You are on page 1of 19

440543

2012
EUR21110.1177/0969776412440543Muñoz-GielenEuropean Urban and Regional Studies

European Urban
and Regional
Article Studies

European Urban and Regional Studies

Urban governance, property 2014, Vol 21(1) 60­–78


© The Author(s) 2012
Reprints and permissions:
rights, land readjustment and sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0969776412440543

public value capturing eur.sagepub.com

Demetrio Muñoz-Gielen
Nijmegen School of Management, Radboud University of Nijmegen, The Netherlands

Abstract
There is an ongoing debate in the literature on urban policy networks about governance and, more specifically, the
role of public bodies in urban policy implementation networks. This paper focuses on the specific debate in Dutch
and Spanish academic and professional circles regarding property rights in land (hereafter property rights) and the
need to separate development rights from property rights. The British nationalisation of development rights in 1947
is an important point of reference in these debates. This paper adds to these debates by providing empirical evidence
about a land readjustment regulation that public bodies can use to modify the power relationships between public and
private parties. This regulation can improve public value capturing by helping public bodies transfer the costs for public
infrastructure and affordable housing to developers while capturing part of the enhanced economic value.

Keywords
Land readjustment, policy networks, property rights in land, public infrastructure, public value capturing, social and
affordable housing, urban governance, urban regeneration

Introduction
In late 20th-century academic debate on governmen- In governance, formal rules (laws and administra-
tal steering, public bodies were said to have lost their tive arrangements) decisively influence power rela-
dominant position in governance. In this debate, the tions between public and private actors. Property
advocates of the policy network approach criticised rights are one important – if not the most important
the rational central rule model for policy making and – type of formal rule. It is sometimes assumed that
implementation in which public bodies played a property rights grant property owners complete free-
dominant role over the other involved parties. These dom in deciding how to use their land. However, the
critics argued that, under the welfare state, where reality is that all countries restrict the exercise of
this model ruled the relationships between the gov- property rights through formal rules established in
ernment and the market, public policies often failed both private and public law. Formal rules from pri-
to meet their targets despite large public expendi- vate law regulate the obligations between equal
tures. The decline and collapse of the centrally gov-
erned states in Eastern Europe at the end of the 1980s
Corresponding author:
reinforced the perception that central government Demetrio Muñoz-Gielen, Radboud University Nijmegen,
steering had many shortcomings (Kickert Sumatrastraat 139D, 1094 LW Amsterdam, The Netherlands.
et al., 1997: 1–8). Email: demetrio@urbsadvies.nl

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 61

actors, regardless of whether the actors are public or bodies to do so on their behalf. Public infrastructure
private. Formal rules from public law regulate the refers to infrastructure provision (e.g. public roads
actions that public bodies impose on others and space) and to the construction of public facilities,
(Needham, 2006: 1–3, 36–38, 39, 43–46). affordable housing and social housing. ‘Value cap-
The current debate in the urban planning field in turing’ describes the moment when the public bodies
the Netherlands and Spain focuses on the extent that have invested in the infrastructure capture the
to which public law should regulate the right of enhanced value that results from the investment
landowners to develop their land. The British 1947 whereas ‘creaming off plus value’ refers to a public
Town and Country Planning Act is the best-known body capturing the enhanced value regardless of any
attempt to regulate this right and has influenced the incurred costs (Smith and Gihring, 2006: 752; Van De
Dutch and Spanish debates, which are quite similar. Krabben and Needham, 2008: 4).
For example, in both countries controversial pro- The evidence presented in this study is based
posals have been presented to separate development on case studies of urban regeneration in the UK
rights from property rights, proposals that echo the (England), the Netherlands and Spain (the region of
1947 British provisions. Although these proposals Valencia). Exploratory research was also conducted
have not been implemented in the Netherlands, in in six other European Union (EU) countries: France,
1994 Spain took concrete steps to do just that; the Germany, Sweden, Italy, Belgium (Flanders) and
region of Valencia adopted new legislation that Denmark.
modified the existing land readjustment regulation The remainder of the paper is organised into seven
to effectively separate infrastructure provision from sections. ‘Power and the role of public bodies in pol-
property rights. This innovation is currently imple- icy networks’ introduces the principles of the policy
mented in almost all 17 Spanish regions. network approach and the main features of the
This paper provides empirical evidence about the advocated role for governments. ‘Critiques of the
possibilities in urban development to modify the policy network approach’ sketches the critiques to
power relations between public bodies (e.g. munici- this advocated role while the ‘The debate on property
palities, public planning bodies, public development rights’ section presents the debate in the Netherlands
agencies) and private actors (non-profit and for profit) and Spain about property rights and introduces the
through network management tools. The evidence modification of property rights that will be empiri-
focuses on how one aspect of property rights – the cally assessed in the following sections. ‘Analysis of
degree to which public bodies depend on landowners power relations in urban development’ presents the
to provide the infrastructure – affects public value first insight into the empirical evidence: an assess-
capturing. Public value capturing is when public bod- ment of the power relationship between public and
ies transfer the costs of public infrastructure and private parties in the exploratory research conducted
affordable housing (the costs of land and construc- in nine EU countries. ‘Method and data’ summarises
tion) to developers while capturing the benefits of the methodology of data gathering and subsequent
development, i.e. the increase in economic value that analysis, including the strategies for improving
accrues from re-zoning the site. Various concepts fall validity. ‘Findings from urban regeneration in
under the notion of ‘public value capturing’, and a England, Valencia and the Netherlands’ presents
multitude of often similar and overlapping terms are detailed empirical data for England, the Netherlands
used in the literature to describe these concepts and the Spanish region of Valencia, and the final
(Alterman, 2009). In this paper, I distinguish three section draws conclusions on the study’s possible
concepts: ‘cost recovery’, ‘value capturing’ and implications for academic and professional debates.
‘creaming off plus value’. ‘Cost recovery’ refers to
the recovery of costs related to building public infra- Power and the role of public bodies
structure through contributions from private develop-
ers. In cost recovery, private developers may
in policy networks
contribute to public infrastructure either by construct- The policy network approach positions itself as a
ing this infrastructure directly or by paying the public sort of ‘third way’ between the rational central rule

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


62 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

model and a market-orientated approach. The net- implementing public policies is a process that relies
work approach emerged in the early 1970s (Kickert on more than one single actor (Kickert et al., 1997:
et al., 1997: 7–8; Klijn and Koppenjan, 2000: 136– 2 Klijn, 1997: 30–31; Scharpf, 1978: 347, 350).
139) as an alternative to the traditional interorgan- Let us further examine the concepts of power,
isational approach. The interorganisational approach resources and dependence. According to Giddens, an
saw public management as a top-down activity agent exercises ‘power’ if he or she can ‘ “make a
based on a clear authority structure consisting of difference” to a pre-existing state of affairs or course
three steps: setting the goals (planning), structuring of events’ (1984: 14–16, 258). By exercising control
and designing the organisation (organising) and over ‘resources’, an actor can influence the behaviour
‘getting the job done’ (leading). In contrast, the net- of others, and in doing so, he or she makes a differ-
work approach argues that a single public central ence to a pre-existing state of affairs or course of
authority cannot have the power to unilaterally events, i.e. exercises power. Elias described ‘depen-
determine clear goals and well-defined requirements dence’ between people as the inverse of power rela-
before policy making and policy implementation tions (1971: 84–85). ‘A’ can exercise power over ‘B’
processes start and that this authority, moreover, because ‘B’ depends on ‘A’ for obtaining one or more
cannot have the power to plan and guide these pro- resources, i.e. the unequal allocation of resources cre-
cesses (Kickert et al., 1997: 11–12). ates dependence and, in turn, dependence allows the
Several factors can explain power relations in exercise of power. The strength or degree of this
policy making and policy implementation processes. dependency is connected to the importance of the
Scharpf suggested focusing on the more stable struc- resources and their substitutability, i.e. the ease with
tural factors that facilitate or impede certain formu- which they can be replaced by other resources (Klijn,
lae of power relations among the involved actors and 1997: 31; Scharpf, 1978: 354–358).
using resource dependence as a method for discover- Together with the concepts of power, depen-
ing these structural factors (1978: 353–334, 366). Of dency and resources, formal rules are also relevant
course, other relevant but non-structural factors also because they regulate the interactions between
play a role in power relations, for example consoli- actors by defining rights and then stating to whom
dated game patterns and the contingent behaviour of these rights belong. Formal rules also create new
individual actors. However, structural factors are resources, which are needed for policy making and
important as they explain the possibility or probabil- implementation, and then allocate them to certain
ity of certain forms of power relations. From this actors (e.g. the legal obligation to have the zoning
perspective, policy networks have three important plans approved and to obtain building permits
structural factors: (1) actors pursue their own goals before being allowed to build). Thus, rules regulate
and are mutually dependent, (2) there is no dominant the behaviour of actors and the distribution of
actor and (3) it is possible to manage networks resources in the network, and this, in turn, shapes
(Klijn, 1997: 30–33). dependency and correspondingly defines the power
interactions among the actors. However, this process
is more complex because power interactions also
Actors pursue their own goals and are shape, consolidate or alter rules (Klijn, 1997: 33;
mutually dependent Klijn and Koppenjan, 2000: 139). In other words,
Policy networks consist of different actors that pur- rules shape power interactions, but power interac-
sue their own goals and follow their own strategy. tions also shape rules (Figure 1).
This individualistic behaviour harbours potential
conflict because the goals and strategies of the
actors might diverge. That said, even though the There is no dominant actor
actors pursue different goals, they are also mutually The network approach seems to apply to the policy
dependent. Dependency is essential for explaining field the same principles of Giddens’s ‘dialectic of
a policy network’s existence as elaborating and control’ in social systems (1984: 16). The network

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 63

which is more time consuming and is thus meant


for future interactions between actors. The empiri-
cal evidence in the ‘Analysis of power relations in
urban development’ and ‘Findings from urban
regeneration in England, Valencia and the
Netherlands’ sections examines how this second
type of tool works.

Figure 1.  The relationship between rules, resources,


Critiques of the policy network
dependence and power in policy networks. approach
The critics of the network approach blame it for
devaluing the status of the public sector (Kickert
approach assumes, as this dialectic does, that each et al., 1997: 170–171; Klijn and Koppenjan, 2000:
actor has at its disposal some of the resources/rules 151–154) when it treats the public sector as just
that are required by the other actors to achieve their another actor in the network. These same critics also
goals, and thus there is no dominant actor (Verhage, question the network approach’s proposal of directly
2002: 158). This assumption explains why the need engaging and involving governments in policy net-
for cooperation is central in the network approach: works as the only way of successfully elaborating
policies can develop only when each actor makes its and implementing policies. In their reproach to the
resources available to the other actors. In other network approach, they criticise the problems of
words, each actor has a veto power (Kickert et al., democratic legitimacy and accountability of deci-
1997: 6; Klijn and Koppenjan, 2000: 142–144; sion making in networks.
Scharpf, 1978: 347, 350). Public actors are recog- In a response to these critiques, Klijn and
nised as occupying a special position in the network Koppenjan argue that the network approach simply
approach because of the unique resources they tries to enable the public sector to defend the public
control and the democratic legitimacy they enjoy. interest and the primacy of politics in a context of
However, this special position is that of a primus interdependency among public and private parties
inter pares and is nowhere close to a dominant role (2000: 151). As is shown in the ‘Power and the role
(Klijn and Koppenjan, 2000: 151). of public bodies in policy networks’ section, the idea
of interdependency is based on the assumption that
governments cannot replace the resources controlled
It is possible to manage policy networks by other actors, and if the resources can be replaced,
The special position of public bodies makes them it is too costly and time consuming for the govern-
suitable to steer or to manage the interactions ment to do so.
between the actors. The network approach distin- Following the critique of Koffijberg, who claims
guishes two types of network management tools: to have discovered how public bodies can effec-
process management and network constitution tively play a dominant role in housing policy net-
(Klijn, 1997: 46–53; Klijn and Koppenjan, 2000: works (2005: 322–323), this paper criticises the
140–142). Process management tries to improve network approach’s basic assumption that interde-
the interactions that are already occurring between pendency is unavoidable. In doing so, this paper
actors and assumes the existing institutional empirically analyses the effects that one specific
context, e.g. the existing rules and resource distri- network constitution management tool has on power
bution. The second network management tool – interactions in policy networks in urban regenera-
network constitution – seeks institutional change, tion in the UK, Spain and the Netherlands, and how
e.g. change of rules and resource distribution, these effects influence the capturing of public value.

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


64 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

The management tool is a land readjustment regula- led, in both countries, to proposals to separate prop-
tion that limits property rights. The next section erty rights from development rights that resemble the
introduces the debate about urban property rights in 1947 nationalisation of development rights in Britain.
the UK, Spain and the Netherlands and shows how
this stimulated the Spanish region of Valencia to
introduce this tool. The debate in the Netherlands
Since the 1990s, private parties have assumed a
more relevant role in urban development by seeking
The debate on property rights to buy land earmarked for re-zoning. As a result, the
building of social housing has drastically dimin-
The British nationalisation of ished (Cao and Priemus, 2007: 367–368). The cur-
development rights rent discussion in Dutch urban planning is focused
The British 1947 Town and Country Planning Act on whether public law (e.g. expropriation) and pri-
introduced the so-called ‘nationalisation of develop- vate law (e.g. buying the land, providing the infra-
ment rights’. The 1947 Act vested development rights structure and assuming all the corresponding costs
(the right to change the prescribed use of land) in the and risks) empower public bodies to satisfactorily
state rather than the landowner. In short, this act man- control the delivery of sufficiently serviced building
dated that no development could take place without plots, the subsequent delivery of building quotas,
permission of the local planning authority. The act also and the financing of public infrastructure. The most
stipulated that if permission were refused, landowners controversial discussions revolve around the sepa-
had no right to compensation (Clusa and Mur, 2007: ration of property rights from development rights.
122–136; Cullingworth and Nadin, 2006: 195–197). If Priemus and Louw (2000: 6–10, 2003) expressed
permission to develop the land were granted, the 1947 scepticism about the powers of public and private
Act stipulated a 100% tax on the accruing betterment. law. The authors found that municipalities suffer seri-
However, this land value taxation was short-lived and ous bottlenecks in obtaining land and recovering the
disappeared for a time. In 1976, the tax was reintro- costs of constructing public infrastructure. According
duced but it was soon fully abolished in 1985. Since to them, there is no free competition in the building
then the UK has not had a betterment tax (Clusa and market, and the success of private parties in this mar-
Mur, 2007: 124–127; Oxley, 2006: 104). In the mean- ket does not hinge on their ability to offer a better and
time, however, betterment-like taxes have been intro- cheaper product but rather on a monopolistic position
duced. In 2004, the Barker Review and the Planning obtained thanks to their control of land. Developers
and Compulsory Purchase Act recommended introduc- tend to pay higher prices for acquiring land, which
ing a Planning-gain Supplement, a sort of added stan- increases development costs that have to be recov-
dard charge to the existing negotiated contributions. In ered through the sale of the constructed buildings.
2010, a Community Infrastructure Levy was intro- The consequence is a diminished and impoverished
duced, which complements the existing negotiated public infrastructure and social housing. Buitelaar et
contributions (Department for Communities and Local al. concluded that another consequence is the maxi-
Government, 2010: 4). The levy, however, cannot be misation of the building volume, which creates many
considered a proper betterment tax because it aims at buildings but little public space (2008: 17–18, 20).
cost recovery and not the expropriation of added value. Korthals-Altes and Groetelaers argued that pub-
This British experience has influenced the debate lic law offers many possibilities and that munici-
about property rights in the Netherlands and Spain. palities still retain some control by purchasing land
In both countries, owing to similar problems with and/or by contractual agreements. The authors go
the public steering of urban development and the a step further by arguing that these are sufficient
financing of public infrastructure, a debate has means for preserving the public interest and influ-
emerged about possible solutions. This debate has encing urban development (2000: 43–45). However,

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 65

Priemus and Louw disagree and are markedly more In the late 1980s critics of this land readjustment
pessimistic about the effectiveness of both public regulation advocated reform (see García-Bellido,
and private law instruments (2003: 373–375). 1989, 1991, 1994; Parejo, 1993). They argued that
Together with Priemus and Louw, some other the anti-speculation provisions in the regulation
authors also see the current strategies of land acqui- (compulsory readjustment and expropriation if land-
sition and the corresponding creation of monopolis- owners fail to provide the public infrastructure) were
tic/oligopolistic positions as limiting free competition ineffective in practice; many municipalities were
in the building market and as harming public interest confronted with the choice between (1) maintaining
by, for example, reducing public value capturing. the requirements but losing the cooperation of the
These authors argue that free competition is possible landowners or (2) lowering the requirements to reach
only by separating development rights from property an agreement. The above-mentioned position of
rights. Canoy and Van Ewijk (1999: 25) recommend Priemus and Louw (2000) in the Dutch debate – that
that landowners should be required to tender for the there is no free competition in the building market –
development and building rights on their land. shares many similarities with the idea in the Spanish
Similarly, Priemus (1996: 32) and Priemus and debate of a ‘captive urban land market’ (García-
Louw (2003: 376–377) propose that expropriation Bellido, 1994: 114–115, 578–579). Owing to restric-
should be possible when the landowner does not tive zoning and the natural features of land (each
develop the plot in a ‘competitive manner’. location is unique), developing land cannot be sub-
Accordingly, the municipality should be able to ject to free competition. Property rights give land-
expropriate the land and organise a public tender. In owners the power to enjoy exclusive use of their land
2009, a governmental advisory commission pro- and to exclude others, i.e. landowners have a monop-
posed to limit property rights in several strategic oly or at least an oligopoly in the building market.
areas (Vrom-raad, 2009: 41–42) and a more recent While parties compete to acquire the land, once they
study evaluated the possible effects in urban devel- own it they do not need to compete any more. They
opment practice of splitting development rights from
can wait, without having to make any investment or
property rights (Geuting, 2011).
effort, until the buyers of the final buildings or other
property developers interested in acquiring and
developing the land offer the highest possible price.
The separation of infrastructure provision Landowners can thus demand the maximum price,
from property rights in Valencia and, in doing so, they can absorb all the residual
Since the 19th century, the difficulties faced by profit margins from the subsequent construction.
Spanish municipalities to finance and realise public The British experience decisively influenced
infrastructure have inspired fundamental reform pro- García-Bellido’s proposal to allow the community to
posals and measures such as the 1956 Land Act (Ley decide who may benefit from the right to develop
del Suelo). This Act and its 1976 modifications suc- land (Clusa and Mur, 2007: 122–136; Roca, 2007).
ceeded in introducing a land readjustment regulation In García-Bellido’s (1994) proposal, the community
(Reparcelación). The regulation makes profiting from may directly provide the infrastructure and build on
the betterment conditional on providing infrastructure. the serviced parcels, and thus benefit from using or
According to the regulation, landowners must pay for selling the buildings. Alternatively, the community
and provide the infrastructure, and, as compensation, may allocate this development right to a private
they share the resulting serviced building plots. As party. Landowners have only the right to the non-
such, they can build on these plots or sell them to urban use of the land, for example for agriculture.
developers. Initially, however, the regulation failed to In the early 1990s the regional government of
provide good-quality public infrastructure on a suffi- Valencia was willing to tackle the lack of free competi-
cient scale (Bassols, 1996; García-Bellido, interview tion in urban development. The proposal of García-
in 2005; Menéndez, 1996). Bellido influenced the preparation of the new Valencian

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


66 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

planning law. Even though each Spanish region has its Analysis of power relations in urban
own planning legislation, the 1978 Spanish constitu- development
tion mandates the central government in Madrid to
equally protect the property rights of all Spaniards. As discussed above, the separation of development
That is, the central government has the responsibility rights from property rights is considered causally
to protect what is considered the ‘essential contents’ of related to public value capturing. This paper analy-
property rights.1 This translates into exclusive compe- ses this supposed causal relationship by developing
tences of the central government on, for example, leg- a model. This model is based on the concepts of
islation on expropriation and the economic appraisal of power, rules, resources and dependence (explained
properties; competences that are thus not transferable in the ‘Power and the role of public bodies in policy
to the regions. According to national planning law, the networks’ section and in a similar model by Verhage,
right to build belongs to the essential contents. As a 2002: 161). The model analyses the power relations
result, regional legislation is not allowed to deny a among public bodies and landowners/developers,
landowner the right to build, as envisaged in García- and hence the resulting public value capturing, in
Bellido’s proposal. The 1994 Valencian Planning Act each of the five transactions in the urban develop-
(Ley Reguladora de la Actividad Urbanística – LRAU), ment process: (1) land assembling (obtaining all the
however, devised an alternative to Garcia-Bellido’s pro- required land); (2) financing of transaction 1 and 3;
posal that still tackles the lack of free competition. (3) land preparation and development (i.e. infrastruc-
The 1994 Act’s alternative was to modify the land ture provision, which ultimately results in serviced
readjustment regulation and to reintroduce the figure building plots); (4) land disposition of serviced
of the ‘urbanising agent’. A 1976 legal reform had building plots; and (5) building on the serviced build-
already introduced this agent, inspired by the ideas of ing plots (Alexander, 2001).
urbanisme concerté in the 1973 French legal reform. With this model I analysed which actor controls
According to the 1976 Spanish reform, public bodies each of these transactions and thereby discerned the
could select through a public tender an urbanising influence that public law exercises on property rights
agent that would provide the infrastructure without and on dependence patterns. For example, if public
necessarily owning the land. However, the reform law grants the landowner the exclusive right to develop
was not effective because the agent had no security in the land, the landowner actually controls the resource
relation to the acquisition of land needed for the pub- ‘land’. This means that public bodies are dependent on
lic infrastructure nor the money to pay for this infra- the landowner to assemble the land (transaction 1).
structure. The 1994 Valencian Act resolved this by Public law might also give public bodies the right to
specifying land readjustment and, if necessary, com- expropriate the land, but if this right is qualified by
pulsory land readjustment as the default procedure. many conditions and guarantees, such as prescribing
As a consequence, urbanising agents can now be high compensation sums, then public bodies remain,
selected by municipalities to provide the infrastruc- in practice, dependent upon landowners. The opposite
ture even if the agents do not own the land. The also holds true: as public law grants public bodies the
urbanising agent designs a land readjustment plan, exclusive right to approve the land use plan and to
which, after being approved by the municipality, issue the necessary permits, public bodies then actu-
gives the agent powers to oblige landowners to pro- ally control the resource ‘land use plan and permits’.
vide the land and pay the costs of infrastructure. As a consequence, landowners/developers depend on
After this is done, the urbanising agent provides the public bodies to prepare and to develop the land (trans-
infrastructure, transfers the public infrastructure to action 3) and to build (transaction 5). In short, public
the municipality, and hands over the serviced build- law leads to a dependency between public and private
ing plots to the landowners. In the last several years, parties, a dependency that strongly influences the
this Valencian innovation has been introduced in negotiations between municipalities and the private
almost all regions of Spain. parties, and thus public value capturing.

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 67

Following exploratory studies in France, Germany, readjustment regulation (Reparcelación) permits a


Sweden, Italy, Flanders (a region of Belgium), higher recovery of costs, does not imply a direct finan-
Denmark, England, Valencia (a region of Spain) and cial and organisational involvement by the municipal-
the Netherlands, it became clear that these countries ity and is used more often.
did not significantly differ with regard to transactions
4 and 5. In all of these countries, development rights
belong to the landowner, i.e. landowners have the Method and data
unique prerogative to build on their land. This also
holds true for the UK, where the 1947 nationalisation This research focuses on several variables to dis-
did not modify this right: development rights cern whether public law limitations to property
remained attached to the land, i.e. developers had to rights – such as the land readjustment regulation
acquire the land to build on it (Cullingworth and (the independent variable) – could contribute to
Nadin, 2006: 195–197). At the same time, in all these more effective public value capturing (the dependent
countries the landowner is limited in his right to variable). In the study, it was not possible to gather
undertake development: he does not have ‘minimum’ enough data for a statistical analysis that would iso-
building rights, and the building that he constructs late the relationship between the independent and
must comply with what the law and the zoning regu- the dependent variables. Considering this limitation,
lations prescribe for the plot. I made several methodological choices. First, I chose
However, with regard to transactions 1–3 (infra- to base the data gathering mainly on explorative
structure provision), it was possible to distinguish two research conducted in nine EU countries and on in-
groups of countries. In the first group (the Netherlands, depth research of several cases of urban regeneration
UK, France, Italy, Sweden for larger building schemes, in three countries: three cases in England, four cases
Flanders and Denmark), transactions depend on agree- in Spain (the region of Valencia) and four cases in
ment between the municipality and the landowners. the Netherlands.2 Second, to increase both the ‘internal
As a rule, if these parties do not agree, the only remain- validity’ of the findings (can the findings explain the
ing alternative for municipalities is to execute pre- studied cases?) and their ‘external validity’ (can the
emption, expropriation and/or a posteriori special tax findings be generalised to other cases?) I introduced
formulas. Such heavy-handed interventions have three groups of measures.
direct financial and organisational implications for The first group of measures consists of variants of
municipalities. For example, they may advance invest- the ‘method of difference’. All of them aim to tackle
ments (transaction 2) to purchase land (transaction 1) the risk of spurious third variables, and thus to
and to construct infrastructure (transaction 3), or they improve the internal validity of the findings:
may endure the risks of eventual delays and low
investment returns. Because these measures are both
heavy handed and politically sensitive, expropriation
Maintaining as similar a context as possible
and special taxes are not frequently used. To control for possible differences in the context of
In the second group (Valencia and Germany) the the cases, I applied two measures:
situation is different: municipalities can obtain the land
(transaction 1) and the money (transaction 2) needed • The examined countries had similar political,
for the infrastructure provision (transaction 3) without economic and social contexts (nine EU mem-
voluntary agreement. Through land readjustment – ber states: the UK, Spain, the Netherlands,
and, if needed, compulsory readjustment – Valencian Germany, France, Italy, Belgium, Denmark
and German municipalities can provide the infrastruc- and Sweden). I am aware of the large differ-
ture without having to depend on the landowner’s pas- ences between these countries, but they differ
sive or active collaboration. Compared with the less than other countries in Europe or other
German equivalent (Umlegung), the Valencian land continents.

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


68 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

• The cases also had to follow some key sim- developments in the real estate markets) occurred in
ilarities: all or most of the land had to be the Valencian region shortly before or after 1994, the
privately owned, land was needed to con- region provided a good opportunity to study the
struct public infrastructure, and an impor- effects of the changes in variable property rights on
tant economic betterment had to result from variable public value capturing.
re-zoning.

Checking for other variables


Maximising the variance in
I analysed not only the variable property rights but
the independent variable
also other variables that might be relevant for public
The countries and cases showing the broadest varia- value capturing. This led to the conclusion that in
tion in the independent variable of ‘property rights’ addition to property rights, ‘certainty’ is another
were selected to increase the chances of observing a independent variable that might also influence pub-
possible causal relationship with the dependent lic value capturing. Governments have statutory
variable of ‘public value capturing’ (Polit et al., powers to create certainty about future contributions
2001: 188–192): before the start of negotiations with property devel-
opers. Both in England and in the region of
• Of the nine countries, three were selected for Valencia, governments use these statutory powers to
in-depth research: Spain, the UK and the create certainty, whereas governments in the
Netherlands. I focused on the Spanish region Netherlands do not. Certainty strengthens the nego-
of Valencia because this region, with its land tiating position of public bodies and improves public
readjustment regulation, has a unique form of value capturing (Muñoz-Gielen and Tasan-Kok,
separation of infrastructure provision from 2010). This public intervention can also be consid-
property rights. The British planning system ered a network management tool – a network con-
is an appropriate case because of its unique stitution type of tool. For instance, when developers
nationalisation of development rights. I are informed in the early stages that they are likely to
focused on England because of the differ- face financial obligations, they can negotiate a lower
ences in planning law between the different price for the land with the landowner. If the develop-
British constituent countries. The Netherlands ers are uncertain when they agree on the price with
was selected because it was the starting point landowners, the developers might pay a price that
of my research. incorporates maximum profit margins. In other
• From the three countries chosen, I further words, certainty beforehand can lower land prices
selected the cases that showed innovative and thus provide sufficient financial leeway for the
features of the property rights variable. This developer’s contribution. If local authorities intro-
selection was aided by the invaluable assis- duce new obligations too late, the developer may not
tance of local experts and professionals have sufficient financial leeway left in his budget to
(Raga, Beltra, Cliff and Holden, interviews contribute (Campbell et al., 2000: 769–771; Rowan-
in 2006 and 2007). Robinson and Lloyd, 1988: 128–130). Also, cer-
tainty strengthens the policy base for public officers
to request contributions.
Repeated measurement In addition, I systematically checked a list of pos-
As highlighted above, the 1994 Valencian Act modi- sible third spurious variables in every case: the per-
fied the variable property rights because it effectively sonal circumstances of those involved, political
separated infrastructure provision from land owner- circumstances and market prices of real estate. For
ship. As no major changes in the context (potential example, I analysed market prices to assess whether
third spurious variables such as culture, public poli- differences in public value capturing could be related
cies, financial situation of the municipalities and more to profit margins of developers than to the

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 69

Table 1.  Selected urban regeneration cases in England, Spain (region of Valencia) and the Netherlands.

Valencia England The Netherlands


Multifunctional central areas Guillem Temple Stationskwartier
Periodista
Monofunctional residential Guillem (*) Kruidenbuurt
areas Part of Benalúa
Old brownfield sites Periodista Megabowl Funen
Camino Harbourside Kop van Oost
Part of Benalúa
Multifunctional central areas are city/town downtown areas and sites around railway stations.
Monofunctional residential areas are districts with a predominantly residential use.
Old brownfield sites are derelict sites: business and other economic–industrial activities; gas and electricity factories; harbour areas;
railway infrastructure; and hospitals, government buildings and military sites.
(*) It was not possible to find a case in England that would fit this category.

variable property rights. This analysis enabled me to For example, supplementary sources are relevant for
explain why public bodies in England were able to determining the degree to which developers contrib-
secure higher contributions than public bodies in the ute to public infrastructure in their respective coun-
Netherlands despite the fact that public bodies in both tries (‘Remarkable differences in public value
countries do not have a land readjustment regulation at capturing’ section). The case-based data were sys-
their disposal (‘Other explanatory variables’ section). tematically compared with other available studies,
which are abundant in Spain and England but scarce
in the Netherlands, and with interviews with numer-
Applying a hypothetical–deductive method ous experts who assessed whether the case-based
Besides the measures based on the ‘method of dif- findings were representative (Lyon, Henneberry, van
ference’, another measure to increase the internal Wageningen, Stauttener, van Bladel and Segeren,
validity of the findings consisted of applying a hypo- interviews in 2007 and 2008).
thetical–deductive method to check the assumption
that separating infrastructure provision from prop-
erty rights improves public value capturing. The Representativeness of the countries
study’s findings confirmed this assumption. The cases of the Netherlands (a country that has a
After measures to increase the internal validity were more conservative profile in the property rights vari-
introduced, another methodological risk, the risk of the able, similar to a certain extent to Germany, France,
case studies being exceptional cases, had to be addressed Italy, Belgium, Denmark and Sweden), and those of
to increase the external validity of the findings. England and Valencia (which have clear exceptional
Therefore, a third group of measures was employed: features) cover the widest variance possible of the
different values of the variable property rights in the
Representativeness of the cases nine countries studied. This increases the chances
I selected cases that are representative of the main that other countries have characteristics that fall
types of urban regeneration projects in the respective within those of any of the three selected countries,
countries (Table 1). i.e. the chances that the selected countries are repre-
sentative of other countries.
The following section presents the evidence from
Supplementary sources the studied countries and employs the dependence
I systematically compared the case-based findings model developed in the ‘Analysis of power relations
with supplementary sources (publications and expert in urban development’ section to demonstrate how
interviews) to assess their degree of external validity. property rights influence public value capturing.

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


70 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

Table 2.  Dependence analysis of the English, Dutch and Valencian (before 1994) cases.

Dependence because of land Dependence because of Dependence because of


investment capacity regulatory resources
Local public Developer/landowner owns The developers are able  
body depends on the land. Dependence is to invest in buying the
the landowner/ only avoidable through land and developing
developer expropriation, but this is it. Dependence is not
used only in exceptional avoidable because local
circumstances. Expropriation public bodies are not
is considered slow, expensive willing to invest. Only in the
and risky. In the Netherlands Dutch case of Breda was
‘self realisation right’ gives the municipality ready to
preference to landowners assume some financial risks
Landowner/ The public bodies grant the
developer depends required permissions (and in
on the local public the Netherlands and Valencia
body approve the land use plan).
Dependence is not avoidable

Findings from urban regeneration use a land readjustment regulation, this regulation
in England,Valencia and the relied on the support and active collaboration of
the owners of at least 60% of the land. Although it
Netherlands was theoretically possible to force land readjust-
ment and hence avoid dependence, this required
Differences in dependence between direct involvement of the municipality, so it did not
public and private actors happen often.
The exploratory research in the ‘Analysis of power The situation in Valencia has changed since
relations in urban development’ section showed that 1994. Valencian municipalities can now opt for
the nine countries that were studied differ in the pro- compulsory land readjustment without having to
cess of infrastructure provision, which in Spain and become directly involved. Through a public tender,
Germany is under public control. The detailed case the municipality can select an urbanising agent to
research in England, Valencia and the Netherlands provide the infrastructure. This agent can be a pub-
confirmed that in England and the Netherlands lic company, the landowners themselves formally
providing infrastructure depends on agreements joined in a company, or, as is most often the case, a
because none of the actors controls all of the neces- commercial developer or construction company that
sary resources, resulting in a strong mutual depen- owns a share of the land. Landowners can choose to
dence (Table 2). Without a voluntary agreement, either opt for voluntary expropriation or participate
Dutch and English municipalities have no alterna- in the development. If they choose expropriation,
tive but to expropriate or to buy the land and to con- the urbanising agent pays the compensation and
struct the infrastructure, i.e. they are forced into acquires the land. Expropriation sums are, however,
direct organisational and financial involvement. not fully equivalent to the value of the land’s future
Expropriation has neither been applied in the stud- use. If the landowners decide to participate and sell
ied cases nor is it a commonly used instrument in the land once the infrastructure has been provided,
these countries. they can secure a higher profit. However, in adopting
Before the 1994 Act, the situation in Valencia this method, landowners have to deliver their land
was similar to the situations in England and the and pay the urbanising agent a proportional share of
Netherlands. Even though municipalities could the infrastructure provision costs. In exchange, they

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 71

receive the serviced building parcels, while the contributions and, in addition, they introduced cost-
municipality receives the public infrastructure. saving changes in the quality of the public space
Furthermore, the municipalities are not dependent (Buitelaar et al., 2008: 113–114). The municipality
on the urbanising agent, which can be selected accepted these terms because it was in a hurry to
through a public tender and usually from several develop the site.
competing developers. Again, municipalities are Before the 1994 Act Valencian municipalities
not limited in their choice, as they can also select were similarly confronted with landowners and
parties that do not own the land. developers who were unwilling to agree with the
required contributions. This reluctance delayed
development and finally forced municipalities to
Dependence has a negative effect lower the contributions package to reach an agree-
on public value capturing ment. As a result, the development sites that were
If dependence exists and it is difficult to avoid, produced were large enough only to provide mini-
landowners can choose to wait, i.e. not to agree with mal infrastructure for several plots. Building
the municipality about the required contributions schemes included only the minimum packages of
package or not to agree about the land price with low-quality public infrastructure. Instead of fol-
another actor who wants to develop the land. lowing a plan with the most suitable parcelling,
Waiting may be the best economic option because a readjustment mostly followed the landowners’
delay in negotiations can increase the profits. property boundaries and interests (Baño, Blanc,
In the English and Dutch cases studied, public Escribano, Montiel, Muñoz, Cañellas, Roger and
bodies were often confronted with landowners/ Rubio, interviews in 2006 and 2007). A good exam-
developers who did not agree, so they had to lower ple of this flawed development is the urban periph-
the required contributions package to reach an ery in the city of Valencia at the end of the 1980s.
agreement. For example, in the English case of The effects are still visible today: large buildings
Harbourside,3 the developer protested the require- stand in the middle of deteriorated agricultural land
ment to construct 30% affordable housing. In without adequate public infrastructure to support
response, the local planning authority lowered them (Figure 2).
this requirement to 9%. These case-based findings The introduction of the 1994 Valencian Act has
are representative for England and the Netherlands had important consequences. Today there is no
(Buitelaar et al., 2008: 17, 94–96, 108–110, 112– mutual dependence in Valencia, and although com-
114; Brand and Hoekstra, interviews in 2008). pulsory readjustment is not common, it does play
A Dutch example is Kop van Oost4 where differ- an important role in dissuading landowners from
ent parties (the original landowner, an intermediary delaying development. The 1994 Act has also posi-
and a property developer) successively bought and tively affected public value capturing (Blanc, 1997;
sold interests in land, which increased the land price Modrego, 2000). Now when a developer submits a
and delayed the development. An ‘interest in land’ proposal and the municipality approves it, land-
might consist of, for example, land ownership or an owners must follow suit. As a consequence, both
optional right to buy and develop the land in the the quality and quantity of public infrastructure
future for a previously agreed price. The developer have improved, and both public and private invest-
who finally bought the land decided to delay redraft- ments have increased extraordinarily, which has
ing the plans (Buitelaar et al., 2008: 58; Segeren, accelerated urban development. In the Valencian
interview in 2008). During the process housing case of Guillem,5 neither the developer who first
prices significantly increased above inflation, which submitted a proposal and was finally selected as
made delaying an interesting economic option. It urbanising agent nor the other three developers sub-
seems that the option to wait also lowered public mitting alternative proposals initially owned any
value capturing: the developers made it clear to the land. The possibility of selecting a developer with-
municipality that there was little financial room for out land was a crucial factor in the Valencian case:

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


72 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

Figure 2.  Examples of buildings in the periphery of the city of Valencia constructed in the 1980s: (1) Orriols; (2)
Torrefiel (November 2006).

hundreds of individuals owned property but not all • Off-site public infrastructure: in England and
the owners would have agreed on a voluntary land Valencia developers contribute significantly.
readjustment. In the end, they had to accept the full In England this is done mostly by financial
contributions package and, as part of the tendering means and in Valencia primarily with land. In
procedure, the urbanising agent accepted to pay the Netherlands these contributions are rare.
additional contributions. • Creaming off added value: public bodies in
Valencia capture a significant share of the
enhanced economic value, even if they do not
Remarkable differences in own land. In England, public bodies do not
public value capturing officially profit, but with the broad definition
When comparing the three countries, several signifi- of developers’ off-site contributions, one might
cant differences emerge in public value capturing, conclude the contrary. In the Netherlands, this
which is the highest in Valencia after 1994, high in is the case only when public bodies own the
England but lower than Valencia, and the lowest in land and/or invests and shares the risks.
the Netherlands:
Financial feasibility as an alternative
• On-site infrastructure provision costs: in
England and Valencia these costs are mostly explanation for landowners/developers
or fully paid by the developers, whereas in the choosing to wait
Netherlands these costs are subsidised by the It has already been claimed that landowners and devel-
government. opers in England and the Netherlands might choose to
• Land for on-site public infrastructure: in stall development, with the expectation that longer
Valencia landowners provide all the land for negotiations will increase profits. However, develop-
free, whereas public bodies in England and ers often cite an alternative explanation: development
the Netherlands also provide part of the land. is often delayed or even completely halted because of
• Social/affordable housing: in England and unreasonably high municipal demands (Whitacker and
Valencia social/affordable housing is Fokkema, interviews in 2007). In this study, it was dif-
largely or almost completely paid by the ficult to empirically assess whether the requirements
developers, whereas in the Netherlands it is were indeed too high because information about devel-
primarily funded by municipalities and opment costs and profits is not public information.
housing associations. Table 3 summarises the costs, returns and the final

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 73

Table 3.  Costs, returns and balance of operations in urban regeneration.

1.   Accounted land costs The land price that the developer includes in the calculations
2.   Infrastructure provision costs Include not only the infrastructure provision works, but also reserved
amounts for unexpected expenses, overhead costs, potential ‘hidden’
profit margins of the developer, etc. In the Netherlands they comprise
Slopen, bouw en woonrijp maken, risico en onvoorzien. (demolition,
infrastructure provision, unforeseen expenses) They should also
include the financial costs (the costs of lending money to finance the
infrastructure provision costs)
3.   Plan preparation costs Includes the costs of the preparation of plans, studies, etc. (Plankosten, or
Voorbereiding, toezicht en planontwikkeling [plan preparation costs])
4.   Soil decontamination costs Includes the costs of decontaminating the land
5.   Compensation costs Includes compensation to existing owners and inhabitants for removal of
activities and residence, demolition of constructions and buildings, etc.
6.   Contributions Includes the contributions, in cash or in kind (i.e. facilities and buildings)
to public goals: payments, construction of public infrastructure or public
buildings, etc. Excludes on-site public spaces and roads (even if they
serve a wider area than the development in question), which are already
included in (2) Infrastructure provision costs.
7.  Real estate development Includes the entire development of the real estate; thus not only the
costs construction costs, but also the preparation of plans, overhead costs,
possible ‘hidden’ profit margins of the developer, etc.
8.  Total returns Includes the total returns accruing from the sale of the real estate
(office, dwellings, etc.)
9.   Developer’s final profit Regards the profits of the final developer, which is equal to the total
returns (8) minus the sum of the other categories above (1–7), and is in
addition to any potential ‘hidden’ profit included in the categories above

balance associated with a site’s regeneration. In the the expected profit than on the objective financial fea-
Dutch cases, the developers claimed that their final sibility of the project. For example, the contributions
profit margins were quite narrow. For example, in Kop in Megabowl6 were high thanks to a relatively low
van Oost, they estimated only €2 million in profit. accounted land cost (€3–4.5 million). This is due to
However, according to my estimates, it was dramati- an exceptional circumstance: there was uncertainty
cally higher – up to €29 million, indicating that there regarding building possibilities on the site, which dis-
was room for higher contributions. In short, it is not couraged developers from purchasing the site in the
clear in the Dutch cases whether developers waited years prior to development. This lowered the land-
because they needed to or because they wanted to owner’s land price expectations, which made it pos-
increase their final profit. Finally, how can one explain sible for the developer to contribute more than usual.
that in the Valencian cases the financial feasibility of
operations was not a problem even though the contri-
butions were much larger than in the Netherlands? Differences in costs of infrastructure
According to my calculations, the profit margins provision and plan preparation
in the English cases were larger than those in the Costs for infrastructure provision and plan prepara-
Dutch cases and allowed for greater contributions. In tion seem to greatly differ between the countries
England, resistance or acceptance of the requirements (Table 4). These costs were highest in the Dutch
was based more on both the expected land price (how cases: €438 in Kruidenbuurt and €368 in Kop van
much the initial landowner or the developer who Oost per square metre of new public space;7 and,
bought the land expected to receive for the land, due to exceptional circumstances, even higher in
which translates into the accounted land costs) and Stationskwartier (€1212). In the English cases costs

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


74 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

Table 4.  Comparison development costs in the Dutch, English and Valencian cases.

Dutch cases Three additional English cases Valencian cases


Dutch cases,
expert opinion

  Kruid KvO Stati One Two Three Mega Temp Harb Guill Period Camin Benal
2.  Infrastructure 438 368 1212 249 222 94 153 269 332 77 418 85 75
provision costs
(€/m2 new public space)
3.  Plan preparation 102  61 24 17 269 18 19
costs
(€/m2 new public space)
In the Dutch case Stationskwartier, the €1212/m2 also includes accounted land, soil decontamination and compensation costs.
In the English case Megabowl, the €153/m2 also includes soil decontamination and compensation costs.

were also high: €153, €269 and €332. In the Valencian • Delay and the corresponding uncertainties
cases they were the lowest: €94, €693, €103 and €94. increase the associated risks, which, in turn,
The extraordinarily high figure for the second case is translate into higher infrastructure provision
not representative of the entire Valencian region, but costs. For example, the developer may allocate
the other three are (Fernández and Fernández, 2002: higher reserve lines for unforeseen expenses,
68–74; Raga, interview in 2008). and delay may also increase the financial costs.
By analysing three additional recent urban regen-
eration projects, two Dutch experts confirmed the
generalisability of the figures from the Dutch cases. Inflationary effect of waiting on land prices
Infrastructure provision and plan preparation costs Landowners can opt to wait before agreeing to sell
amounted to €352 in Project 1 and €283 in Project 2. or to develop, and this gives them a strong negotiat-
In Project 3, the costs were lower (€118), which sug- ing position. Therefore, parties are more interested
gests that costs can sometimes be similar in the in acquiring land, which, in turn, results in more par-
Netherlands and in Valencia (Stauttener and Van ties competing with each other to acquire the land
Bladel, interviews 2008). and this competition increases land price. The find-
A possible explanation for the high costs of infra- ings in the Dutch cases suggest that land prices
structure provision and plan preparation in the indeed increased. In De Funen, the landowner appar-
Netherlands and England is that when landowners/ ently sold the land to the developer for a significantly
developers exercise the option to wait, it has an higher price than the price he bought it for. In Kop
inflationary effect: van Oost, the estimated market value of the previous
use (industrial land) was about €3.6 million, but the
• Delays usually bring additional activities land was sold for around €12 million.
(studies, meetings, etc.) and thus increase the
plan preparation costs. In the Dutch Projects 1
and 2, plan preparation costs were €102 and Other explanatory variables
€61, respectively. In the Valencian cases, they Even though landowners in both England and the
were about €18. Unfortunately, it was not Netherlands have the option to wait before selling or
possible to specify these costs for the other developing their land, England has better public
Dutch and English cases. value capturing. Two variables other than the option

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 75

to wait might explain this. First, when the data were with reduced steering powers. Through the land read-
gathered, housing prices in the English cases were justment regulation, municipalities in Valencia can
significantly higher (€3000–5000 per square metre select their preferred developer, avoid long negotia-
of floor space and even higher) than prices in tions and force infrastructure provision. In addition,
Valencia and in the Netherlands (about €2000–3000 these powers can lower land prices and land develop-
in both countries). This could explain why English ment costs, thus leaving a larger leeway for develop-
developers offered more generous contributions than ers to contribute. In the Netherlands, public bodies do
their Dutch counterparts did, but it does not explain not have any land readjustment regulation at their
why English developers offered fewer contributions disposal and thus have a weaker position that makes
than their Valencian counterparts. Second, in the it difficult for them to steer urban regeneration. This
early stages of development processes (before nego- weaker position ultimately results in their subsidising
tiations take place), there is high certainty in England of public infrastructure. In England, public bodies
regarding the obligatory contributions, but not in the also have a weak position. However, by using their
Netherlands. This certainty seems to lower land regulatory powers to create certainty about future
prices and to strengthen the negotiating position of contributions, and as a result of higher real estate
English municipalities (see ‘Checking for other vari- prices, English public bodies manage to obtain far
ables’ and Muñoz-Gielen and Tasan-Kok, 2010). more contributions than Dutch public bodies, despite
the contributions remaining lower than those in
Valencia.
The findings in this study undermine the basic
Conclusions
theoretical assumption of the policy network approach
This research sought to provide empirical evidence that public bodies must assume a more modest role
to contribute to the debates about urban governance and cannot be dominant in policy making and imple-
and the separation of development rights from prop- mentation. The policy network approach has failed to
erty rights in land. One particular type of network sufficiently demonstrate that dependence of the gov-
management tool, the Valencian land readjustment ernment on private actors is inevitable and that private
regulation, takes away the control of infrastructure actors have unavoidable veto powers in policy mak-
provision from landowners and, in so doing, modi- ing and implementation. In Valencia, public bodies
fies the public–private power relationship in such a can efficiently avoid this veto power and thus avoid
way that public value capturing improves. A second mutual public–private dependency through compul-
network management tool that seems to improve sory land readjustment. Many advocates of the policy
public value capturing is the English and Valencian network approach come from the Netherlands, but the
governments’ use of regulatory powers to create cer- nature of the power relationship between public and
tainty about future contributions (Muñoz-Gielen and private actors in this country should neither be taken
Tasan-Kok, 2010). for granted nor be viewed as an inevitable departing
Thanks to the land readjustment regulation, public point for drafting theories and policies as the policy
bodies in Valencia play a role that clearly fits more network approach does.
within the advocated role of public bodies in the tra- The findings also support the idea that when
ditional interorganisational approach than in the pol- public bodies pursue the production of urban space
icy network approach. In Valencia, public bodies and housing through the involvement of landowners
assert themselves as the only authority structure to and commercial developers, then property law
plan and to guide the urban redevelopment process should be a matter not only of rights but also of obli-
and not as a mediator that only guides interactions gations. I agree with Hong and Needham (2007:
and provides opportunities. This situation is the xv–xix), who state that land readjustment is an
opposite to that in the Netherlands and England, alternative solution to problems with traditional
where the absence of this tool leaves public bodies forms of land assembly (voluntary exchange or

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


76 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

expropriation). However, the findings in Valencia Funding


highlight the weaknesses of land readjustment by This study was supported by the Dutch government
demonstrating that effective enforcement mecha- (Habiforum Program Innovative Land Use) and Delft
nisms are needed to prevent landowners from University of Technology (Delft Centre for the Sustainable
engaging in speculative actions. Urban Areas).
Regarding the Dutch debate, the findings coin-
cide with the position of Priemus and Louw, who Notes
argue that the increase in private control of the land 1. The ‘essential contents’ of property rights in land could
since the 1990s has inflated land prices and impov- be identified, grosso modo, with what in the Anglo-
erished public infrastructure. Another discussion Saxon legal tradition is called the minimal ‘bundle of
topic is whether municipalities can satisfactorily rights’ that someone has to own to be regarded as the
achieve their public goals using the current instru- owner (cf. Needham, 2006, 34–35, 38–40).
ments of public and private law. In this discussion, 2. The study of the three English urban regeneration
the concept ‘satisfactorily’ has not been clearly projects was conducted in the summer of 2007 in the
defined. As a consequence, it is not possible to city of Bristol: ‘Harbourside/Canon’s Marsh’ (7.8 ha),
assess whether public law in the Netherlands ‘Temple Quay’ (7.4 ha) and ‘Megabowl’ (1.3 ha). Of
results in ‘satisfactorily accomplished’ public the four Valencian projects three are located in the city
of Valencia (‘Guillem de Anglesola’ (1.2 ha),
goals. However, it is possible to conclude that a
‘Periodista Gil Sumbiela’ (0.6 ha) and ‘Camino
land readjustment regulation can significantly Hondo del Grao’ (5.7 ha)) and one in the city of
improve public value capturing and accelerate Alicante (‘Benalúa Sur’, 8 ha). All were studied in the
urban development. Because the Dutch 2008 winter of 2006–2007. The four Dutch cases are
Development Contributions Act (Grondex­ located in the cities of Amsterdam (‘De Funen’, 8 ha,
ploitatiewet) has neither introduced such a regula- studied in the winter of 2004–2005), Eindhoven
tion nor substantially modified the dependence (‘Kruidenbuurt Noord’, 17 ha, studied in the winter of
relationship between public bodies and landown- 2007–2008), Groningen (‘Kop van Oost’, 5 ha, stud-
ers, it will probably not substantively improve pub- ied in the winter of 2007–2008) and Breda
lic value capturing. (‘Stationskwartier’, 16 ha, studied in the winter of
Regarding the Spanish debate, the findings sup- 2007–2008). The most relevant data were updated in
the spring and summer of 2010.
port the critical approach of García-Bellido and oth-
3. The English case of ‘Harbourside/Canon’s Marsh’
ers. In a context of privately owned land and in the (7.8 ha) is the last and largest part of the regeneration
absence of public subsidies, breaking the monopolis- of the former dockland and was mostly flat before
tic/oligopolistic position of landowners is the only redevelopment. In 1999, a developer submitted the
way of assuring good quality and adequate quantity first application, which was rejected; the second one
of public infrastructure. was also unsuccessful. In 2001, the third application
In conclusion, the current economic crisis has was successful, and planning permission was formally
already negatively affected public value capturing granted in 2003 after negotiations under Section 106
and construction rates. Owing to decreases in real ended with the signing of a development agreement.
estate prices, the developer’s final profits are Initially, 60% of the land was privately owned, and the
diminishing, which makes it even more difficult rest was owned by the city council of Bristol. Work on
infrastructure provision commenced in 2004. By June
for developers to contribute to public infrastruc-
2007 more than half of the development had been
ture, and thus forces delays on urban projects. This delivered or was under construction; from the 700
further emphasises the need to lower the costs of apartments, 44,000 m2 office space and 30,000 m2 lei-
obtaining the land, providing the infrastructure sure space, the first buildings were already occupied
and preparing the plans. This paper argues that and in use at this time.
lowering these costs can be achieved by modifying 4. The site in the Dutch case ‘Kop van Oost’ (5 ha,
property rights through a land readjustment Groningen) was no longer in use, and 60% of the land
regulation. was owned by the former user, a wood-processing

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


Muñoz-Gielen 77

company. In 2000, an intermediary commissioned by Bassols CM (1996) El derecho urbanístico de la Restau-


a commercial developer negotiated with the land- ración a la II República (1876–1936): crisis de los
owner and most probably acquired an interest in land. Ensanches y las dificultades para alumbrar un nuevo
After negotiating general development terms with the modelo jurídico-urbanístico. Ciudad y Territorio-
municipality, the interest was resold to another devel-
Estudios Territoriales 107–108: 53–90.
oper in 2002. Negotiations with the second developer
Blanc CF (1997) Los efectos de la LRAU sobre la activi-
formalised into a development agreement in 2005.
The plan was definitively approved in 2006; it includes dad urbanizadora: causas y consecuencias de una
430 dwellings, most of them apartments, and about transformación. Ciudad y Territorio-Estudios Territo-
4,000 m2 of commercial space. As of 2010, none of the riales 29: 257–294.
apartments were finished. Buitelaar E, Segeren A and Kronberger P (2008) Stedeli-
5. Regeneration in the Valencian case ‘Guillem de jke transformatie en grondeigendom. Den Haag: Rui-
Anglesola’ (1.2 ha, Valencia) included the demolition mtelijk Planbureau/Nai uitgevers, p.61.
of old and decrepit housing owned by hundreds of dif- Campbell H, Ellis H, Henneberry J, et al. (2000) Planning
ferent owners and the construction of a main road obligations, planning practice, and land-use outcomes.
flanked by about 125 new apartments. In 1999, a com- Environmental and Planning B: Planning and Design
mercial developer submitted a proposal and in 2005
27: 759–775.
was formally selected as the urbanising agent after a
Canoy M and Van Ewijk C (1999) De Grondwolf bijt niet.
public tender, negotiations and the signing of a devel-
opment agreement. While the developer had owned Economisch Statistische Berichten 84(4233): D24–D30.
almost none of the land in 1999, the developer had Cao L and Priemus H (2007) Spatial disparities and hous-
bought almost all of it by the end of the land readjust- ing market deregulation in the Randstad Region: a
ment procedure (May 2008). comparison with the San Francisco Bay Area. Euro-
6. The English case ‘Megabowl’ (1.3 ha) is relatively pean Urban and Regional Studies 14: 362–381.
isolated from the rest of the city. Before redevelop- Clusa J and Mur S (2007) La experiencia británica 1973–
ment the site was used as a bowling alley and there 2006 de JGB y el pago de una deuda pendiente. ACE
was no zoning plan for the regeneration of the site. In Architecture, City and Environment 3: 122–149.
2006, the landowner submitted an application for Cullingworth JB and Nadin V (2006) Town & Country
regeneration into 184 apartments and, after obtaining
Planning in the UK. 14th ed. London: Routledge, p.624.
provisional approval at the end of that year, the land-
Department for Communities and Local Government
owner sold the site to a commercial developer. In
2007, negotiations ended with the signing of a devel- (2010) The Community Infrastructure Levy: An Over-
opment agreement. Infrastructure provision started in view. London: DCLG Publications.
2007, but as of 2010 the building was not completed. Elias N (1971) Wat is sociologie? Utrecht: Het Spectrum.
7. New public space is the surface area that is redevel- Fernández FGR and Fernández MP (2002) Balance actual
oped and is allocated for public use. Most of the costs del modelo urbanístico valenciano. Apuntes para un
are related to the construction of public infrastructure análisis propositivo. Revista de derecho urbanístico y
above or under this surface. medio ambiente 36(193): 59–82.
García-Bellido J (1989) Hacia una renovación de la racio-
References nalidad urbanística. Ciudad y Territorio-Estudios Ter-
ritoriales 81–82: 167–222.
Alexander ER (2001) A transaction–cost theory of land García-Bellido J (1991) Perspectiva ilustrada sobre el con-
use planning and development control. Town Planning tenido urbanístico de la propiedad ante la Ley 8/90 de
Review 72: 45–75. Reforma de la del Suelo. In Colegio de Arquitectos
Alterman R (2009) Can the ‘unearned increment’ in land (ed): Ley de reforma del regimen urbanístico y valor-
values be harnessed to supply affordable housing? In: aciones del suelo. Alicante: Colegio Oficial de Arqui-
Paper in conference ‘Financing affordable housing tectos de la Comunidad Valenciana, Delegación de
and infrastructure in cities: towards innovative land Alicante, pp.67–127.
and property taxation system’, UN Habitat GLTN, García-Bellido J (1994) Configuración de la ‘propiedad
Warsaw, 15–16 October 2009. desagregada’: dualidad de derechos en la propiedad

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016


78 European Urban and Regional Studies 21(1)

inmobiliaria. Revista de Derecho Urbanístico (1st part) Oxley M (2006) The gain from the planning-gain supple-
138: 547–634, and (2nd part) 139: 793–884. ment: a consideration of the proposal for a new tax to
Geuting E (2011) Marktstructurering als ruimtelijke boost housing supply in the UK. European Journal of
ordeningsinstrument: Verkenning van drie rechtsar- Housing Policy 6: 101–113.
rangementen in de woningbouwmarkt. Enschede: Parejo AL (1993) Reflexiones sobre la situación actual
Esther Geuting. y las posibles líneas de reforma del ordenamiento
Giddens A (1984) The Constitution of Society: Outline of urbanístico. Ciudad y Territorio-Estudios Territoria-
the Theory of Structuration. Cambridge: Polity Press. les 95–96: 231–243.
Hong YH and Needham B (eds) (2007) Analyzing Land Polit DF, Beck CT and Hungler BP (2001) Nursing
Readjustment: Economics, Law, and Collective Action. Research: Methods, Appraisal, and Utilization. 5th ed.
Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Philadelphia, PA: Lippincott Williams and Wilkins.
Kickert WJM, Klijn EH and Koppenjan JFM (eds) (1997) Priemus H (1996) Recent changes in the social rented sec-
Managing Complex Networks. SAGE: London. tor in the Netherlands. Urban Studies 33: 1891–1908.
Klijn EH (1997) Policy networks: an overview. In: Priemus H and Louw E (2000) Gemeentelijk grondbeleid.
Kickert W, Klijn E-H and Koppenjan JFM (eds) Man- Regiefunctie bij de realisatie van ruimtelijk beleid.
aging Complex Networks: Strategies for the Public Delft: Delft University Press.
Sector. London: SAGE, pp.14–34. Priemus H and Louw E (2003) Changes in Dutch land pol-
Klijn EH and Koppenjan JFM (2000) Public manage- icy: from monopoly towards competition in the build-
ment and policy networks: foundations of a network ing market. Environment and Planning B: Planning
approach to governance. Public Management Review and Design 30: 369–378.
2: 135–158. Roca CJ (2007) García-Bellido y la renovación del
Koffijberg J (2005) Getijden van beleid: Omslagpunten paradigma urbano. Post-escriptum a la Propiedad
in de volkshuisvesting. Over de rol van hiërarchie en Desagregada. ACE Architecture, City and Environ-
netwerken bij grote veranderingen. PhD Thesis, Delft ment 3: 160–169.
University Press, The Netherlands. Rowan-Robinson J and Lloyd G (1988) Land Develop-
Korthals-Altes W and Groetelaers D (2000) De ontwik- ment and the Infrastructure Lottery. Edinburgh: T&T
keling van uitbreidingslocaties: context en praktijk. Clark Ltd.
Acthergrondinformatie mededelingenblad van de Scharpf FW (1978) Interorganisational policy studies:
Vereniging van Grondbedrijven 18: 35–45. issues, concepts and perspectives. In: Hanf KI and
Menéndez RA (1996) Constitución y democracia: 1976– Scharpf FW (eds) Interorganisational Policy Making:
1996. La segunda reforma de la Ley del Suelo. Ciudad Limits to Coordination and Central Control. London:
y Territorio-Estudios Territoriales 107–108: 127–148. SAGE, pp.345–370.
Modrego CF (2000) Cuarenta meses de aplicación de Smith JJ and Gihring TA (2006) Financing transit systems
la Ley Reguladora de la Actividad Urbanística de la through value capture. American Journal of Econom-
Comunicad Valenciana. Ciudad y Territorio-Estudios ics and Sociology 65: 751–786.
Territoriales 32: 11–28. Van De Krabben E and Needham B (2008) Land readjust-
Muñoz-Gielen D and Tasan-Kok T (2010) Flexibility in ment for value capturing: a new planning tool for urban
planning and the consequences for public value cap- redevelopment. Town Planning Review 79: 651–672.
turing in UK, Spain and the Netherlands. European Verhage R (2002) Local Policy for Housing Development,
Planning Studies 18: 1097–1131. European experiences. Hampshire: Ashgate.
Needham B (2006) Planning, Law and Economics: The Vrom-raad (2009) Grond voor kwaliteit. Voorstellen voor
Rules We Make for Using Land. London: Routledge, verbetering van overheidsregie op (binnen)stedelijke
p.178. ontwikkeling, Advise 070. The Hague: Vrom-raad.

Downloaded from eur.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on May 12, 2016

You might also like