Yes Yes
Regret aversion bias 0.8603 0.5568 0.0441 0.0210 Yes Yes
Self-control bias 0.9557 0.8439 0.1552 0.0574 Yes Yes
Risk preferences 0.9693 0.9133 0.0114 0.0059 Yes Yes

Abbreviations: ASV, average shared variance; AVE, average variance explained; CR, critical ratio; MSV, maximum shared variance.
6 of 9 RITIKA AND KISHOR

developing appropriate policies, the policy makers should try to


understand the behavior of individual investors. By understanding the
limitations of human beings, the policy maker would be able to
develop better policies as compared to the policies framed by keeping
in mind the assumptions of traditional finance. The results of this
study will be of great use to investment consultants, retail investors,
policy makers, regulators, and various other stakeholders associated
with preparing and suggesting investment strategies for their own or
for others. A better understanding of risk preferences and emotional
biases enhances the practitioners' ability to understand the preferences
of various clients and devise for them customized recommendations
F I G U R E 1 Structural model analysis. LA, loss aversion bias; OC, about the investment products and strategies (Birkenmaier, Sherraden,
overconfidence bias; RA, regret aversion; RP, risk preferences; SC, Jacobson Frey, Callahan, & Santiago, 2016). Making assessments about
self-control bias the risk tolerance is not only an individual's own job; the advisors and
policy makers are also required to understand and interpret investors'
behavior. The effect of emotions is important to understand because
conformity with (Gilovich & Douglas, 1986; Harris, 1996; Kilka & the advisors know that it is difficult to deal with emotional clients. Bet-
Weber, 2000; Sitkin & Weingart, 1995; Sjöberg, 2003). ter recognition of the client's preferences will prepare the advisor in
Regret aversion bias showed a negative significance on the risk advance to deal with various irrationalities that can pop up.
preferences. This shows that the investors who might have made
losses in the past, feel afraid to make bold investment decisions. They
favor clinging on to less risky securities to circumvent the regret of 7 | LIM I TAT I ONS A ND FUTU RE SCOPE
making bad investment decisions. Even if they are investing in stocks,
they would prefer to invest in stocks of familiar companies or of the However, there are various potential limitations of this study. Only
companies that are designated as good ones. The findings are in con- the most relevant biases related to risk preferences were taken for
firmation to (Grable, Lytton, & O'Neill, 2004; Harlow & Brown, 1990; the study. The other emotional biases which can have an impact can
Loomes & Sugden, 1982). also be tested in the future studies to gain a better understanding.
Similar to the previous studies (Pompian & Wood, 2006), the Although this study used the investors residing in Delhi as the respon-
results of this study showed self-control bias to be a significantly dent base, the results of this study can also be tested in various geog-
influencing factor for risk preferences. This outcome shows that inves- raphies as a theoretical model.
tors susceptible to this bias cannot control their own behavior and end
up investing in too risky securities. Also, since the investors having self-
OR CID
control bias start saving late for their goals, they tend to take higher risk
Ritika https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5742-1872
in order to make up for the lost time. The findings of this study contrib-
ute to the existing literature stating that risk is affected by feelings and
RE FE RE NCE S
emotions (Eisenberg et al., 1995; Hsee & Weber, 1997; Loewenstein
Ackert, L., Deaves, R., Miele, J., & Nguyen, Q. (2019). Are time preference
et al., 2001) and is basically a trade-off between greed and fear.
and risk preference associated with cognitive intelligence and emo-
tional intelligence? Journal of Behavioral Finance, 21(2), 136–156.
Antony, A. (2020). Behavioral finance and portfolio management: Review
6 | C O N CL U S I O N A ND I M P LI C A TI O N S of theory and literature. Journal of Public Affairs., 20(2), e1996. https://
doi.org/10.1002/pa.1996
Aspara, J., & Tikkanen, H. (2008). Interactions of individuals' company-
While making decisions under uncertainty and risk, emotions play a related attitudes and their buying of companies' stocks and products.
significant role (Mellers, Schwartz, & Ritov, 1999; Slovic, Finucane, Journal of Behavioral Finance, 9(2), 85–94.
Peters, & MacGregor, 2002). Risk preferences of the investors are Bagozzi, R., & Yi, Y. (1988). On the evaluation of structural equation
models. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 16(1), 74–94.
affected by various judgmental biases (Ricciardi, 2008). People need
Baker, H. K., & Nofsinger, J. R. (2002). Psychological biases of investors.
to keep a check on their emotional biases in order to maximize their Financial Services Review, 11(2), 97.
outcomes. Finance professionals and money managers need to be Baker, H. K., & Ricciardi, V. (2014). Investor behavior: The psychology of
aware about these biases since they affect the perception of public financial planning and investing. New Jersey: Wiley (Finance).
Baker, H., Kumar, S., Goyal, N., & Gaur, V. (2019). How financial literacy
and their observed response (Furnival, 2002). The research will prove
and demographic variables relate to behavioral biases. Managerial
to be beneficial for policymakers who aim to motivate people to Finance, 45(1), 124–146.
invest. They get an insight that only cognitive ability will not ensure Barber, B., & Odean, T. (2001). Boys will be boys: Gender, overconfidence,
success, emotional ability is also important along with it. The policy and common stock investment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
116(1), 261–292.
makers need to understand that “one size fits all” does not work. For
RITIKA AND KISHOR 7 of 9

Barnes, J. (1984). Cognitive biases and their impact on strategic planning. Houghton, S., Simon, M., Aquino, K., & Goldberg, C. (2000). No safety in
Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 129–137. numbers: Persistence of biases and their effects on team risk percep-
Bateman, H., Islam, T., Louviere, J., Satchell, S., & Thorp, S. (2011). Retire- tion and team decision making. Group and Organization Management,
ment investor risk tolerance in tranquil and crisis periods: Experimental 25(4), 325–353.
survey evidence. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 12(4), 201–218. Hsee, C., & Weber, E. (1997). A fundamental prediction error: Self–others
Birkenmaier, J., Sherraden, M., Jacobson Frey, J., Callahan, C., & discrepancies in risk preference. Journal of Experimental Psychology:
Santiago, A. (2016). Financial capability and asset building: Building General, 126(1), 45–53.
evidence for community practice. Journal of Community Practice, 24(4), Jain, J., Walia, N., & Gupta, S. (2019). Evaluation of behavioral biases
357–367. affecting investment decision making of individual equity investors by
Campos-Vazquez, R. M., & Cuilty, E. (2014). The role of emotions on risk fuzzy analytic hierarchy process. Review of Behavioral Finance., 12,
aversion: A prospect theory experiment. Journal of Behavioral and 297–314. https://doi.org/10.1108/RBF-03-2019-0044
Experimental Economics, 50, 1–9. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of deci-
Chang, C. T. (2007). Interactive effects of message framing, product per- sion under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.
ceived risk, and mood—The case of travel healthcare product advertis- Kilka, M., & Weber, M. (2000). Home bias in international stock return
ing. Journal of Advertising Research, 47(1), 51–65. expectations. Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets, 1(3–4),
Charupat, N., Deaves, R., Derouin, T., Klotzle, M., & Miu, P. (2013). Emo- 176–192.
tional balance and probability weighting. Theory and Decision, 75(1), Kliger, D., & Levy, O. (2008). Projection bias by investors: A market
17–41. approach. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 66(3–4),
Connolly, T., & Zeelenberg, M. (2002). Regret in decision making. Current 657–668.
Directions in Psychological Science, 11(6), 212–216. Kugler, T., Connolly, T., & Ordóñez, L. D. (2012). Emotion, decision, and
Cooley, P. (1977). A multidimensional analysis of institutional investor per- risk: Betting on gambles versus betting on people. Journal of Behavioral
ception of risk. The Journal of Finance, 32(1), 67–78. Decision Making, 25(2), 123–134.
Cooper, A., Woo, C., & Dunkelberg, W. (1988). Entrepreneurs' perceived Kumar, S., & Goyal, N. (2015). Behavioural biases in investment decision
chances for success. Journal of Business Venturing, 3(2), 97–108. making—A systematic literature review. Qualitative Research in Finan-
Damasio, A. R. (1994). Descartes' error and the future of human life. Scien- cial Markets, 7(1), 88–108.
tific American, 271(4), 144–144. LeDoux, J. (1996). Emotional networks and motor control: A fearful view.
Dhar, R., & Wertenbroch, K. (2000). Consumer choice between hedonic In G. Holstege, R. Bandler, & C. B. Saper (Eds.), Progress in brain
and utilitarian goods. Journal of Marketing Research, 37(1), 60–71. research (Vol. 107, pp. 437–446). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Duxbury, D., & Summers, B. (2004). Financial risk perception: Are individ- Loewenstein, G., Weber, E., Hsee, C., & Welch, N. (2001). Risk as feelings.
uals variance averse or loss averse? Economics Letters, 84(1), 21–28. Psychological Bulletin, 127(2), 267–286.
Edwards, K. D. (1995). Prospect theory: A literature review. International Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1982). Regret theory: An alternative theory of
Review of Financial Analysis, 5(1), 19–38. rational choice under uncertainty. The Economic Journal, 92(368), 805.
Eisenberg, N., Fabes, R. A., Murphy, B., Maszk, P., Smith, M., & Karbon, M. Pompian, M. M., & Wood, A. S. (2006). Behavioral finance and wealth man-
(1995). The role of emotionality and regulation in children's social func- agement: How to build optimal portfolios for private clients. New Jersey:
tioning: A longitudinal study. Child Development, 66(5), 1360–1384. Wiley (Finance).
Evans, D., Holcomb, J., & Chittenden, W. (1989). The relationship between Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. S. (2007). Baby boomer retirement security: The
risk-return preference and knowledge in experimental financial mar- roles of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. Journal of Mon-
kets. Journal of Behavioral Economics, 18(1), 19–40. etary Economics, 54(1), 205–224.
Fehr-Duda, H., Epper, T., Bruhin, A., & Schubert, R. (2011). Risk and ratio- Mellers, B., Schwartz, A., & Ritov, I. (1999). Emotion-based choice. Journal
nality: The effects of mood and decision rules on probability of Experimental Psychology: General, 128(3), 332–345.
weighting. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 78(1–2), Nofsinger, J. R. (2017). The psychology of investing (6th ed.). New York:
14–24. Routledge.
Fogel, S. O. C., & Berry, T. (2006). The disposition effect and individual Nunnally, J. C., & Bernstein, I. H. (1967). Psychometric theory: McGraw-Hill
investor decisions: The roles of regret and counterfactual alternatives. series in psychology. New York: McGraw-Hill.
The Journal of Behavioral Finance, 7(2), 107–116. Odean, T. (1998). Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? The Jour-
Fornell, C., & Larcker, D. (1981). Structural equation models with nal of Finance, 53(5), 1775–1798.
unobservable variables and measurement error: Algebra and statistics. Olsen, R. (1997). Investment risk: The experts' perspective. Financial Ana-
Journal of Marketing Research, 18(3), 382–388. lysts Journal, 53(2), 62–66.
Furnival, A. (2002). Isolating risk for better public affairs outcomes. Journal Olsen, R. (2000). The instinctive mind on wall street: Evolution and invest-
of Public Affairs, 2(2), 16–18. ment decision-making. The Journal of Investing, 9(4), 47–54.
Gilovich, T., & Douglas, C. (1986). Biased evaluations of randomly deter- Olsen, R. A., & Cox, C. M. (2001). The influence of gender on the percep-
mined gambling outcomes. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, tion and response to investment risk: The case of professional inves-
22(3), 228–241. tors. The Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets, 2(1), 29–36.
Grable, J., Lytton, R., & O'Neill, B. (2004). Projection bias and financial risk Prosad, J., Kapoor, S., & Sengupta, J. (2015). Behavioral biases of Indian
tolerance. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 5(3), 142–147. investors: A survey of Delhi-NCR region. Qualitative Research in Finan-
Grable, J., & Roszkowski, M. (2008). The influence of mood on the willing- cial Markets, 7(3), 230–263.
ness to take financial risks. Journal of Risk Research, 11(7), 905–923. Ricciardi, V. (2005). A research starting point for the new scholar: A unique
Hair, J. F., Black, W. C., Babin, B. J., Anderson, R. E., & Tatham, R. L. perspective of behavioral finance. ICFAI Journal of Behavioral Finance,
(2006). Multivariate data analysis (Vol. 6). New Jersey: Prentice Hall. 3(3), 6–23.
Harlow, W., & Brown, K. (1990). Understanding and assessing financial risk Ricciardi, V. (2008). The psychology of risk: The behavioral finance per-
tolerance: A biological perspective. Financial Analysts Journal, 46(6), spective. In F. J. Fabozzi (Ed.), Handbook of finance: Investment manage-
50–62. ment and financial management (Vol. 2, pp. 85–111). New Jersey: John
Harris, P. (1996). Sufficient grounds for optimism?: The relationship Wiley & Sons.
between perceived controllability and optimistic bias. Journal of Social Ricciardi, V., & Simon, H. K. (2000). What is behavioral finance? Business,
and Clinical Psychology, 15(1), 9–52. Education and Technology Journal, 2(2), 1–9.
8 of 9 RITIKA AND KISHOR

Roszkowski, M. J., & Davey, G. (2010). Risk perception and risk toler- White, J. L., Moffitt, T. E., Caspi, A., Bartusch, D. J., Needles, D. J., &
ance changes attributable to the 2008 economic crisis: A subtle but Stouthamer-Loeber, M. (1994). Measuring impulsivity and examining
critical difference. Journal of Financial Service Professionals, 64(4), its relationship to delinquency. Journal of Abnormal Psychology, 103(2),
42–53. 192–205.
Rottenstreich, Y., & Hsee, C. K. (2001). Money, kisses, and electric shocks: Zajonc, R. B. (1980). Feeling and thinking: Preferences need no inferences.
On the affective psychology of risk. Psychological Science, 12(3), American Psychologist, 35(2), 151–175.
185–190.
Russo, J. E., & Schoemaker, P. J. (1992). Managing overconfidence. Sloan
Management Review, 33(2), 7–17. AUTHOR BIOGRAPHIES
Samuels, J., Bienvenu, O. J., Cullen, B., Costa, P. T., Jr., Eaton, W. W., &
Nestadt, G. (2004). Personality dimensions and criminal arrest. Com-
prehensive Psychiatry, 45(4), 275–280. Ritika is a research scholar at School of Management Studies
Schwenk, C. (1984). Cognitive simplification processes in strategic
(SOMS), Indira Gandhi National Open University, New Delhi,
decision-making. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 111–128.
Sciortino, J., Huston, J., & Spencer, R. (1987). Perceived risk and the pre- India. She is currently a member of Indian Commerce Association.
cautionary demand for money. Journal of Economic Psychology, 8(3), She holds the degree of B.Com. (Hons.) and M.Com. from the Uni-
339–346. versity of Delhi. She has qualified UGC NET-JRF in both disci-
Shaver, K., & Scott, L. (1992). Person, process, choice: The psychology of
plines, Commerce and Management. She has presented papers at
new venture creation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 16(2),
23–46. national and international conferences at institutions of national
Sitkin, S. B., & Pablo, A. L. (1992). Reconceptualizing the determinants of repute. Her research areas include behavioral biases, behavioral
risk behavior. Academy of Management Review, 17(1), 9–38. finance and risk preferences.
Sitkin, S., & Weingart, L. (1995). Determinants of risky decision-making
behavior: A test of the mediating role of risk perceptions and propen- Prof. Nawal Kishor is M. Com, PGDIM and Ph.D. He has been
sity. Academy of Management Journal, 38(6), 1573–1592. working at SOMS, IGNOU for the last 30 years. He has been
Sjöberg, L. (2003). Risk perception is not what it seems: The psychometric
engaged in teaching, training, research and other academic activi-
paradigm revisited. In K. Andersson (Ed.), VALDOR conference 2003
(pp. 14–29). Stockholm: Valdor. ties. He has published various research papers in reputed interna-
Slovic, P., Finucane, M., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2002). Rational tional and national journals and has presented many research
actors or rational fools: Implications of the affect heuristic for papers in international and national conferences. He has been
behavioral economics. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 31(4),
actively involved as Key note speaker, technical session chairper-
329–342.
Steil, B. (1993). Corporate foreign exchange risk management: A study in son, guest of honour, and resource person in international and
decision making under uncertainty. Journal of Behavioral Decision Mak- national conferences. He had been the resource person for aca-
ing, 6(1), 1–31. demic staff colleges of various universities as well as for the fac-
Strong, R. A. (2007). Practical investment management. Mason:
ulty development programmes. He has been the managing editor
Thomson/South-Western.
Summers, B., & Duxbury, D. (2012). Decision-dependent emotions and of The Indian Journal of Commerce and editor of Indian Journal of
behavioral anomalies. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Pro- Open Learning. His areas of interest are: International Business
cesses, 118(2), 226–238. Management, International Marketing, Foreign Trade, Export-
Thaler, R., & Johnson, E. (1990). Gambling with the house money and try-
Import Procedures, Retail Management, Organisational Behaviour,
ing to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Man-
General Management, Commerce and Distance Education.
agement Science, 36(6), 643–660.
Weber, E., & Hsee, C. (1998). Cross-cultural differences in risk perception,
but cross-cultural similarities in attitudes towards perceived risk. Man-
agement Science, 44(9), 1205–1217.
Weber, E., Blais, A., & Betz, N. (2002). A domain-specific risk-attitude How to cite this article: R, Kishor N. Risk preferences for
scale: Measuring risk perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behav- financial decisions: Do emotional biases matter? J Public
ioral Decision Making, 15(4), 263–290.
Affairs. 2020;e2360. https://doi.org/10.1002/pa.2360
Westland, J. C. (2010). Lower bounds on sample size in structural equation
modeling. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 9(6), 476–487.
RITIKA AND KISHOR 9 of 9

APPENDIX: INSTRU MENT FOR DATA COLLECTION

Construct Measurement variables Sources


Overconfidence bias O1: I am confident of my ability to make investment decisions better than others Prosad et al. (2015); Baker et al. (2019)
O2: I cannot predict future prices of my investments better than othersa
O3: I always feel optimistic about the future returns of my investments
O4: I have complete knowledge of various types of investments
Loss aversion bias LA1: I do not avoid an investment when I fear the lossa Baker et al. (2019); Jain et al. (2019)
LA2: Loss of Rs. 1,000 is more painful than happiness of Rs. 1,000 profit
LA3: I never sell an investment at a loss with an expectation that it will
eventually improve
LA4: I avoid taking decisions with the fear of incurring losses
Regret aversion bias RA1: I regret when I miss an opportunity of getting good returns Baker et al. (2019); Prosad et al. (2015)
RA2: I avoid investing in profitable assets if I had incurred losses in similar
investments in the past
RA3: Holding loss-making investments for longer time is more painful than
disposing profitable investments early
RA4: I changed my investment decisions in light of the wrong decisions I had
made earlier
RA5: I became risk seeking because I have made profits in the past
RA6: I became risk averse because I have incurred losses in the past
Self-control bias SC1: I lack the self-discipline required to fulfill my long-term saving objectives Pompian and Wood (2006)
SC2: I am able to achieve my saving and investment goalsa
SC3: I easily stick to difficult saving objectives once I decidea
SC4: It is very difficult for me to keep up my saving goals
Risk preferences RP1: Investing 10% of your annual income in blue chip stocks Weber et al. (2002)
RP2: Investing 10% of your annual income in very speculative stocks
RP3: Investing 10% of your annual income in government bonds
a
The items were negative in sense and were reverse coded for the analysis.

You might also like