You are on page 1of 21

International Journal of Management Reviews, Vol.

14, 18–38 (2012)


DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-2370.2011.00302.x

Diversification and Performance in


Developed and Emerging Market
Contexts: A Review of the Literature* ijmr_302 18..38

Saptarshi Purkayastha, Tatiana S. Manolova1 and Linda F. Edelman1


Strategic Management, Indian Institute of Management, Kozhikode, IIMK Campus P.O. Kozhikode-673570, Kerala,
India, and 1Business Policy and Strategy, Bentley University, 175 Forest St., Waltham, MA 02452, USA
Corresponding author email: ledelman@bentley.edu

The link between diversification and performance has become an important topic for
research in diverse fields such as strategic management, industrial organization and
financial management. However, a synthesis of the research done in developed
and emerging markets is missing. This paper attempts such a synthesis by comparing
and contrasting the past cumulative empirical research evidence on the relationship
between diversification and firm performance in the context of developed economies to
the more recent work in the emerging economies. The empirical literature has been
divided into three broad perspectives, and the paper highlights the considerable diver-
sity in its findings in developed and emerging markets across each of these perspectives.
Based on this study, it is proposed that related diversification is preferable in developed
economies and should be based on specific resources, whereas unrelated diversification
is appropriate in emerging economies and should be based on generic resources.
Although agency problems exist in both contexts, it is argued that the type of problem
differs in developed and emerging markets. The paper concludes by identifying three
directions for future research. First, the relationship between diversification and per-
formance should be examined across each industry separately and not in aggregate.
Secondly, future research needs to examine the organizational mechanisms required to
make diversification successful. Finally, the relationship needs to be examined under
unstable and dynamic situations such as the current global economic downturn.

Introduction strategies in the developed world during the period


1950–1980 has been replaced by a trend of refocusing
Diversification is a popular growth option for firms in (Wall Street Journal 1985), the competitive landscape
both developed (Datta et al. 1991) and emerging in emerging economies continues to be dominated by
countries (Kakani 2000). Besides the advantages of large conglomerates such as the Tata Group in India or
increased revenues and opportunities to spread risks, the Group Carso in Mexico. These diversified and
it has the potential to create shareholder value through often family-controlled conglomerates account for up
the exploitation of economies of scope and the cre- to 80–85% of the total sales and asset base of the
ation of efficient internal capital and labour markets. private sector in some emerging economies. The
Although the diversification trend which dominated effect of diversification on corporate performance in
the context of emerging markets is therefore an impor-
tant managerial and public policy concern.
*A free Teaching and Learning Guide to accompany this
article is available at: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/ While diversification continues to be a growth
journal/10.1111/(ISSN)1468-2370/homepage/teaching___ strategy for firms, the relationship between diversifi-
learning_guides.htm cation and firm performance is not clear, because the

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA
02148, USA
Diversification and Performance 19

findings of past empirical studies do not point to an et al. (2009).1 In selecting the papers, we focused on
easy generalization (Palich et al. 2000). For example, two questions. First, how has diversification and firm
in developed economies, Rhodes (1973) and Chatter- performance research evolved over time? Second,
jee (1986) have advocated a positive relationship; who has published most in this literature, and what is
Bettis and Hall (1982) and Perry (1998) have found a their contribution to the evolution of this field? To
negative or no relationship, while Rumelt (1974) and address the first question, we followed the develop-
Markides and Williamson (1996) have found a curvi- ment of the diversification literature and then catego-
linear relationship between diversification and firm rized it into three broad perspectives, the external
performance. The situation is similar in emerging perspective (industrial organizational (I/O) and insti-
economies. Although there is limited research in this tutional theories), the internal perspective (the RBV),
area (Hoskisson et al. 2000; Kakani 2000), the few and the finance perspective for both developed and
studies that have been done provide conflicting emerging economies. Unlike Datta et al. (1991) and
results. For example, Chang and Hong (2000) found Ramanujam and Varadarajan (1989), who developed a
that diversification has a positive influence on firm framework to organize their literature review, we
performance; Kakani (2000) predicts an inverse anchor the review in the frameworks provided by
relationship; Khanna and Palepu (2000a,b) predict a established theoretical perspectives. The disciplines
curvilinear relationship; while Saple (2000) and Chu of I/O and finance have extensively researched the
(2004) predict no relationship between diversification diversification–performance relationship (Datta et al.
and firm performance. 1991), while the resource-based perspective is an
The sheer number and variety of diversification emerging theory in this line of work (Perry 1998). The
studies in developed economies have made it difficult institutional framework is considered the most appli-
to synthesize the results. As Hunter and Schmidt cable paradigm for explaining diversification in the
(1990, p. 34) pointed out, ‘the need for today is not context of emerging economies (Shenkar and von
additional empirical data but some means of making Glinow 1994), but research in the other two areas has
sense of the vast amount of data we have accumu- been comparatively limited. In sum, we were as com-
lated’. Without a clear synthesis of the existing prehensive as possible in selecting the theoretical
studies, the effect of diversification on firm perform- anchors for the literature review.
ance cannot be answered. Thus the primary motiva- After categorizing the diversification–
tion of this study is to compare and contrast the past performance literature in three perspectives, we iden-
empirical research on the relationship between diver- tified the prolific authors in this field and followed
sification and firm performance in the context of the evolution of their scholarship over time. We
developed economies to the more recent work in the selected these authors by tracking their publications
emerging economies. In doing so, we organize the in the top management journals (e.g. Academy of
review into three broad perspectives: the external Management Review, Academy of Management
perspective (industrial organization (I/O) and institu- Journal, Journal of Finance, Management Science,
tional theories), the internal perspective (resource- Journal of Management and Strategic Management
based view (RBV)) and the finance perspective, and Journal). Specifically, we used the Social Science
discuss them in the context of developed and emer- Citation Index Journal Impact Factor to determine
ging markets, culminating the discussion by formu- whether an article was in a journal which we deemed
lating conclusions from prior research. Next, we high enough quality to include. In the developed
review firm performance measurement issues in economies literature review, all journals have a five-
developed and emerging market context. The paper year rolling impact factor of over 1. As a secondary
concludes by identifying several directions for future check or for an article that we deemed important but
research. was not published in the better cited journals, we
looked to Goggle Scholar to see the number of article

Methodology
1
Given the large volume of research on diversification, We choose Rumelt’s (1974) work as our boundary because
he developed categorical measures of diversification which
the study is constrained by strict temporal boundaries. were widely used by other researchers (i.e. Bettis 1981; Chu
The literature review starts with the seminal work of 2004; Hoskisson 1987; Lubatkin and Chatterjee 1994;
Rumelt (1974) and ends with the recent work of Lim Palepu 1985).

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
20 S. Purkayastha et al.

citations. If an article had over 50 citations, we deter- sified firms is associated with the structure of
mined that it was important and hence included it in the industry (Demsetz 1974; Montgomery 1985;
the review. Phillips 1976). This finding led researchers to study
In the case of emerging economies, because of the effect of industry structure on diversification.
the paucity of empirical research, we captured most Bettis (1981) found that diversification leads to the
of the literature. The search process made extensive creation of entry barriers, which in turn leads to
use of the ABI-Inform and EBSCO databases, using higher industry profitability. Bettis and Hall (1982)
keywords such as ‘diversification’, ‘business group’, found that the differences between the profitability
‘firm performance’ AND ‘emerging economy/ies’. of Rumelt’s categories disappeared after correcting
Finally, we examined each study thoroughly to for the industry bias in the sample. Hill (1983) also
determine its fit with the scope of the review. In found no difference in the average profitability
total, we reviewed 124 articles, 87 in the context of among categories of diversification. Other studies
developed markets and 37 in the context of emer- that did not find any significant differences between
ging markets. diversification and firm performance after control-
ling for industry effects include McDougall and
Round (1984), Montgomery (1985), Johnson and
The external view: industrial Thomas (1987), Grant and Jammine (1988), Hill
organization (developed economies) and Snell (1988), Chang and Thomas (1989) and
Chatterjee and Wernerfelt (1991).
and the institutional perspectives Given the lack of conclusiveness in this line of
(emerging economies) inquiry, researchers examined alternative perform-
ance measures and contingency factors. Michel and
Most of the earlier studies on diversification in devel- Shaked (1984) and, subsequently, Dubofsky
oped economies in the I/O literature (pre-Rumelt and Varadarajan (1987) examined a market-based
1974 studies) have been concerned with the extent or measure of performance: the increase in sharehold-
motives of diversification (e.g. Gort 1962; Miller ers’ value. They found that unrelated diversification
1969; Weston and Mansinghka 1971), and are based led to increased performance over related diversifi-
on the structure–conduct–performance framework. cation. Wernerfelt and Montgomery (1986) found
This section provides a critical analysis of the litera- that industry profitability and industry growth, the
ture in the field of diversification which uses an I/O two dimensions of industry attractiveness, have dif-
framework, starting with the seminal work of Rumelt ferent implications for related (which they termed as
(1974). efficient) and unrelated (which they termed as inef-
ficient) firms. They suggested that related diversified
firms would be better off in highly profitable indus-
Rumelt and post-Rumelt works: diversification in
tries, while unrelated firms would be better off in
developed markets
high growth industries.
Rumelt’s (1974) work is a seminal study in this A group of studies by Hoskisson and co-authors
field, as he developed a new categorical measure of examined the relationship between diversification
diversification. One of his major findings was that and firm structure. Thus, Hoskisson (1987) and Hill
firms with related diversified portfolios outperform et al. (1992) found that related diversifiers need to
other diversification types, owing to gains from adopt co-operative organizational arrangements,
economies of scope. Researchers following while unrelated diversifiers required competitive
Rumelt’s 1974 study have found similar relation- arrangements. Hill and Hoskisson (1987) argued
ships between diversification and firm performance that vertically integrated firms achieve vertical
(Christensen and Montgomery 1981; Fryxell and economies by reducing transaction costs, related
Barton 1990; Hill and Snell 1989; Hitt and Ireland diversified firms achieve synergistic economies by
1986; Hoskisson 1987; Lecraw 1984; Palepu 1985; exploiting synergy, and unrelated firms achieve
Palich et al. 2000; Varadarajan and Ramanujam financial economies by risk reduction, portfolio
1987). management and internal capital markets. Teece
Although there is strong support for Rumelt’s et al. (1994) studied how environments affect firm
(1974) perspective on related diversification, other structure. They suggested that, with low path
studies have shown that the performance of diver- dependence, slow learning and weak selection,

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 21

conglomerates persist, but in environments with Market power and diversification


rapid learning and colliding technological trajecto-
A different approach to examining the effect of diver-
ries, networked firms may arise. Thus, from the per-
sification on firm performance is to analyse the
spective of different measures of firm performance
market power that a conglomerate has with respect to
and firm structure, no overall conclusions could be
specialized firms. Market power is the ability of a
derived.
market participant to influence price, quality and the
nature of the product in the marketplace (Markham
Synergy and diversification 1973). The fundamental prerequisite for market
power is the existence of entry barriers (Baumol
Researchers also examined the effect of synergies
et al. 1982). Entry barriers can be erected by the
and economies of scope on diversification. Two
diversified firm by cross-subsidization, mutual for-
businesses are said to have synergy if the union
bearance and reciprocal buying (Montgomery 1994).
of the two allows for opportunities that are not
Some researchers have found that diversification
available to either of them separately (Perry 1998).
based solely on market power has a positive relation-
Synergies may arise from the use of common infra-
ship with firm performance (Edwards 1955; Hill
structures, including resources that are either tan-
1985). They argue that, as long as the firm is larger
gible or intangible, such as marketing and R&D
than its competitors, it will have the advantage of
operations, brand names, production and distribu-
market power, irrespective of the type of diversifica-
tion systems (Teece 1982). Empirical studies on
tion strategy it pursues. However, other studies dis-
synergy and their relation to diversification do not
agree, stating that a firm’s expansion into businesses
abound in the literature because of measurement
that are related to its original products results in
problems. Carter (1977) examined the performance
transfer of skills in technology, marketing or special-
difference between diversified and specialized firms
ized management which can help in developing
and found that diversified firms outperform their
expertise and thereby market power in relation to its
specialized counterparts. He rationalized that the
competitors (Singh and Montgomery 1987). Related
source of superior performance can be related to the
diversifiers are more likely to create barriers to entry
synergy that arises because of diversification.
based on scope economies, patents, experience
However, there is a limit to diversification, because
advantages or brand reputation, thus giving more
over-extended use of shared resources may result in
market power relative to unrelated firms (Singh and
congestion and loss of control. Deneffe (1993)
Montgomery 1987). Although the increase in market
found that diversified firms delayed entry into new
power of unrelated diversifiers can arise from
markets compared with undiversified firms, because
increases in the absolute size and breadth of the firm,
the former tried to exploit cost externalities from
which allow opportunities for cross-subsidization,
experience transfer (because of synergy) from their
predatory pricing and reciprocity in buying and
core product to new markets.
selling (Markham 1973), these benefits should also
Economies of scope are a specific expression of
be available to related diversified firms and, thus,
synergy, usually thought of primarily in the context
related diversifiers should have more market power
of cost. They are said to exist when the cost of joint
than unrelated diversifiers (Singh and Montgomery
production of two goods by a multi-product (diver-
1987). However, the above observation must be
sified) firm is less than the combined cost of produc-
qualified by the fact that a diversified firm with an
tion of the two goods by two single-product firms.
insignificant position in a number of markets will
However, Teece (1980) says that this is not a suffi-
not, in sum, have market power (Gribbin 1976).
cient condition for exploitation of economies of
Figure 12 presents a model of the I/O stream of
scope. The proposition that he advances is that a cost
function displaying economies of scope has no direct
implication on the diversification of a firm if the cost 2
The conduct variable is shown by a dashed line because of
can be efficiently traded in the open market. Never- the initial I/O postulate that acceptable prediction levels of
theless, if economies of scope are based upon the performance can be made by using the structural variables.
common and recurrent use of propriety know-how or However, the seminal work of Rumelt (1974) and his clas-
sification of diversified firms into related and unrelated cat-
of a specialized and indivisible physical asset, the egories made the firm and hence conduct variables the focal
multi-product enterprise is an efficient way of orga- point. One may thus tend to conclude that the diversification
nizing economic activity. literature emerged out of I/O literature and entered the strat-

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
22 S. Purkayastha et al.

economies, intermediate institutions – such as finan-


Diversification
cial and market intermediaries – are either inefficient
or absent, and therefore diversified firms can gain
scope and scale advantages from internalizing those
Structure Conduct Performance intermediate functions typically provided by institu-
tions and markets in advanced economies (Chakra-
barti et al. 2007).
Figure 1. The industrial organization stream Khanna and Palepu (1997 1999, 2000a,b) argue
that greater diversification may enhance firm
performance in emerging economies because of
insufficient market and institutional development.
research on diversification and performance in the By diversifying, firms can create internal markets
context of developed economies. that may be more effective than inefficient external
markets. As intermediaries are often absent or inef-
The external view on diversification in emerging ficient in developing economies, internalization
economies: the role of institutions may be viable and profitable. Diversified firms do
not gain equally in developed institutional environ-
Studies exploring the effect of industry structure on a ments, since it is more difficult for internal opera-
diversified firm’s performance in developed econ- tions to match relatively efficient markets. Similar
omies base their hypotheses on one critical assump- arguments apply to the cost of diversification. Effi-
tion: markets are competitive and strive towards effi- cient markets in developed economies detect and
ciency. However, this assumption cannot be made in penalize diversification costs more than the less
the context of an emerging economy because of efficient markets of institutionally developing
market impediments, such as the lack of inter- economies. This may be because the internal inter-
mediary institutions (Khanna and Palepu 1997), the mediate institutions of diversified firms in devel-
lack of well-defined property rights that convey oped economies cannot match the efficiency levels
exclusivity, transferability and quality of title (Devlin of open market institutions. Diversified firms thus
et al. 1988), and the lack of a strong legal framework, have higher costs, which results in lowering their
which results in opportunism, bribery and corruption performance (Leaven and Levine 2007; Villalonga
(Nelson et al. 1998). Given these constraints, in the 2004). In institutionally developing economies,
context of emerging markets, the I/O perspective has however, the absence or inefficiency of external
been complemented by what we call the ‘institutional intermediate institutions results in firms developing
perspective’. these institutions internally, which helps firms to
The institutional perspective emphasizes the influ- lower their costs (Lins and Servaes 2002). Thus,
ence of systems surrounding organizations that internalization in less developed institutional envir-
shape social and organizational behaviour (Scott onments would bring about greater net marginal
1995). Peng and Health (1996) and Child and Lu benefits.
(1996) argued that the internal growth of firms in Backman (1999) proposes that, for many Asian
emerging economies is limited by institutional con- firms, diversification is motivated by aspects which
straints and, as a result, network-based (diversified) market efficiency factors do not adequately capture,
growth is expected to be more viable. Several other such as exploitation of privileged access to informa-
studies concur (Guillen 2000; Khanna and Palepu tion, licences and markets. However, such advan-
2000a,b; Kock and Guillen 2001; Palepu and Khanna tages decrease with economic development,
1998). The underlying argument is that, in emerging suggesting that diversification is less beneficial in
more developed institutional environments (Kock
egic management literature (Bettis 1981; Bettis and Hall and Guillen 2001).
1982). However, a distinction between these two literature While the institutional perspective makes intuitive
streams has not been made in this paper because the distinc- sense, studies have been done that provide contradic-
tion is not a very major one and the overall model is the tory results. Kakani (2000) found an inverse relation-
same. Moreover, post-Rumelt; researchers used the I/O
literature to great degree to explain the diversification– ship between diversification and firm performance
performance relationship (Christensen and Montgomery measures. The results were robust in the sense that
1981; Montgomery 1985; Palepu 1985). the inverse relationship was observed throughout the

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 23

Economic Orientation
Poor labour markets
Poor capital markets
Poor government
regulations
Poor product market
Decision to Performance
diversify
Sociological orientation
Political constrains
Cultural constrains

Figure 2. The institutional perspective

study period (1987–1999) and using multiple meas- emerge to solve market problems, but emerge
ures of diversification (i.e. categorical and continu- because of special skills and abilities of entrepre-
ous) and performance (i.e. accounting and market neurs (Granovetter 1994). A second issue is how to
based). Saple (2000) measured the diversification of validate the implicit assumption that an ideal state
Indian firms as a simple count of the number of exists in which individual firms do not need to
industries in which the firms’ divisions are present. diversify because the missing institutions would
no effect She found that diversification does not have any eventually emerge in the open market. Having risen
effect on the firm’s performance; however, synergy from the open market processes, these institutions
had an inverted-U-shaped relationship with firm would be as efficient. Thus, once economies
performance. Considering synergy3 a proxy for reached this ideal state, the need for diversified
diversification in the econometric model, this study’s firms would disappear, and they would disintegrate.
conclusion did not differ from the studies done in However, diversified firms still exist in advanced
advanced countries. Figure 2 presents a model of the economies, assuming that their economies are
institutional view on diversification in emerging market driven and efficient. Thus, the rationale that
markets. diversified firms arise because of market failures is
Khanna and Rivkin address this variation in the problematic.
performance of diversified firms by suggesting that
the inability to profit from diversification indicates Discussion
‘poorly developed selection environment, where
A review of more than four decades of re-
weak organizational forms4 are not weeded out’
search within the I/O literature demonstrates that
(Khanna and Rivkin 2001, p. 47). There are two
no clear direction seems to be emerging in the
issues in the logic of such an argument. The first is
diversification–firm performance debate in devel-
whether one can empirically show how an organi-
oped economies. The dominant view in this stream
zational form such as the diversified firm arises as a
finds a positive relationship between related diver-
response to market failure (Gould and Lewontin
sification and firm performance (Hitt and Ireland
1979). It can be argued that diversified firms do not
1986; Palepu 1985; Rumelt 1974; Varadarajan and
Ramanujam 1987). Related diversifiers enjoy the
3
The computation of synergy by Saple (2000) is similar to benefits of synergy by sharing and transferring
that computed by Berger and Ofek (1995) with the one resources and skill sets across different businesses.
exception: the latter used median values, while the former
used mean values. Synergistic benefits of a diversified firm In the case of unrelated diversifiers, superior market
are the difference between the actual values of an accounting power and profitability can arise from increases in
term (profits or asset utilization) and the benchmark value. the size and breadth of the firm, allowing opportu-
These benchmark measures are the total profits or asset nities for financial benefits (Hill and Hoskisson
utilization that a diversified firm would have faced had it 1987). Since financial benefits are also available to
operated in each of the industries separately as undiversified
firm with a size proportional to the sales output in that related diversified firms, but the potential benefits
industry to the total sales of the firm. of related diversification are unavailable to unre-
4
Weak organizational forms refer to undiversified firms. lated diversifiers, most of the studies in this stream

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
24 S. Purkayastha et al.

of thought suggest that related diversified firms diversification strategy based on inputs that are char-
should perform better than unrelated firms (Perry acterized as valuable, durable, inimitable and non-
1998). substitutable can provide the basis for sustainable
The number of theoretical and empirical studies competitive advantage (Markides and Williamson
using an institutional framework in emerging 1996). Such inputs can only be firm specific and can
economies is limited even though some theorists be exploited if firms diversify in related industries
have argued that this perspective is perhaps the (Collis and Montgomery 1995; Perry 1998). More-
most applicable paradigm for explaining diversifi- over, firms should continuously upgrade their stock
cation in such a context (Shenkar and von Glinow of resources and capabilities5 to meet market-specific
1994). In such economies, the institutions required demands and use them in existing or new markets
for business are either absent or inefficient, so firms (Collis and Montgomery 1995; Grant 1991). The
that have internalized these institutions can diver- reason for upgrading resources and capabilities
sify across industries and be profitable. Diversified rather than simply using existing stock is that the
firms can benefit from access to internal institutions forces that affect market and competition are numer-
such as internal capital and labour markets to miti- ous and complex, so an existing resource may fail to
gate external market failures. Internalization of provide lasting competitive advantage.
these institutions entails fixed costs, so diversifica- According to the RBV logic, resources and capa-
tion will only be beneficial when the fixed costs bilities also need to be leveraged beyond the products
required to set up these institutions can be distrib- that they were originally developed for; thus provid-
uted across divisions that are spread across a ing an opportunity for diversification (Prahalad and
number of industries. Thus, highly diversified firms Hamel 1990). Unfortunately, companies that can
as opposed to less diversified firms will have super- sustain competitive advantage by upgrading or lever-
ior firm performance. Rumelt (1974) rationalizes aging their resources and capabilities are the excep-
that firms initiate diversification by moving into tion rather than the rule. Collis and Montgomery
related industries because of the ease of sharing of (1995) identify three errors that companies commit
resources, and then gradually move towards unre- when trying to diversify by leveraging resources.
lated diversification. Hence, highly diversified firms First, managers overestimate the transferability of
are more likely to be unrelated diversifiers. Thus, specific assets and capabilities to a different product
we conclude: environment. As resources that provide sustainable
competitive advantage are inimitable, the company
(a) In developed economies, related diversification
may find it difficult to replicate them in new markets.
is likely to lead to superior performance.
For example, although Levi Strauss was able to move
(b) In emerging economies, unrelated diversifica-
successfully into related jeans products, broader
tion is likely to result in superior performance.
moves into high fashion clothing have been less
successful. It appears that brand recognition is not
extensible across too broad a product line. Second,
The internal perspective: the RBV managers overestimate their own capability to
compete in highly profitable industries. Such indus-
tries are profitable because entry (resource) barriers
The RBV in developed economies
limit competition, since accumulating the necessary
The RBV offers new insights into the performance of resources is difficult. Finally, managers assume that
diversified firms. This theory proposes that there are generic resources would be a source of competitive
no long-term benefits to diversification based on advantage in a new market, regardless of the dynam-
generic resources, as they are in abundant supply and ics of that market. As economies of scope exist, man-
are imitable (Montgomery and Wernerfelt 1988;
Wernerfelt and Montgomery 1988). Besides, 5
Resources encompass all input factors – both tangible and
resources lose value when transferred to markets that intangible, human and non-human – that are owned or con-
are dissimilar to the one where it originated (Wern- trolled by the firm and enter into the production of goods and
erfelt and Montgomery 1988). Researchers adopting services to satisfy human wants (Amit and Schoemaker
1993), while capabilities refers to the firm’s capacity to
the RBV are interested in how firms obtain competi- acquire, develop and deploy its resources to achieve superior
tive advantage through diversification in the long performance relative to other firms (Dierickx and Cool
term. The RBV theory suggests that developing a 1989).

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 25

Whether
R&C are
Valuable Yes
Resources Capabilities Durable
Diversify
(R) (C) Inimitable
Non-
substitutable?

No

Do not
diversify

Figure 3. The RBV on diversification

agers assume that resources that are not specific to firm performance. Markides and Williamson (1994,
any product category can result in growth through 1996) developed indicators of relatedness based on
diversification. However, due to slow organizational product or market-specific resources, such as brand
learning and causal ambiguity (Dierickx and Cool recognition, customer loyalty, distributor loyalty and
1989) and competitive pressures to be efficient (Kock organizational systems, and found a positive associa-
and Guillen 2001), diversification based on generic tion between these resources and firm performance.
resources would not be sustainable. For example, Brush (1996) examined the extent of resource
Philip Morris assumed that their generic resource of sharing between acquired and acquiring firms and
distribution was transferable from tobacco products found that the higher the resource sharing, the more
to soft drinks. They acquired 7UP only to turn around successful the acquisition.
and divest it years later because of the difficulty of The results of the above studies have been remark-
managing the franchise distribution network. Thus, ably consistent. By conceptualizing relatedness in
according to the RBV view, firms will have sustain- terms of shared specific resources (e.g. unique tech-
able advantage only if they diversify into products nology or managerial know-how), the above studies
that are related to the resources and capabilities that have found that firms with highly interrelated busi-
they already possess, i.e. the firm must show ‘coher- ness portfolios outperform firms with lower levels of
ence’ in its capabilities (Teece et al. 1994). portfolio relatedness. A model for this stream of
Although the RBV provides a deep theoretical research is presented in Figure 3.
understanding of the link between diversification and
firm performance, there are few empirical studies
The resource-based perspective on diversification
that investigate this link. One reason for this over-
in the context of emerging economies
sight is the difficulty in measuring the constructs of
resources and capabilities. Robins and Wiersema The types of resources that firms acquire over time
(1995) used RBV logic to measure the flow of tech- are related to the country and the industrial environ-
nology between businesses as an indicator of relat- ment surrounding them (Porter 1990). The emerging
edness. They found that the greater the extent of economies of East Asia, Latin America and Southern
technological interrelationships, the more superior Europe developed in the late 1960s and 1970s,
the performance of the firms. Ilinitch and Zeithmal mostly by entering into mature industries such as
(1995) studied the relationship between managerial simple assembled goods, electrical appliances,
relatedness and the performance of diversified rubber, transportation equipment, steel and chemi-
firms. A significant positive association emerged cals (Haggard 1990). The native governments of
between the degree of managerial relatedness and these countries encouraged local entrepreneurs to

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
26 S. Purkayastha et al.

participate in the economy by protecting them from run value-enhancing internal product and labour
foreign competition. These local entrepreneurs lever- markets. Khanna and Palepu (1999) established that
aged local and foreign contacts to obtain foreign indices of product, labour, and capital market inter-
technology and resources to serve the local market. mediation for Chilean and Indian business groups are
Further, Kock and Guillen (2001) opine that protec- positively correlated with both accounting and stock
tionism and other barriers in emerging economies market measures of firm performance. Chang and
distort the value of firms’ resources and capabilities. Hong (2000) found that Korean business groups had
They propose that in addition to competencies and a positive influence on firm performance, while Yiu
technological abilities, resources such as political et al. (2005) found that Chinese business groups that
and bureaucratic contacts and connections are impor- have developed a unique portfolio of market related
tant for firm performance in such environments. This resources and capabilities perform better than those
ability to leverage contacts or harness political and that have not.
bureaucratic connections can be applied across A second stream of work emerges from sociology
diverse industries, which results in the creation of an and considers groups as a medley of formal and
organization form characterized by diversification informal relationships that link together affiliates
across a wide range of businesses. Known as the (Granovetter 1994; Keister 1988). This network of
business group,6 this organizational structure has relationships, also known as social capital (Adler and
come to dominate the private sector in emerging Kwon 2002; Bhappu 2000), is built on mutual trust
economies (Ghemawat and Khanna 1998). For and reciprocity. Violation of trust and reciprocity can
example, in 2000, Chinese business groups contrib- permanently damage the relationship, resulting in
uted close to 60% of the nation’s industrial output both social and economic ostracization, so partici-
(Liu et al. 2006) and Indian business groups con- pants are encouraged to comply with the norms of
trolled about 75% of the total industrial output in the the network. The expected benefits of the network are
private sector (data collected from CMIE7 database). high quality information processing among the par-
Business groups are defined as a set of firms ticipants, mutual influence and power, and resource
which, though legally independent, are bound sharing (Adler and Kwon 2002). Thus, the economist
together by a constellation of formal and informal interpretation of business groups as primarily driven
ties and are accustomed to taking co-ordinated by equity interlocks is disputed in this stream of
actions (Khanna and Rivkin 2001). Leff (1978) research. The downside of social capital is that overly
defines a business group as a group of companies embedded intragroup networks can encourage paro-
that do business in different markets under a chialism, xenophobia, isolationism and inertia,
common administrative or financial control, and its which are detrimental to corporate performance and
members are linked by interpersonal trust and on the globalization (Chung 2004).
basis of a similar personal, ethnic or commercial The third stream of research sees business groups
background. Research on business groups using the as counterproductive because they enable a handful
resource-based perspective is limited (Khanna and of firms to obtain favourable treatment from the
Palepu 2000a), and can be divided into a few broad power structure of the country in question, thus
streams. Pioneered by Leff (1976, 1978), the domi- posing a direct barrier to the operation of competitive
nant stream of work conceptualizes business groups forces in allocating resources efficiently in the
as responses to the lack of intermediary institutions economy (Ghemawat and Khanna 1998). Further,
resulting in market imperfections.8 Chang and this close connection to the power structure ensures
Hong (1998) found evidence that Korean chaebols that the firms can be bailed out in times of distress,
especially when they are considered too big to fail.
6
The most influential study in this stream is the Fis-
Business groups are known as groups in Latin America,
business houses in India, and chaebols in South Korea. man’s (2001) event study in Suharto’s9 Indonesia. He
7
CMIE (Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy) is a found that announcements related to Suharto’s mor-
database which has information for around 10,000 firms. tality yielded sharp reductions in the market capita-
8
This view can be related to the role of institutions discussed lization of firms that were considered to be in close
in the previous section. However, the RBV in emerging
economies is more comprehensive than the role of institu-
9
tions view, as the former includes the sociological and Suharto (8 June 1921–27 January 2008) was the second
political perspective of the diversification–performance President of Indonesia, holding the office from 1967 to
relationship. 1998.

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 27

proximity to the President. Much of the work in this great supply, and thus cannot lead to sustained com-
stream is descriptive (Encarnation 1989; Gill 1999), petitive advantage (Montgomery and Wernerfelt
so further empirical studies are needed to validate the 1988; Wernerfelt and Montgomery 1988).
current findings. In the case of emerging economies, resource-
Research needs to be done on the impact of busi- based theorists point out that the rationale for the
ness groups not only on their affiliated firm perfor- development of business groups can be found in the
mance, but also on the economy as a whole. In environment which prevailed during the beginning of
countries as varied as China, India, Korea, Malay- economic development in these countries. Local
sia, Mexico and South Korea, policy-makers and entrepreneurs were encouraged by the native govern-
managers are currently debating the future of busi- ment to participate in the economy; the selection of
ness groups. The debate has gathered momentum as entrepreneurs being based on their ability to use con-
waves of deregulation and financial crises reshape tacts to combine knowledge of local markets with
the economic landscapes of these countries. Some technological and organizational resources from
policy-makers, as in South Korea, have advocated outside the country (Oliver 1997). Moreover, firm
the shrinking of business groups while others, as in performance is also determined by political and
China, have encouraged the formation of business bureaucratic contacts and connections (Kock and
groups. Yet others in India and South Africa have Guillen 2001). We argue that resources required to
adopted a mixed stance. It would be very difficult to develop such capabilities are generic, which created
rationalize such marked variance in public policies incentives for firms to use them across diverse indus-
without prior understanding of the potentially dif- tries, resulting in the formation of business groups.
ferent roles that business groups play in each of For example, Korean business groups were able to
these contexts. Studies that focus on the dynamic of acquire and deploy a set of non-specific industry
the business group would therefore make a strong entry skills, such as obtaining licences, arranging
contribution to the diversification literature in financial packages, acquiring technology and mana-
emerging economies. gerial know-how, with active support from the gov-
ernment (Amsden and Hikino 1994). Because these
resources are generic in nature, and unless repeatedly
Discussion used, they would become idle, business groups can
use these resources to diversify profitably across
Resource-based-view theorists argue that diversifi-
unrelated industries (Guillen 2000). Therefore, we
cation in developed economies would be efficient if it
conclude:
were based on specific resources, rather than generic
resources, so that synergistic benefits from econ- (a) In developed economies, only firm-specific
omies of scope can be exploited (Teece 1980, 1982). resources would lead to sustainable competitive
The issue of specificity arises because diversification advantage, and hence firms should concentrate
based on a resource that is not characterized as caus- on one industry or at best on a limited number
ally ambiguous (Reed and DeFillippi 1990), path of related industries.
dependent, unique (Barney 1991) and perfectly (b) In emerging economies, generic resources
immobile (Peteraf 1993) will not lead to sustainable would lead to sustainable competitive advan-
competitive advantage. Therefore, firm-specific tage, which would create incentives for firms to
resources should be valuable, durable, inimitable and diversify into unrelated industries, resulting in
non-substitutable (Markides and Williamson 1994, the formation of business groups.
1996). We argue that firm-specific resources can only
be exploited in a single industry or at best in a limited
number of related industries. This is because a
resource which provides competitive advantage in
The role of finance
one industry may not do so in another.10 However,
The finance perspective in developed economies can
resources that are not specific (i.e. generic) are in
be divided into three broad streams. The first stream
comprises the risk-reduction motive of diversifica-
10
The example that we cite earlier in the paper of Philip tion; the second stream consists of economies of
Morris and their acquisition and subsequent divesture of internal capital market, and, the third stream takes
7UP points to that effect. the agency view.

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
28 S. Purkayastha et al.

Risk and diversification in developed economies even when they detect that managers are not invest-
ing funds in the most efficient way. In contrast, the
Unrelated diversification is pursued by firms because
corporate office of a diversified firm, which acts as
negatively correlated earnings streams from two or
an internal capital market, has rich information on
more businesses would reduce the total variance in
its divisions and auditing systems which allows it
organizational earnings (Amit and Linvat 1988).
effectively to control divisional managers by adjust-
Considering that the goal of the firm is earnings
ing their incentive if performance is inadequate
stability, the firm should seek new acquisitions or
(Jones and Hill 1988; Williamson 1975). Thus, a
investments with earnings streams different from that
diversified firm can achieve an efficient allocation of
of its existing business (Lewellem 1971; Perry 1998).
resources between divisions and also control them
Risk diversification is therefore one of the benefits of
effectively. Further, a cost–benefit analysis of inter-
unrelated diversification.
nal market vs external debt market reveals that an
Researchers, however, argue that an economic
internal capital market leads to better monitoring
advantage cannot be achieved by a conglomerate
than financial institutional lending, and thus makes
merger (Levy and Sarnat 1970). Although firms can
it easier to redeploy efficiently the assets that are
minimize unsystematic risk, no value is expected to
poorly performing.
be created due to risk pooling in unrelated diversified
However, an internal capital market has some
firms even under the assumption of perfect capital
disadvantages; first, it reduces managerial entrepre-
markets, since shareholders can achieve the desired
neurial incentives, as funding is decided by the head-
level of risks through individual portfolio diversifi-
quarters (Gertner et al. 1994). Secondly, it can give
cation at a cost lower than that of the firm (Mont-
rise to agency problems because of the resources
gomery and Singh 1984). Thus, managers should not
at its disposal. However, agency problem may not
be concerned with managing such risk, as it can be
necessarily be a bad thing, as long as the tendencies of
done profitably by investors and thus would not be
managers are more or less in line with shareholder
rewarded by the stock market (Lubatkin and O’Neill
value maximization (Stein 1997). Finally, an internal
1987). Although firms can lower their systematic risk
capital market leads to inefficient allocation if the firm
by related diversification, that benefit arises from
segments are not financially independent, since a
synergies through sharing resources in related busi-
financial shock in one segment affects the cost of
nesses rather than risk diversification (Lubatkin and
finance in another segment, even if the latter segment
Chatterjee 1994).
has better profitability (Lamont 1997). Thus, invest-
ment does not depend on the segment’s better invest-
Transaction costs of internal capital markets in
ment opportunities, and hence cross-subsidization is
developed economies
not always efficient (Berger and Ofek 1995; Shin and
Williamson (1975) suggested that the internal Stulz 1997).
capital market provides a rationale for diversifica-
tion. His argument is built on the proposition that
Agency theory in developed economies
diversified firms have lower transaction costs com-
pared with undiversified firms in raising and allo- Agency theory explores the possibility that diversi-
cating capital. A single business firm is more fication may be motivated by managerial efforts to
dependent on external resources for raising capital, make personal gains. This theory suggests that
which is often more costly than internally created diversification may benefit managers because of the
capital (Caper 2003). Raising funds internally not power and prestige associated with managing a
only reduces transaction costs, but also gives the larger firm (Jensen 1986), the relationship between
firm the ability to shift capital within the firm to managerial compensation and firm size (Jensen and
where it is expected to bring the greatest returns Murphy 1990) and reduction in the unemployment
(Stein 1997). Moreover, stockholders (members of risks of managers (Amihud and Lev 1981). Agency
the external capital market) experience information theorists also argue that there is a conflict of interest
and control disadvantages owing to the diffused because of the difference in risk preference between
ownership of a firm. The existence of information managers and stockholders. The managerial motive
asymmetries allows managers to behave opportunis- of diversification is largely to decrease managers’
tically and also restricts stockholders to taking dis- unemployment risk (Amihud and Lev 1981). In
ciplinary actions, owing to high transaction costs contrast, as stockholders can diversify their own

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 29

portfolios quickly and at a lower cost/risk than the processing, ineffective price mechanisms or poor
firm, so they have little to gain from the risk- contractual obligations (Chang and Hong 2000).
reducing aspects of unrelated diversification (Levy Inefficient external markets make it harder for firms
and Sarnat 1970). to conduct day-to-day business. Under these condi-
Besides the risk aspect of diversification, excess tions, business groups reduce the transaction costs of
cash flow can also lead managers to diversify. Man- affiliated firms mainly in three ways. First, business
agers would be unwilling to deploy the extra groups are organizational structures for appropriat-
resources as dividends, as that would decrease the ing quasi-rents which accrue as a result of the low
resources under their control. Moreover, in the event transaction costs of accessing scarce and imperfectly
of resources being required, they have to depend on marketed inputs such as capital and information
the external capital market, resulting in increased (Chung 2004); second, business groups provide an
external monitoring of the firm. Managers will thus alternative to portfolio diversification owing to the
use the free (excess) cash flow in value-reducing absence of developed capital markets; and third,
activities such as diversification and takeovers business groups engage in vertical integration to
(Jensen 1986). eliminate problems arising from bilateral monopoly
However logically compelling, the empirical or oligopoly (Chang and Choi 1988). Transaction
evidence points to an alternative explanation for cost theory has also been used in conjunction with
diversification. Evidence suggests that there is a social capital theory in emerging economies. As
significant decrease in the number of firms engaged mentioned earlier, social capital refers to a web of
in diversification activities (i.e. mergers) for social, interpersonal and structural relationships
manager-controlled firms compared with owner- which are built on trust and reciprocity (Adler and
controlled firms (Denis et al. 1997).11 There is evi- Kwon 2002). The expected benefits of social capital
dence of a monotonically increasing relationship include high quality information processing among
between diversification and the intensity of owner- the participants, mutual influence and power, and
ship (Amihud and Lev 1981). This may be due to solidarity (Tsai and Ghoshal 1998). Capitalizing
the tendency of empire-building by owners. More- on these benefits, business group companies can
over, concentrated ownership does not result in an improve their firms’ economic performance by
increase in value to the firm, and the refocusing that reducing transaction costs.
had taken place mostly in the 1980s was mainly Most agency theorists argue that professional
because of external market conditions rather than managers with little equity of their own may pursue
ownership changes (Denis et al. 1997). Figure 4 value-reducing actions such as diversification at the
provides a summary model of the financial perspec- expense of shareholders (Fama and Jensen 1983;
tive of diversification. Jensen and Meckling 1976). Some further argue that
firms with concentrated ownership outperform those
with dispersed ownership, because they have a strong
The finance perspective applied to incentive to monitor managers and discipline them
emerging economies (Claessens et al. 1999; Thomsen and Pedersen 2000).
When the financial perspective is applied to emer- Continuing with this line of argument, Gong and
ging markets, it includes both transaction cost eco- Kim (1999) argue that the efficiency of business
nomics and the agency perspective. Transaction cost group managers is superior to that of professional
economists assert that, when open market costs are managers as the former have an ownership incentive.
low, firms should use market mechanisms to allocate However, agency problems may still exist in an
resources, but when such costs are relatively high, emerging economy between owners-cum-managers
firms should internalize the transactions (Choi et al. (who have corporate control of the business group)
1999; Todorova 2007). In an emerging market, there and minority shareholders of the affiliated firms of
are a variety of reasons for market failure: opportu- that business group. Specifically, business group
nistic behaviour of suppliers, inefficient information managers may intentionally sacrifice or transfer the
resources from one group company to strengthen the
11
competitive position of another group company
Manager-controlled firms are firms where no single group
owns more than 10% of the outstanding stock, whereas without enhancing the wealth of the former com-
owner-controlled firms are those where a single group owns pany’s shareholders (Chung 2004). Moreover, as the
more than 10% of outstanding stock (Denis et al. 1997). founder families also manage the business groups,

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
30 S. Purkayastha et al.

Risk Reduction
Negative Unrelated
relationship diversification
between may mitigate
unrelated risk but not
diversification better returns
and risk for investors.

Internal Capital Market

Reduces transaction Inefficient


costs in raising capital cross
Better allocative subsidization Firm
efficiency Reduces Performance
Better control of managerial
divisional managers entrepreneurial
incentives

Agency Theory

More power and No increase in


prestige the value of the
Better compensation firm
Reduce Free cash flow
unemployment risk results in value
Makes the manager reducing
indispensable for the activities like
firm diversification.

Diversification

Figure 4. The finance perspective on diversification

they can easily expropriate minority shareholders by problems still occur in advanced economies, as illus-
means of intra-group business transaction and abuse trated by the debacles of Enron and WorldCom and in
of insider information (Chang 2003). the recent financial crisis. In emerging economies,
While agency problems may also arise in devel- where the corporate governance mechanisms are
oped economies, they are constantly checked by more weak, agency problems are acute and can potentially
robust corporate governance systems. The board of threaten the survivability of business groups as illus-
directors, investor activism, and the capital markets trated by the Asian financial crises in the 1990s (Lim
constantly challenge professional managers, and et al. 2009). Although corporate governance mecha-
when these forces are operating efficiently, poorly nisms have begun to be more prominent in emerging
performing managers are replaced. Even with such economies, they still have a long way to go (Chung
elaborate corporate governance mechanisms, agency 2004).

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 31

Discussion least in developed economies, reveals conflicting


results when firm performance is measured in
Proponents of agency theory within the financial
accounting terms, such as return on assets (ROA) or
stream argue that, in developed economies, there is a
return on sales (ROS), vis-à-vis share price terms,
conflict of interest between professional managers
such as the Sharpe ratio or Treynor ratio. For
and shareholders because of their difference in risk
example, firms diversifying into related areas have
preference. Diversification, specifically unrelated
the highest ROA (Bettis 1981; Hoskisson 1987),
diversification, provides incentives for managers by
while firms diversifying into unrelated areas have the
providing them with greater job security and higher
highest Sharpe, Jensen and Treynor ratios (Michel
executive compensation (Amihud and Lev 1981;
and Shaked 1984; Dubofsky and Varadarajan (1987).
Jensen and Murphy 1990). The managerial motive for
Although firm performance is a multi-dimensional
diversification is largely to decrease their unemploy-
concept, a review of the literature reveals a growing
ment risk (Amihud and Lev 1981). In contrast, share-
consensus that performance is at least a two-
holders can diversify their portfolios at a much lower
dimensional construct consisting of risk and return
cost/risk than the firm, so they have little to gain from
(Bettis and Hall 1982; Lubatkin and Rogers 1989).
the risk-reducing benefit of unrelated diversification.
Traditionally, performance was measured by returns
In emerging economies, agency theorists argue
only, and it is only recently that attention has been
that, because the business groups are owned and
given to risk measurement, because diversification
managed by founder families, agency problems of
which results in improved returns but at the cost of
the type evidenced in developed economies are
increased risks does not leave a firm better off than
absent (Chung 2004). However, agency problems are
one which results in lower returns and also lower
created between the founder families who also
risks (Bettis and Mahajan 1985). Further, if risk is
manage the business groups (principal/manager) and
excluded, it is simplistically assumed that managerial
the minority shareholders of the affiliated firms. As
motives of diversification for the purpose of risk
the founder families command the controlling shares
reduction do not exist, which, according to the
of affiliated firms, they can expropriate minority
agency theory, is not true. Thus, risk and return act in
shareholders by means of intra-group business trans-
concert to motivate diversification.
actions and abuse of insider information (Chang
The second critical aspect is that each dimension
2003). Such problems are further aggravated because
of performance can be measured using either
of the lack of efficient corporate governance mecha-
accounting- or market-based data. Accounting-based
nisms. Hence we conclude that:
measures are oriented towards the past and thus may
(a) in developed economies, agency problems arise be susceptible to accounting manipulation (Chakra-
between shareholders and professional manag- varthy 1986), so they may not reflect the expected
ers, whereas future cash flow which a firm is likely to generate.
(b) in emerging economies, agency problems arise Researchers have found that there is a strong positive
between minority shareholders and business correlation between accounting-based measures and
group managers. market-based measures of firm performance (Jacob-
son 1987). However, when these measures are used
Diversification and the measurement to evaluate diversification strategies, they lead to
of firm performance conflicting findings (Dubofsky and Varadarajan
1987; Hoskisson et al. 1993; Lubatkin et al. 1993).
The relationship between diversification and firm This may be due to the time lags in reflecting the
performance depends to a great extent on the meas- impact of a firm’s diversification strategy on
urement of firm performance. Researchers have used accounting-based measures of performance (Dubof-
both accounting measures (Bettis 1981; Hill 1983; sky and Varadarajan 1987) or to the greater role that
Palepu 1985) and market measures (Dubofsky and environmental instability plays in stock market
Varadarajan 1987; Michel and Shaked,1984) in returns (Keats and Hitt 1988). Studies have also used
examining this relationship.12 Empirical research, at hybrid approaches wherein they have combined
accounting and stock market data (Kakani 2000;
12
Detailed tables on the types of performance measures used Khanna and Palepu 2000a). These measures indicate
along with independent variables for each of the three per- how stockholders value a firm’s assets. Fundamental
spectives are available in the online version of the paper. to the belief of superiority of market-based measures

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
32 S. Purkayastha et al.

Table 1. Classification scheme for measuring firm performance

ROA, ROEa, ROS, ROIb, Abnormal returns, Sharpe


ROCc, Growth in sales, Index, Treynor Index,
Return Risk and return measured Return
Growth in earnings per Market to book equity, Risk and return measured
using accounting-based share Tobin’s Q using market-based data
data
Variability in ROA, ROC and Total risk, Systematic and
Risk Risk
earnings unsystematic risk
a
return on equity.
b
return on investment.
c
return on capital.

is the assumption that the market acts efficiently, and the aggregate analysis, some researchers have not
all future benefits of diversification are fully antici- considered the effect of industry (Amit and Linvat
pated and incorporated into the firm’s stock price 1988; Bettis 1981; Hill 1983; Palich et al. 2000),
(Lubatkin 1983). Table 1 represents the classification while others have controlled for industry effects
scheme of the alternative approaches found in diver- (Hoskisson 1987; Khanna and Palepu 2000a,b;
sification literature for measuring firm performance. Montgomery 1985; Villalonga 2004). Yet even when
researchers have controlled for industry effects, we
argue that the functional form of diversification and
Summary
firm performance relationship in different industries
So far, we have discussed three broad perspectives in may not be identical. Specifically, industry-wise
the literature on firm diversification – the external analysis may capture the intra-industry variation
perspective, the internal perspective and the finance which gets lost when studies are done at the aggre-
perspective – in two contexts, developed and emer- gate level. Future research thus needs to examine the
ging markets. We enriched the review with a discus- diversification and firm performance relationship
sion of the measurement issues on firm performance. across each industry separately.
The perspectives discussed above postulate different Secondly, future research also needs to include the
relationships between diversification and firm per- role of organizations in examining the relationship
formance. Given the objective to present a unified between diversification and firm performance. All
perspective on the benefits and pitfalls of firm diver- three broad perspectives discussed in the paper agree
sification, the lack of convergence in outcomes is that firm performance would be enhanced if there
disturbing. Reasons for the divergence of outcomes were transfer of skills and sharing of resources across
in the diversification literature include differences in different businesses. However, the crucial link that
the operationalization of variables used to measure examines the type of organizational mechanisms
diversification and performance. For example, some required to promote such transfer or sharing of skills
researchers have used continuous variable measures, remains virtually unexplored. Although Hill and
while others have used categorical measures. Simi- Hoskisson (1987) argue that related diversified firms
larly, firm performance has been measured using need to adopt co-operative organizational structures,
both accounting and/or market-based measures. and unrelated diversified firms require competitive
Table 2 summarizes the major findings across the organizational structures, empirical work done in this
three theoretical perspectives and two contexts, and area is sparse in the context of developed economies
the implications for future research in this area. and almost non-existent in the case of emerging
economies.
Finally, we concluded that unrelated diversifiers in
Implications and conclusions emerging economies are likely to be more profitable
than related diversifiers and that related diversifiers
Based on the extensive review of the diversification– are likely to be more profitable than unrelated diver-
performance relationship, we can identify several sifiers in the context of advanced economies. This
directions for future research. First, the relationship conclusion is based on studies that have been carried
between diversification and firm performance has out in relatively stable environments. There have been
been examined across all industries in aggregate. In relatively fewer studies that compare diversification

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 33

Table 2. Summary of the major findings of the three perspectives

The external view The internal view The finance perspective

Major findings in developed Related diversification is the Related firms that can create Systematic risk is not
economies best with accounting a structure by which diversifiable hence
measures of performance. strategically important diversification is not
Industry profitability plays a resources can be beneficial.
major role. transferred will be A diversified firm can have
Unrelated diversification is successful. the advantages of internal
the best with market capital market.
measures of performance. Diversification may be
motivated by managerial
efforts to make personal
gains.

Some papers Bettis 1981; Hill et al. 1992; Collis and Montgomery Amihud and Lev 1981; Amit
Michel and Shaked 1984; 1995; Ilinitch and and Linvat 1988; Jensen
Palepu 1985; Palich et al. Zeithmal 1995; Markides 1986; Lubatkin and
2000; Rumelt 1974 and Williamson 1996; Chatterjee 1994; Stein
Robins and Wiersema 1997
1995

Implications for future The exact relationship Empirical studies are rare Debate whether systematic
research in developed between diversification because of the difficulty of risk is diversifiable or not.
economies and performance. measuring the constructs Empirical evidence of
Which of the effects – that of of resources and monotonically increasing
diversification strategy or capabilities. relationship between
of industry structure – has diversification and
the greatest influence? intensity of ownership in
contrast to agency theory.

Major findings in emerging Institutions are inefficient so As emerging markets mature Undeveloped capital markets
economies greater diversification is firms must learn not only leads to diversified
not harmful. to acquire but also to hierarchical firm
share intangible resources development.
and capabilities across
other firms within the
same business group.

Some papers Kakani 2000; Khanna and Chang and Hong 2000; Chang and Choi 1988;
Palepu 1999 2000a,b; Khanna and Rivkin 2001; Chung 2004; Claessens
Peng and Health 1996 Yiu et al. 2005 et al. 1999

Implications for future Research is limited to China, Importance of business Inefficiency of capital
research in emerging Korea and East European groups is fairly recent and markets and how they can
economies countries, and thus both theoretical and be negated by the
broadening is required. empirical work is required. emergence of business
Benefits of diversification in groups.
times of major and broad
changes to the economy.

and firm performance in unstable periods such as an holders, as unpredictability clouds the effect of mana-
economy-wide shock (Lim et al. 2009). An economy- gerial decision (Haleblian and Finkelstein 1993).
wide shock, such as the Asian financial crisis, reduces Thus managers can engage in buffering, collusion
the internal market benefits for diversification and without fear of censure from other stakeholders. This
increases management and organizational costs for results in an increase in agency problems, and the
both developed and emerging markets (Chakrabarti mechanisms designed to control agency problems
et al. 2007). Moreover, an unstable environment become less effective in unstable environments.
increases managerial discretion, influence and control Future studies can establish the boundaries of our
over the organization at the expense of other stake- conclusions from this prior research by comparing

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
34 S. Purkayastha et al.

diversification and firm performance relationship return. Academy of Management Journal, 25, pp. 254–
under stable and unstable periods. 264.
To sum up, this paper compares and contrasts the Bettis, R.A. and Mahajan, V. (1985). Risk/return perform-
past cumulative empirical research on the relation- ance of diversified firms. Management Science, 31,
pp. 785–799.
ship between diversification and firm performance in
Bhappu, A.D. (2000). The Japanese family: the institutional
the context of developed economies with the more
logic for Japanese corporate networks and Japanese man-
recent work in emerging economies. The review of agement. Academy of Management Review, 25, pp. 409–
literature points to considerable diversities in find- 415.
ings across studies done in these two contexts, which Brush, T. (1996). Predicted change in operational synergy
can be attributed to theoretical and methodological and post-acquisition performance of acquired business.
reasons. In order to address these issues, we advance Strategic Management Journal, 17, pp. 1–24.
three directions for future research. Given that diver- Caper, N. (2003). An analysis of the relationships between
sification is likely to remain a popular growth option international diversification, product diversification, firm
in both the developed and the emerging market con- resources and firm performance. Doctoral dissertation,
texts, we suggest that scholars should look at the Florida State University, College of Business.
Carter, J.R. (1977). In search of synergy: a structure–
implications of industry on diversification decisions
performance test. Review of Economics and Statistics, 59,
and that managers of diversified firms should
pp. 279–289.
become aware of the implications of their diversifi- Chakrabarti, A., Singh, K. and Mahmood, I. (2007). Diver-
cation decisions as they continue to alter the scope sification and performance: evidence from East Asian
and scale of their firms. firms. Strategic Management Journal, 28, pp. 101–120.
Chakravarthy, B.S. (1986). Measuring strategic perform-
References ance. Strategic Management Journal, 7, pp. 437–458.
Chang, H.J. and Choi, U. (1988). Strategy, structure and
Adler, P. and Kwon, S. (2002). Social capital: prospects for performance of Korean business groups: a transaction
a new concept. Academy of Management Review, 27, pp. cost approach. Journal of Industrial Economics,
17–40. XXXVII, pp. 141–168.
Amihud, Y. and Lev, B. (1981). Risk reduction as a con- Chang, H.J. and Hong, J. (1998). How much does the busi-
glomerate motive for managerial mergers. Bell Journal of ness group matter in Korea? Mimeo, Korea University
Economics, 12, pp. 605–616. School of Business Administration.
Amit, R. and Linvat, J. (1988). Diversification and risk– Chang, S.J. (2003). Ownership structure, expropriation, and
return trade off. Academy of Management Journal, 31, pp. performance of group-affiliated companies in Korea.
154–166. Academy of Management Journal, 46, pp. 238–253.
Amit, R. and Schoemaker, P.J.H. (1993). Strategic assets and Chang, S.J. and Hong, J. (2000). Economicperformance of
organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, 14, group-affiliated companies in Korea; intragroup resource
pp. 33–46. sharing and internal business transaction. Academy of
Amsden, A. and Hikino, T. (1994). Project execution Management Journal, 43, pp. 429–448.
capability, organizational know-how and conglomerate Chang, Y. and Thomas, H. (1989). The impact of diversifi-
corporate growth in late industrialization. Industrial and cation strategies on risk–return performance. Strategic
Corporate Change, 3, pp. 111–147. Management Journal, 10, pp. 271–284.
Backman, M. (1999). Asian Eclipse: Exposing the Dark Side Chatterjee, S. (1986). Types of synergy and economic value:
of Business in Asia. Singapore: Wiley. the impact of acquisitions on merging and rival firms.
Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive Strategic Management Journal, 7, pp. 119–139.
advantage. Journal of Management, 17, pp. 99–120. Chatterjee, S. and Wernerfelt, B. (1991). The link between
Baumol, W.J., Panzer, J.C. and Willig, R.D. (1982). Contest- resources and type of diversification: theory and evidence.
able Markets and the Theory of Industrial Structure. New Strategic Management Journal, 12, pp. 33–48.
York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Child, J. and Lu, Y. (1996). Institutional constrains on eco-
Berger, P. and Ofek, E. (1995). Diversification’s effect nomic reforms: the case of investment decisions in China.
on firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 37, pp. Organizational Science, 7, pp. 60–67.
39–65. Choi, C.J., Lee, S.H. and Kim, J.B. (1999). A note on
Bettis, R.A. (1981). Performance differences in related and counter trade: contractual uncertainty and transaction
unrelated diversified firms. Strategic Management governance in emerging economies. Journal of Interna-
Journal, 2, pp. 379–393. tional Business Studies, 30, pp. 189–201.
Bettis, R.A. and Hall, W.K. (1982). Diversification strategy, Christensen, H.K. and Montgomery, C.A. (1981). Corporate
accounting determined risk, and accounting determined economic performance: diversification strategy versus

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 35

market structure. Strategic Management Journal, 2, Ghemawat, P. and Khanna, T. (1998). The nature of diversi-
pp. 327–343. fied business groups: a research design and two case
Chu, W. (2004). Are group-affiliated firms really more prof- studies. Journal of Industrial Economics, 46, pp. 35–61.
itable than nonaffiliated? Small Business Economics, 22, Gill, S. (1999). The Pathology of Corruptions. New Delhi:
pp. 391–405. HarperCollins.
Chung, H.K. (2004). Business groups in Japan and Korea: Gong, B.H. and Kim, C.H. (1999). The chaebols: myth and
theoretical boundaries and future direction. International reality. Paper presented at Mont Pelerin Conference, Van-
Journal of Political Economy, 34, pp. 67–98. couver, Canada, August.
Claessens, S., Simeon, D., Joseph, P.H. and Larry, H.P.L. Gort, M. (1962). Diversification and Integration in Ameri-
(1999). Corporate diversification in east Asia: the role of can Industry. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
ultimate ownership and group affiliation. World Bank, Gould, S. and Lewontin, R. (1979). The spandrels of San
Policy Research Working Paper 2089. Marco and the Panglossian paradigm: a critique of the
Collis, D.J. and Montgomery, C.A. (1995). Competing on adaptationist programme. Proceedings of the Royal
resources: strategy in the 1990s. Harvard Business Society of England, B205, pp. 581–598.
Review, July–August, pp. 118–128. Granovetter, M. (1994). Business groups. In Smelser, N.J.
Datta, D.K., Rajagopalan, N. and Rasheed, A.M.A. (1991). and Swedberg, R. (eds), Handbook of Economic Sociol-
Diversification and performance: critical review and ogy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press: Russell
future directions. Journal of Management Studies, 28, pp. Sage Foundation.
529–558. Grant, R.M. (1991). The resource-based theory of competi-
Demsetz, H. (1974). Industry structure, market rivalry and tive advantage: implications for strategy formulation.
public policy. Journal of Law and Economics, 16, pp. California Management Review, 33, pp. 114–134.
1–9. Grant, R.M. and Jammine, A.P. (1988). Performance differ-
Deneffe, D. (1993). Cost externalities and corporate diver- ences between Wrigley/Rumelt strategic categories. Stra-
sification. International Journal of Industrial Organiza- tegic Management Journal, 9, pp. 336–346.
tion, 11, pp. 261–282. Gribbin, J.D. (1976). The conglomerate merger. Applied
Denis, J.D., Denis, K.D. and Sarin, A. (1997). Agency prob- Economics, 8, pp. 19–34.
lems, equity ownership and corporate diversification. Guillen, M.F. (2000). Business groups in emerging econo-
Journal of Finance, 52, pp. 135–160. mies: a resource based view. Academy of Management
Devlin, R.A., Grafton, R.Q. and Rowlands, D. (1988). Journal, 43, pp. 362–380.
Rights and wrongs: a property rights perspective of Rus- Haggard, S. (1990). Pathways from the Periphery: The Poli-
sia’s market reforms. Antitrust Bulletin, 43, pp. 275–296. tics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries.
Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. (1989). Asset stock accumulation Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
and sustainability of competitive advantage. Management Haleblian, J. and Finkelstein, S. (1993). Top management
Science, 35, pp. 1504–1514. team size, CEO dominance, and firm performance: the
Dubofsky, P. and Varadarajan, P.R. (1987). Diversification moderating roles of environmental turbulence and discre-
and measures of performance: additional empirical tion. Academy of Management Journal, 36, pp. 844–863.
evidence. Academy of Management Journal, 30, pp. 597– Hill, C.W.L. (1983). Conglomerate performance over the
608. economic cycle. Journal of Industrial Economics, 2, pp.
Edwards, C.D. (1955). Business concentration and price 197–211.
policy. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Hill, C.W.L. (1985). Diversified growth and competition: the
Paper No. 0967. experience of twelve large UK firms. Applied Economics,
Encarnation, D. (1989). Dislodging Multinationals: India’s 17, pp. 827–847.
Comparative Perspective. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Hill, C.W.L. and Hoskisson, R.E. (1987). Strategy and struc-
Press. ture in the multi-product firm. Academy of Management
Fama, E.F. and Jensen, M.C. (1983). Separation of owner- Review, 2, pp. 331–341.
ship and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26, pp. Hill, C.W.L. and Snell, S.A. (1988). External control, cor-
74–98. porate strategy, and firm performance in research-
Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connec- intensive industries. Strategic Management Journal, 9,
tions. American Political Review, 91, pp. 1095–1102. pp. 577–590.
Fryxell, G.E. and Barton, S.L. (1990). Temporal and con- Hill, C.W.L. and Snell, S.A. (1989). Effects of ownership
ceptual changes in the measurement structure of financial structures and control on corporate productivity. Academy
performance: implications for strategy research. Journal of Management Journal, 32, pp. 25–46.
of Management, 16, pp. 553–569. Hill, C.W.L., Hitt, M.A. and Hoskisson, R.E. (1992). Co-
Gertner, R.H., Scharfstein, D.S. and Stein, J.C. (1994). Inter- operative versus competitive structures in related and
nal versus external capital markets. National Bureau of unrelated diversified firms. Organization Science, 3,
Economic Research, Working Paper No. 4776. pp. 501–521.

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
36 S. Purkayastha et al.

Hitt, M.A. and Ireland, R.D. (1986). Relationships among Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (2000a). The future of business
corporate level distinctive competencies, diversification groups in emerging economies: long run evidence from
strategies, corporate structure and performance. Journal Chile. Academy of Management Journal, 43, pp. 268–285.
of Management Studies, 23, pp. 401–416. Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (2000b). Is group affiliation
Hoskisson, R.E. (1987). Multidivisional structure and per- profitable in emerging markets: an analysis of Indian
formance: the contingency of diversification strategy. diversified business groups. Journal of Finance, 55,
Academy of Management Journal, 30, pp. 625–644. pp. 867–891.
Hoskisson, R.E., Eden, L., Lau, C.M. and Wright, M. Khanna, T. and Rivkin, J.W. (2001). Estimating the perform-
(2000). Strategy in emerging markets. Academy of Man- ance effects of business groups in emerging markets. Stra-
agement Journal, 43, pp. 249–267. tegic Management Journal, 22, pp. 45–74.
Hoskisson, R.E., Hitt, M.A., Johnson, R.A. and Moesel, Kock, C.F. and Guillen, M.F. (2001). Strategy and structure
D.D. (1993). Construct validity of an objective (entropy) in developing countries: business group as an evolution-
categorical measure of diversification strategy. Strategic ary response to opportunities for unrelated diversification.
Management Journal, 14, pp. 215–235. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10, pp. 77–113.
Hunter, J.E. and Schmidt, F.L. (1990). Methods of Meta- Leaven, L. and Levine, R. (2007). Is there a diversification
Analysis. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. discount in financial conglomerates? Journal of Financial
Ilinitch, A.Y. and Zeithmal, C.P. (1995). Operationalizing Economics, 85, pp. 331–367.
and testing Galbraith’s centre of gravity theory. Strategic Lamont, O. (1997). Cash flow and investments: evidence
Management Journal, 16, pp. 401–410. from internal capital markets. Journal of Finance, 52, pp.
Jacobson, R. (1987). The validity of ROI as a measure of 83–109.
business performance. American Economic Review, 77, Lecraw, J.D. (1984). Diversification strategy and perform-
pp. 470–478. ance. Journal of Industrial Economics, 2, pp. 179–
Jensen, M.C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, cor- 197.
porate finance and takeovers. American Economic Leff, N. (1976). Capital markets in less developed countries:
Review, 76, pp. 323–329. the group principle. In McKinon, R. (ed.), Money and
Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Finance in Economic Growth and Development. New
managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership struc- York: Marcel Dekker.
tures. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, pp. 305–360. Leff, N. (1978). Industrial organization and entrepreneurship
Jensen, M.C. and Murphy, K.J. (1990). Performance pay and in developing countries: the economic groups. Economic
top management incentives. Journal of Economic Per- Development and Cultural Change, 26, pp. 661–678.
spective, 2, pp. 21–48. Levy, H. and Sarnat, M. (1970). Diversification, portfolio
Johnson, G. and Thomas, H. (1987). The industry context of analysis and the uneasy case of conglomerate mergers.
strategy, structure and performance: the U.K. brewing Journal of Finance, 25, pp. 795–802.
industry. Strategic Management Journal, 8, pp. 343– Lewellem, W. (1971). A pure financial rationale for the
361. conglomerate merger. Journal of Finance, 26, pp. 521–
Jones, C.R. and Hill, C.W. (1988). Transaction cost analysis 527.
of strategy–structure choice. Strategic Management Lim, E.N., Das, S.S. and Das, A. (2009). Diversification
Journal, 9, pp. 159–172. strategy, capital structure and the Asian financial crises
Kakani, R.K. (2000). Financial performance and diversifi- (1997–1988): evidence from Singapore firms. Strategic
cation strategy of Indian business groups. Doctoral dis- Management Journal, 30, pp. 577–692.
sertation, Indian Institute of Management, Calcutta. Lins, K.V. and Servaes, H. (2002). Is corporate diversifica-
Keats, B.W. and Hitt, M.A. (1988). A causal model of link- tion beneficial in emerging markets? Financial Manage-
ages among environmental dimensions, macro organiza- ment, 31, pp. 5–31.
tional characteristics and performance. Academy of Liu, G., Wang, L. and Li, J. (eds) (2006). The China
Management Journal, 31, pp. 570–598. Economy Yearbook: Analysis and Forecast of China’s
Keister, L. (1988). Engineering growth: business group Economy. Beijing: China Economic Yearbook Press.
structure and firm performance in China’s transition Lubatkin, M. (1983). Mergers and the performance of the
economy. American Journal of Sociology, 10, pp. 404– acquiring firm. Academy of Management Journal, 8, pp.
440. 218–225.
Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (1997). Why focused strategies Lubatkin, M. and Chatterjee, S. (1994). Extending modern
may be wrong for emerging markets. Harvard Business portfolio theory into the domain of corporate diversifica-
Review, 77, pp. 3–10. tion: does it apply? Strategic Management Journal, 12,
Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (1999). Policy shocks, market pp. 251–270.
intermediaries, and corporate strategy: evidence from Lubatkin, M. and O’Neill, H.M. (1987). Merger strategies
Chile and India. Journal of Economics and Management and capital market risks. Academy of Management
Strategy, 2, pp. 271–310. Journal, 30, pp. 665–684.

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Diversification and Performance 37

Lubatkin, M. and Rogers, R.C. (1989). Diversification, sys- Peng, M.W. and Health, P.S. (1996). The growth of the firm
tematic risk and shareholders return: a capital market in planned economies in transition: institutions, organiza-
extension of Rumelt’s 1974 study. Academy of Manage- tions and strategic choice. Academy of Management
ment Journal, 32, pp. 454–465. Review, 21, pp. 492–528.
Lubatkin, M., Merchant, H. and Srinivasan, N. (1993). Con- Perry, R. (1998). A meta analytic review of diversification–
struct validity of some unweighted product-count diversi- performance relationship: aggregating findings in stra-
fication measures. Strategic Management Journal, 14, pp. tegic managements. Doctoral dissertation, Florida Atlan-
439–445. tic University.
Markham, J.W. (1973). Conglomerate Enterprise and Eco- Peteraf, M.A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive
nomic Performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University advantage: a resource-based view. Strategic Management
Press. Journal, 14, pp. 179–191.
Markides, C.C. and Williamson, P.J. (1994). Related diver- Phillips, A. (1976). A critique of the empirical studies of
sification, core competence and corporate performance. relations between market structure and profitability.
Strategic Management Journal, 15, pp. 149–165. Journal of Industrial Economics, 24, pp. 241–249.
Markides, C.C. and Williamson, P.J. (1996). Corporate Porter, M.E. (1990). The Competitive Advantage of Nations.
diversification and organizational structure: a resource- London: Macmillan.
based view. Academy of Management Journal, 39, pp. Prahalad, C.K. and Hamel, G. (1990). The core competence
340–367. of the corporation. Harvard Business Review, 68, pp.
McDougall, F.M. and Round, D.K. (1984). A comparison 79–91.
of diversifying and non-diversifying Australian industrial Ramanujam, V. and Varadarajan, P.R. (1989). Research on
firms. Academy of Management Journal, 27, pp. 384– corporate diversification: a synthesis. Strategic Manage-
398. ment Journal, 10, pp. 523–551.
Michel, A. and Shaked, I. (1984). Does diversification affect Reed, R. and Defillippi, R.J. (1990). Causal ambiguity, bar-
performance? Financial Management, 13, pp. 18–25. riers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage.
Miller, R.A. (1969). Market structure and industrial perform- Academy of Management Review, 15, pp. 88–102.
ance: relation of profit rates to concentration, advertising Rhodes, S.A. (1973). The effect of diversification on industry
intensity and diversity. Journal of Industrial Economics, profit performance in 241 manufacturing industries: 1963.
17, pp. 104–108. Review of Economics and Statistics, 55, pp. 146–155.
Montgomery, C.A. (1985). Product–market diversification Robins, J. and Wiersema, M.F. (1995). A resource-based
and market power. Academy of Management Journal, 28, approach to the multibusiness firm: empirical analysis of
pp. 789–798. portfolio interrelationships and corporate financial perfor-
Montgomery, C.A. (1994). Corporate diversification. mance. Strategic Management Journal, 16, pp. 277–299.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, pp. 163–178. Rumelt, R.P. (1974). Strategy, Structure and Economic Per-
Montgomery, C.A. and Singh, H. (1984). Diversification formance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
strategy and systematic risk. Strategic Management Saple, V. (2000). Diversification, merger and their effect on
Journal, 5, pp. 181–191. firm performance: a study of the Indian corporate sector.
Montgomery, C.A. and Wernerfelt, B. (1988). Diversifica- Doctoral dissertation, Indira Gandhi Institute of Develop-
tion, Ricardian rents, and Tobin’s Q. RAND Journal of ment Research, Mumbai, India.
Economics, 19, pp. 623–632. Scott, W.R. (1995). Institutions and Organizations. Thou-
Nelson, J.M., Tilley, C. and Walker, L. (1998). Transform- sand Oaks, CA: Sage.
ing post-communist political economies. In National Shenkar, O. and von Glinow, M.A. (1994). Paradoxes of
Research Council (ed.), Task Force on Economies in Tran- organizational theory and research: using the case of
sition. Washington DC: National Academy Press. China to illustrate national contingency. Management
Oliver, C. (1997). Sustainable competitive advantage: Science, 40, pp. 56–71.
gaining institutional and resource based views. Strategic Shin, H.H. and Stulz, R.M. (1997). Are internal capital
Management Journal, 18, pp. 697–713. markets efficient? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113,
Palepu, K. (1985). Diversification strategy, profit perform- pp. 531–552.
ance and the entropy measure. Strategic Management Singh, H. and Montgomery, C.A. (1987). Corporate acqui-
Journal, 6, pp. 239–255. sition strategies and economic performance. Strategic
Palepu, K. and Khanna, T. (1998). Building institutional Management Journal, 8, pp. 377–386.
infrastructure in emerging markets. Brown Journal of Stein, J.C. (1997). Internal capital markets and the compe-
World Affairs, V, pp. 71–78. tition for corporate resources. Journal of Finance, 52, pp.
Palich, L.E., Cardinal, L.B. and Miller, C.C. (2000). Curvi- 111–133.
linearity in the diversification–performance linkage: an Teece, D.J. (1980). Economies of scope and the scope of the
examination of over three decades of research. Strategic enterprise. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organiza-
Management Journal, 21, pp. 155–174. tion, 3, pp. 223–247.

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
38 S. Purkayastha et al.

Teece, D.J. (1982). Towards an economic theory of the Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis
multiproduct firm. Journal of Economic Behaviour and and Anti-Trust Implications. New York: Free Press.
Organization, 3, pp. 39–63. Yiu, D., Bruton, G.D. and Lu, Y. (2005). Understanding
Teece, D.J., Rumelt, R., Dosi, G. and Winter, S. (1994). business group performance in an emerging economy:
Understanding corporate coherence: theory and evidence. acquiring resources and capabilities in order to prosper.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 23, pp. Journal of Management Studies, 42, pp. 183–206.
1–30.
Thomsen, S. and Pedersen, T. (2000). Ownership structure
and economic performance in the largest European com-
panies. Strategic Management Journal, 21, pp. 689–705. Supporting information
Todorova, T. (2007). The Coase theorem revisited: implica-
tions for economic transition. Atlantic Economic Journal, Additional supporting information may be found in
35, pp. 189–201. the online version of this paper:
Tsai, W. and Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social capital and value
Table S1. Summary review of empirical research
creation: the role of intra-firm networks. Academy of
Management Journal, 3, pp. 390–412. papers in the external perspective that examines
Varadarajan, P.R. and Ramanujam, V. (1987). Diversification the relationship between diversification and firm
and performance: a reexamination using a two- performance.
dimensional conceptualization of diversity in firms. Table S2. Summary review of empirical research
Academy of Management Journal, 30, pp. 380–393. papers in the internal perspective that examines
Villalonga, B. (2004). Does diversification cause the ‘diver- the relationship between diversification and firm
sification discount’. Financial Management, 33, pp. 5–27. performance.
Wall Street Journal (1985). Shifting strategies: surge in Table S3. Summary review of empirical research
restructuring is profoundly altering much of US industry, papers in the finance perspective that examines
12 August, p. 1.
the relationship between diversification and firm
Wernerfelt, B. and Montgomery, C.A. (1986). What is an
performance.
attractive industry? Management Science, 32, pp. 1223–
1229.
Wernerfelt, B. and Montgomery, C.A. (1988). Tobin’s Q and
the importance of focus in firm performance. American Please note: Wiley-Blackwell are not responsible for
Economic Review, 78, pp. 246–250. the content or functionality of any supporting mat-
Weston, J.F. and Mansinghka, S.K. (1971). Test of the effi- erials supplied by the authors. Any queries (other
ciency performance of the conglomerate firms. Journal of than missing material) should be directed to the cor-
Finance, 26, pp. 909–914. responding author for the article.

© 2011 The Authors


International Journal of Management Reviews © 2011 British Academy of Management and Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

You might also like