You are on page 1of 21

Journal of International Management

10 (2004) 431 – 451

A coopetition perspective of MNC–host


government relations
Yadong Luo*
Department of Management, School of Business Administration, University of Miami, 417 Jenkins Building,
Miami, FL 33124, United States
Available online 3 October 2004

Abstract

Building on convergent insights of resource dependence and business political behavior, this
article attempts to develop a conceptual and typological framework of coopetition in which
cooperation and competition simultaneously coexist in the relationship between multinational
corporations (MNCs) and host governments. The coopetition view does not see the MNC–
government relationship (MGR) as dichotomous or as a continuum between cooperation and
competition but as a simultaneous, inclusive partnership containing cooperation and competition as
two separate yet interrelated continua. This article addresses why coopetition arises, what coopetition
constitutes, and how coopetition configures with environmental and organizational dynamics. It
offers a typology of coopetition that identifies MNCs involving varying cooperation and competition
(estranger, contender, partner, and integrator) and elucidates each identity’s political responses.
D 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Coopetition; MNC; Host government

1. Introduction

In the beginning of the twenty-first century, the nature of the relationship between
multinational corporations (MNCs) and host governments can perhaps be best described as
coopetition, that is, cooperation and competition simultaneously function in increasingly

* Tel.: +1 305 284 4003; fax: +1 305 284 3655.


E-mail address: yadong@miami.edu.

1075-4253/$ - see front matter D 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.intman.2004.08.004
432 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

interdependent MNC–government relations (MGRs). Cooperation reflects the elements of


mutual accommodation and collaboration, seeking joint payoffs and goal accomplishment
from their interdependent activities or resources. Competition reflects the elements of
bargaining or control and related conflicts, seeking private gains at the expense of the other
party’s interests. From a government’s viewpoint, increasing pressure of global
integration, heightened competition for inbound foreign direct investment (FDI),
decelerated economic growth, and stronger needs for upgrading economic structure all
encourage cooperation with MNCs. From an MNC’s viewpoint, foreign operations
increasingly depend on educational, technological, industrial, and financial structures built
by host governments. For MNCs, whether a host government provides a stable set of rules
for business players to act within and whether the rules can be adapted to changing
conditions become increasingly crucial for firm growth and international expansion.
However, the competition element remains in MGRs, mainly manifested in bargains and
controls for resources or market access, despite its decreasing significance in countries
with liberalized foreign investment policies.
The dominant MGR paradigm has been the bargaining model developed by Vernon
(1971) and further enriched by Behrman et al. (1975), Fagre and Wells (1982), Lecraw
(1984), Encarnation and Wells (1985), Poynter (1985), Kobrin (1982), Behrman and
Grosse (1990), and Brewer (1992), among others. Although it did not exclude all elements
of cooperation, this model assumed that MGRs were predominately conflictual and that
governmental intervention was an inverse function of an MNC’s bargaining power arising
from contributed resources. This model certainly sheds light on how MNCs and
governments compete for exploiting each other’s resources in pursuit of respective goals,
and accurately reflects the adversarial climate of the 1970s and 1980s. As the nature of
MGRs shifts toward more cooperative-complementary (Dunning, 1998), it, however,
becomes important to unveil the cooperative behavior required for relationship building
today.
We attempt here to develop a preliminary framework that can better unfold
simultaneous competition and cooperation between individual MNCs and host govern-
ments, reflecting interdependence in many strategic aspects—resource sharing, market
expansion, infrastructure development, industrial transformation, and economic growth.
We apply convergent insights of resource dependence and business political behavior
theories, supplemented by networking, social exchange, and bargaining power perspec-
tives, to demonstrate how coopetition occurs and how organizational behavior in
coopetition may vary. We offer a typology of coopetition that identifies MNCs involving
varying cooperation and competition (estranger, contender, partner, and integrator).
Finally, we address how cooperation and competition should be aligned with multilevel
environmental conditions (economic development, political stability, regulatory deter-
rence, and industrial growth) as well as with multifaced organizational dynamics (resource
complementarity, goal congruence, previous relationship, and strategic proactiveness).
Configuring properly with these variants has implications on the consequences of MGR
development. These variants are important contingencies that explain the circumstances in
which cooperation or competition becomes more salient and necessary. In sum, this article
deals with (1) what coopetition constitutes; (2) why coopetition occurs, (3) how various
MNCs typologically differ in coopetition and politically respond to coopetition; and (4)
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 433

where cooperation or competition changes. This paper addresses these issues with a focus
on MNCs in relation to emerging economy governments. MNCs are remarkably more
active in investing and operating in these markets than ever before. For many MNCs,
success depends on how they perform in these markets—which, in turn, depends to some
extent on their relationships with local governments.

2. Defining coopetition: concept and cause

2.1. Concepts and components

Political and economic events in the global economy, coupled with a new generation of
technological advances, have spawned a new scenario for MGRs and accentuated the
interdependence between MNCs and governments (Dunning, 1998; Stopford, 1994).
Coopetition is a reflection of such interdependence. According to Brandenburger and
Nalebuff’s (1996) seminal illustrations, coopetition exists when competition and
cooperation simultaneously occur in the course of relationship development between
two parties. Strategic interdependence between MNCs and governments contains both
bargaining and collaborating elements, with competitive as well as collaborative aims, vis-
à-vis each other, in resource sharing process. Competition is bargaining for respective
benefits and interests that are incompatible between a group of MNCs and a host country
government whereas cooperation is a joint effort for mutual gains. Cooperation and
competition coexist because MNCs and governments depend on each other’s resources
and supports but meanwhile they encounter conflicts arising from different goals and an
absence of mechanisms mitigating possible opportunism. Cooperation and competition are
simultaneously present where an MNC deals with a host government for numerous issues,
areas or projects at the same time, with some of these issues, areas or projects containing
more cooperative elements while others involving more competition.

2.2. Competition

Bargaining-based competition inevitably remains at all times because MNCs and


foreign governments are constrained by asymmetrical parameters in the decision-making
process. Some clashes of interest inescapably remain because economic and social goals
sought by governments are not always complementary with MNC interests (Daniels et al.,
2004). For instance, structural transformation in emerging economies may necessitate
institutional protection for industries that consume national scarce resources, perform in
the dual-track price systems (one state regulated and the other market determined), or
represent pillar sectors fundamental to social development and economic stability. This
protection will lead to a series of interference over investments undertaken by MNCs in
these industries. In the decision-making formula, MNCs seek to maximize risk-adjusted
net returns, which may discord with a host government’s optimization of social equity and
economic efficiency (Rugman and Verbeke, 1998).
MNCs and governments compete for input-, process-, and outcome-based resources.
They may bargain or control for such inputs as production factors (e.g., natural resources,
434 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

land rent, and local financing) and operational inputs (e.g., distribution, pricing,
information, and infrastructure access). Process-based competition concerns the power
of changing regulatory framework in a host country. This changeability indicates power
asymmetry in the competing process. When asymmetry emerges, FDI rules and policies
are likely to move in a direction desired by the party who holds a dominant bargaining
position (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994). Finally, outcome-based competition involves
bargains for immediate consequence (market/industry access), intermediate consequence
(local market expansion), and/or ultimate consequence (financial returns).

2.3. Cooperation

We argue that cooperation and competition are not opposite ends of a single continuum
but distinct yet interrelated separate dimensions that often simultaneously occur for a given
MNC that deals with the host government for various issues or projects. Cooperation is
gaining momentum in shaping MGRs, given heightened strategic interdependence
between MNCs and governments. This interdependence can create mutual synergies if
both parties cooperate. These expected mutual gains are crucial as they determine the
departure from cooperative or from competitive behaviors. Unlike competitive behaviors,
cooperative behaviors are not blinded to opportunities for realizing positive-sum benefits
through effective collaboration (Lado et al., 1997). In the presence of competition, each
seeks to control its own resources and uses this control to escalate its bargaining power. In
the presence of cooperation, each seeks to see resource complementarity so as to attain a
stronger reciprocal support from the counterpart. Both MNCs and governments today
better know conditions under which one may, or may not, be expected to contribute to the
other’s well-being (Dunning, 1998). Governments in emerging economies have made
progress in their knowledge and understanding not only of the costs and benefits of
different types of MNC activities, but also of the implications of being integrated into the
global economy, through actions taken by MNCs (Stopford, 1994).
MNCs and governments cooperate along four levels: Country-level internationaliza-
tion, Industry-level competitiveness, Firm-level capability, and Individual-level produc-
tivity. Governments depend on MNCs for linking national economies with the outside of
the world through various MNC activities. MNCs depend on this openness for more
efficient flows of production factors within their globally coordinated networks and better
leveraging a host country’s comparative advantages. At the industry level, superior
performance of MNCs in a host country requires strong competitive segments (factor
endowment, market demand, related and supporting industries), and they, in turn, can be
substantially framed by government policies such as interest rates, science and education,
infrastructure, taxation, antitrust regulation, and information technology. To governments,
MNCs may be an important force of improving a host country’s industrial environment
(e.g., Xerox helped China to build and upgrade the copy machine industry by establishing
the technical and quality standards and training local employees). They cooperate with
governments in developing sophisticated factors such as skilled workforce, scientific base,
and information industry and in consummating related and supporting industries such as
supply base and technological infrastructure. At the business level, MNCs and govern-
ments cooperate to improve business capabilities. Many emerging market governments
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 435

have offered numerous privileges, such as tax exemption, free land use, and local talent
recruitment to R&D centers built there by MNCs. Meanwhile, governments depend on
MNCs for bringing in technological and organizational skills. Finally, MNCs and
governments cooperate to enhance individual productivity. This is beneficial to MNCs
because improved productivity of workers, managers, designers, and engineers in a host
country increases organizational productivity and operational efficiency of firms, which
leads to cost reduction or revenue growth. From the government viewpoint, MNCs can
play a fundamental role in improving this productivity, especially through joint ventures or
alliances.
Growing interdependence between MNCs and governments has been heightened for
the following four reasons: First, many governments of emerging economies have been
attaching greater importance to the contemporary need for indigenous resources to be used
productively and allocated to best conform to the needs of increasing globalization. They
have steered away from imposing counterproductive actions on MNC activities that can
create social wealth. Second, deregulation and liberalization of national economies creates
a favorable atmosphere for developing MGRs. While this liberalization provides MNCs
with more opportunities, governments also depend on MNCs for helping upgrade the
newly opened sectors. Third, recent shifts of government policies facilitate cooperation.
These shifts include changing the regulatory emphasis from direct intervention to indirect
involvement, from central government interference to regional government (province,
state, or city) supervision, from policy rigidity to treatment flexibility, and from separation
from domestic policies to convergence with domestic policies. Lastly, cooperation is
spurred by heightened competition pressure for attracting inbound FDI among emerging
economies. This implies that the bargaining power of governments versus MNCs is
changing in favor of the latter (Strange, 1997) and that governments now come under
pressure to be more cooperative with MNCs if they want increased FDI inflows (Dunning,
1998).
We want to point out that the above trends do not mean the nonexistence today of MNC–
government conflicts nor suggest an absence of cooperation in the past (before the mid-
1980s). While realizing heightened cooperation at the overall level, we see ample evidence
showing the coexistence of cooperation and competition, as well as variations in
cooperation and competition among different firms and even same firms with different
time periods or dealing with different governments. Some MNCs (i.e., contenders in Fig. 1)
may confront more conflicts or stronger competition with a foreign government than
cooperation with it. We recognize that some cooperation elements also existed in the post-
war period. The main logic for MNCs to go abroad or for governments to use foreign capital
may not markedly change over the past decades, but the interdependence is growing.

3. Modeling coopetition: theory and typology

3.1. Theoretical foundation of coopetition

The coopetition view suggests that MGRs are a coopetition matrix in which
cooperation and competition simultaneously exist as two axes. MGRs are not
436 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

dichotomous, polarizing with pure forms of collaboration or conflict. Instead, there is


likely to be some form of simultaneous cooperation and competition in interactions
between an MNC and a host government. They cooperate in some aspects while
competing in other aspects. This simultaneity arises for two major reasons. First,
coopetition is underpinned by economic interdependence in which competition and
cooperation are naturally intertwined. Although specific firms have varying degrees of
competition as well as cooperation with a host government, absolutely pure competition or
cooperation does not exist in the real world (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996). Both an
MNC and a government must deal with diverse issues, giving rise to cooperation on some
issues or projects and competition on other issues or projects. MNCs and governments do
not share congruent interests in all aspects or at all times. Substantial differences on issues
such as transfer pricing, environment protection, allocation of export markets, and
deregulation of infant industries—not to mention those that are ideologically or culturally
sensitive—still remain. Second, unlike strategic alliances or joint ventures, MGRs are not
structurally organized nor legally contracted. The absence of this structure and codification
makes MGRs highly susceptible to changes of environments and respective needs.
The cooperation–competition dualism in MGRs is anchored in the resource dependence
perspective. Organizations are dependent, to varying degrees, on other organizations or
identifiable environmental components for reducing uncertainty or acquiring resources
(Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). Some organizations enter into interorganizational or
intersectional relationships because they are dependent on other organizations, and desire
to develop efficient and effective coping strategies for acquiring or allocating resources. If
business is highly dependent on resources that are mediated by government, then
managers may want to develop strategies that reduce the resource cost of governmental
intervention (Dowling and Shaeffer, 1982). An interorganizational strategy to deal with
government may then devise cooperative and competitive components based on the
perception of how organizational resources will be best conserved, acquired, or expanded
in the transaction. This dualism exists because MNCs and governments mutually depend
on each other and yet they have both cooperative and competitive aims underlying their
interdependence. Cooperative aims can nourish joint payoff creation through exploiting
complementary resources cooperatively. Meanwhile, competitive aims can breed conflicts
that may emerge when either party emphasizes its own gains from specific projects in
which respective needs are not compatible.
The cooperation and competition dualism is also underpinned by the network/alliance
theory. Success in today’s business world requires a syncretic rent-seeking behavior-
defined as a behavior that pursues both competitive and cooperative strategies
simultaneously (Lado et al., 1997). On the one hand, firms need to adopt repertoires of
behavior that support cooperation and trust building with stakeholders including
regulators. On the other hand, firms need to compete for competencies generated through
partnerships. This syncretic behavior emphasizes the positive-sum efficiency-enhancing
effects of competition and cooperation (Lado et al., 1997). MNCs can achieve competitive
advantages through leveraging their ownership-specific assets in the bargaining process
with governments. Meanwhile, they can achieve collaborative advantages by identifying
strategic opportunities for realizing positive-sum gains and making resource commitments
necessary to realize strategic goals of the partnership (Buckley and Casson, 1988). The
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 437

syncretic behavior is often performed on a long-term basis with designated stakeholders


(Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996; Lado et al., 1997), which accords with the fact that
MGRs are of a long-term orientation, especially in the context of emerging markets.
Cooperation increases or competition decreases if the ratio of private benefits to common
benefits perceived by managers decreases (Khanna et al., 1998). This logic applies to
MGRs where firms have both private goals (e.g., market leaders) and common goals (e.g.,
infrastructure advancement) as they deal with governments (Osland and Bjorkman, 1998).

3.2. Typology of coopetition

Degrees of competition and cooperation vary among individual MNCs. While some
MGRs reach high levels of both cooperation and competition, other MGRs may involve
high cooperation but low competition and vice versa. This variance leads to four types of
identifiers (estranger, contender, partner, and integrator) that reflect different arrays of
varying competition and cooperation in the coopetition matrix. MNCs under each identity
can choose from several political tactics, depending mainly on their intention and
bargaining power resulting from contributed resources. This typology is introduced from
the MNC perspective as we attempt to explicate some strategic responses that MNCs
should employ under different cooperation or competition circumstances. Noting that
some of terms for strategic responses used in this article are not new (e.g., Gladwin and
Walter used appeasement, accommodation, and compromise in 1980; Oliver used
challenge, influence, and compliance in 1990), this study nevertheless is among the first
to apply them in the coopetition setting.
An estranger is an MNC that is relatively distant from government involvement,
maintaining low competition as well as low cooperation with regulatory authorities. In this
type of relationship, MNC–government interdependency is low. In the context of an
emerging foreign market, this identity often exists in highly deregulated, labor-intensive
industries (e.g., toys and shoes) in which a host government does not significantly

Fig. 1. A typology of coopetition.


438 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

intervene in MNC activities and MNCs depend largely on their own resources. Kim (1988)
and Ring et al. (1990) demonstrate that corporate political responsiveness is linked to
industrial characteristics such as rivalry, regulation, and structure because improved MGRs
are used as a counterforce against competitive threats. An estranger runs its foreign
business in a relatively independent fashion, with no strong needs for governmentally
controlled resources defined as not only physical resources but also financial and
operational treatments stipulated in various government policies. A corresponding
governance mode may have low dependence on local resources and high integration
with the MNC’s own network (e.g., subcontracting, franchising, and wholly owned
subsidiaries). Such governance modes satisfy an estranger’s needs for transactions under
low market uncertainty and low regulatory stringency.
The political response of an estranger emphasizes either compliance or circumvention.
Compliance is conscious obedience to government regulations, rules, laws, and policies,
while circumvention is an organizational attempt to preclude the necessity of conformity
by maneuvering around governmental pressures or avoiding from governmental rules or
interventions (Oliver, 1991). Several institutional theorists have acknowledged the
importance of compliance as a response to institutional pressures. DiMaggio and Powell
(1983) and Pfeffer and Salancik (1978) suggest that an organization consciously and
strategically chooses to comply with institutional pressures in anticipation of specific self-
serving benefits that may range from social support to operation predictability. MNCs
opting for compliance are often those estrangers facing relatively simple, nondiscriminated
FDI rules that are embodied in the host country’s laws on domestic economic, procedural,
administrative, or civil legislation. They choose compliance because the costs of
complying with these laws are low and virtually same as those incurred by local
businesses. Circumvention is used by estranger MNCs whose resources suffice for
operational requirements in a deliberately selected market domain in which they are largely
free from government intervention after avoidance. Circumvention is possible because
estrangers are virtually self-sufficient and do not rely on governmentally controlled
resources.
A contender (or bargainer) is such an MNC that is vying with a host government for
local resources (including regulatory stances), maintaining high competition and low
cooperation with regulatory authorities. A contender MNC must depend on local resources
to fulfill its international expansion. These resources are controlled by local governments
and manifested in various forms such as input-based resources (e.g., natural resources, raw
materials, land use, local financing, and infrastructure access), process-based resources
(e.g., regulations), and outcome-based resources (e.g., market access and product
marketing). Since these resources are not limitless, a host government inevitably exerts
high control over their use. Moreover, the growth of local economy is strategically
bolstered by pillar industries using these resources (Porter, 1990). Bargains between
MNCs and governments become more combative if they compete for location-specific
resources that fuel host-country competitiveness (Moran, 1985). As natural resource
exploitation often adds less value to economic and social development than other FDI
activities, governmental attitude toward exploitation is likely to be less cooperative.
Further, local firms have grown up and dominated in the exploitation and utilization of
these resources. In fact, several emerging economies have recently formed local business
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 439

groups in respective resource sectors in a bid to better battle against foreign companies in
these sectors (Khanna and Palupe, 1997). This suggests that strategic interdependence
between contender MNCs and governments are asymmetrical, to the extent that the former
depend more on the latter than vice versa.
The political responses of contender MNCs include bargaining and challenging.
Resource dependence theorists assume that organizational relations with the environment
are open to negotiation and the exchange of concessions (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978, pp.
143–187). Bargaining tactics involve the effort of the organization to exact some
concessions from an external constituent in its demands or expectations (Oliver, 1991).
Although limited, a contender MNC’s bargaining power originates from its technological
and organizational capabilities that improve the efficiency of resource exploitation and
utilization. Challenging is a political tactic that contests regulatory requirements.
Institutional theorists suggest that organizations that challenge institutional pressures go
on the offensive in defiance of these pressures and may indeed make a virtue of their
insurrection (Scott, 1987). MNCs are more prone to challenge host governmental rules and
policies when they have greater bargaining power and their strategic goals in entering the
host country are short-term (Gladwin and Walter, 1980).
A partner (or ally) is an MNC that collaborates with a host government, maintaining
high cooperation and low competition with regulatory authorities. A partner relationship
exists when MNCs and governments have formed alliances or coalitions (e.g., in
infrastructure building), and when MNCs and governments depend highly on each other
without rigorously competing for host-country resources due to relatively compatible or
congruent interests (e.g., in high-tech development). In infrastructure sectors such as
power generation and transportation construction, MNCs and governments form partner-
ships through build–operate–transfer (BOT) or joint ventures. In high-tech sectors, MNCs
and governments cooperate like partners in the sense that the latter improve the investment
climate on which MNCs depend and the former diffuse innovation on which national
competitiveness depends. Although both depend on each other, an MNC’s bargaining
power and its underlying contributions are expected to be significantly high—to the point
that the host government will renounce some power in resource or market control and
would rather commit to synergy creation through the partnership (thus leading to low
competition). When MNC–government partnerships are not formally structured, inter-
dependence and mutual commitment hold the partnership together.
The political response of partner MNCs emphasizes accommodation, cooptation, or
adaptation. Accommodation refers to the extent to which an MNC has been responsive and
contributive to social needs or concerns (e.g., education, employment, training, pollution
control, research funding). Accommodation signals an MNC’s political commitment to
social needs, thus determining a level of reciprocation from governments (Gladwin and
Walter, 1980). From the government’s standpoint, an MNC’s political accommodation
shows its commitment to the host society, which, in turn, reduces its liability of
foreignness as perceived by officials and amplifies its credibility and legitimacy as
perceived by the public (Kostova and Zaheer, 1999).
Cooptation is about an MNC’s commitment to enhancing legitimacy or neutralizing
possible conflicts with governments (e.g., inviting a senior official as a board member or
chief consultant). Cooperation may be improved if one side coopts the other into adopting
440 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

each other’s goals (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983; Oliver, 1991). Mutual assimilation of
goals and attitudes becomes more likely when each side gains a greater understanding of
the other’s mission and behavior through various contacts. Cooperation arises when
mutual understanding, rather than mistrust, is at the root of the relationship (Stevens and
McGowan, 1983).
Adaptation is defined here as an MNC’s efforts to accept, mimic, and comply with the
host country’s social norms, standards, and practices including those for business culture.
Adaptation is the product of investment strategies consciously aimed at establishing or
reproducing social relationships with bureaucrats in power (Oliver, 1991). Partner MNCs
seek informal or social approaches such as network-based, personalized exchanges with
political institutions to better safeguard operations under uncertainty. As social exchange
theorists have stated, social ties can institutionally undergird market activities (Gran-
ovetter, 1985) and nourish cooperation.
Finally, an integrator is an MNC that mutually depends with a host government for
achieving respective goals, integrating high competition and high cooperation with
regulatory authorities. Contrary to partners, integrators do not necessarily share compatible
or convergent goals with local governments in all areas or projects, and they compete with
the latter for local resources. Goal differences create different imperatives for the MGR
interaction and interdependence (Dunning, 1995). In situations that involve the allocation
of limited resources, competition may be a natural and possibly inevitable result of
interaction (Dowling and Shaeffer, 1982). If all parties cannot be fully satisfied from the
stakes available, then there must necessarily be some elements of competition (Porter,
1990). An integrator relationship typically exists in newly opened but not yet completely
deregulated industries (e.g., telecom, automobile, pharmaceutical, Internet, insurance, and
banking) in which MNCs bargain with local governments for securing limited resources
(e.g., preferred financial treatments and local partner selection) and privileges (e.g., broad
scope of business or market and free investment modes). Since these industries are
generally more critical to the stability and prosperity of local economies than others,
governments still control industry access, market breadth, business activities, and financial
conditions. This control compels an MNC to use its bargaining power based on the
resources it can contribute to boost these emerging sectors (Osland and Bjorkman, 1998).
Integrator MNCs are more likely to choose joint ventures as the entry mode and partner
with local firms that have superior relations with government authorities. If FDI
regulations permit, they may opt for a majority equity status so as to exercise greater
control over joint venture activities. Thus, a joint venture mode may spur cooperation
while a majority ownership may nurture bargaining.
The political response of integrator MNCs emphasizes compromise or influence.
Compromise concerns appropriate balance of conflictual interests between governments
and MNCs (Gladwin and Walter, 1980). It represents organizational attempts to achieve
parity between regulatory requirements and an organization’s own interests (Oliver, 1991).
MNCs are prone to balance when they attach importance to long-term cooperation with
local governments that control critical resources on which MNCs must depend. When
governmental expectations conflict with organizational ones, an MNC’s interests may be
best served by obtaining an acceptable compromise on competing objectives and
expectations (Stopford and Strange, 1991).
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 441

Influence is a more active political response than compromise, which shapes


governmental policies and rules with which MNCs must comply (Stopford and Strange,
1991). MNCs can strategically influence or manipulate a host country’s regulatory
environment by some offensive measures such as corporate lobby, pressure from the home
government, and pressure from international economic organizations (e.g., WTO, IMF,
and World Bank). Whether an MNC should use compromise or influence depends on its
calculation of resource gains or losses resulted from different tactics and dyadic
differences in bargaining power. Influence may be used under conditions that an MNC
maintains high bargaining power and governments still gain from new regulatory
framework after this influence (Strange, 1997). Compromise seems advisable if MNCs and
governments depend on each other in long cooperation and both share a similar level of
bargaining power in competition.
This section offers a typology of coopetition. While we suggest a simultaneous
coexistence of cooperation and competition in the coopetition matrix, specific levels of
cooperation and competition with governments are not homogenous among MNCs, thus
resulting in four types of identities: estranger, contender, partner, and integrator (Fig. 1).
For highly diversified large MNCs with multiple subsidiaries (or projects) in a single host
country (e.g., Motorola in China), this typology can be used at the corporate level
(assessing the company’s overall cooperation and competition arrays with this govern-
ment) as well as at the subunit level (assessing the subsidiary’s specific cooperation and
competition with this government). The major parameter underlying this typology is an
MNC’s strategic need for, and its dependence on, resources that are controlled, regulated,
or mediated by local governments. In this typology, contender and estranger face relatively
low cooperation whereas partner and integrator encounter relatively high cooperation.
Similarly, estranger and partner confront relatively low competition, while contender and
integrator share relatively high competition. The foregoing political tactics identify the
repertoire of behaviors that different types of MNCs may exhibit in response to
governmental involvement and regulatory requirements. Estrangers emphasize compliance
or circumvention, while contenders focus on bargaining or challenging. Integrators
emphasize compromise or influence, while partners focus on accommodation, cooptation,
or adaptation. The theoretical rationale underlying these different strategies surrounds the
intention and ability of MNCs to shape regulatory frameworks.

4. Predicting coopetition: contingency and configuration

The resource dependence theory assumes that organizations vary in terms of the degree
of dependency on other organizations (e.g., government) or identifiable environmental
components (e.g., regulations) for reducing uncertainty or acquiring critical resources
(Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). We assume that MNCs seek their economic gains from the
relationships with local governments through leveraging degrees of cooperation and
competition with the latter. In other words, we assume that, from the MNC perspective,
cooperation and competition embedded in MGRs are not predetermined (fixed) but
variable such that degrees of cooperation and competition are arrayed optimally and cost-
efficiently to meet the firm’s needs. It does so through adjusting the level of cooperation or
442 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

competition to respond to environmental conditions (or contingencies in the resource


dependence theory). Aligning these contingencies properly with levels of cooperation and
competition is expected to determine whether a firm’s efforts in developing cooperation
and competition create net gains after subtracting costs for this development. This
alignment is needed in both ex ante stage (i.e., initial alignment with given contingencies)
and ex post stage (i.e., ongoing alignment as these contingencies change). Thus, a positive
link means an initial positive alignment as well as a response to a contingency’s change in
a same direction. In either stage, a focal MNC’s strategic need for government-controlled
resources is the central force determining an MNC’s efforts in designing MGRs. We
discuss below detailed alignments in terms of how the levels of cooperation and
competition in all typologies match the following conditions. We expect that such
alignments in terms of the directions remain the same under different typologies proposed
above. Nevertheless, MNCs may adjust their political tactics differently under different
typologies to respond to new arrays between cooperation or competition and environ-
mental or organizational changes. Finally, we note that the following propositions are
raised from a perspective of MNCs, and hence the adjustment of cooperation or
competition reflects only what MNCs perceive.
An organization’s political imperative is a function of environments that exhibit great
diversity in terms of economic, political, regulatory, and industrial conditions (Ring et al.,
1990). This diversity is amplified when MNCs operate in foreign emerging markets where
economic, political, regulatory, and industrial systems are undergoing structural trans-
formations (Ramamurti, 2001). Because of this reason, we emphasize below how
economic development, political stability, regulatory deterrence, and industrial growth
may affect the levels of cooperation and competition in the coopetition matrix. Although
there are other environmental correlates possibly influencing these levels as well, the four
parameters we focus on are more representative in exhibiting environmental dynamics in
emerging economies and in capturing environmental determinants of MGRs. Economic
conditions in emerging economies are largely determined by the status of economic
development and this status influences the quantity and quality of local resources needed
by MNCs (Porter, 1990). Political stability has long been recognized as a high-impacting
conditional factor influencing an MNC’s investment strategies (Bartlett and Ghoshal,
1989; Caves, 1996; Dunning, 1995) and political behaviors (Boddewyn, 1988;
Ramamurti, 2001). This stability affects the payoff of political responsiveness (Kobrin,
1982). According to Oliver (1991), regulatory stringency escalates environment impedi-
ments and heightens the costs of obtaining, scanning, and analyzing information for
operations and management, thus leading to more circumvent political response. Finally,
political behavior may differ among industries (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994). For
example, firms might be more cooperative with governments if the host industry grows
more rapidly. We detail these contingencies next.

4.1. Economic development

According to the resource dependence theory, cooperation or competition is partially


determined by the abundance of external resources on which the firm must rely (Pfeffer
and Salancik, 1978). This abundance is then affected by a host country’s economic
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 443

development. We expect that when the stage or level of economic development in an


emerging market is higher, MNCs are likely to maintain higher cooperation and lower
competition with local government authorities, other things being constant, for several
reasons. First, MNCs generally depend more on local resources when a host economy is
better developed. Infrastructure conditions and quality of production factors (especially
skillful labor force) are an increasing function of the stage of economic development
(Porter, 1990). When infrastructure and production input are superior, foreign companies
will rely more on local resource endowments and infrastructure because it is more efficient
and cheaper to use them than to allocate from home. As the development of these
resources is mainly or partly provided by the government (e.g., governmentally launched
training program in Singapore), firms are more cooperative when they depend more on
such resources. Second, economic liberalization increases as the national economy
continues to develop. Consequently, MNCs will face a more liberalized climate of
investment and operations in a more developed emerging economy. This liberalization
reduces bargains and competition with the government because the political authority has
eliminated institutional control in many sectors in which private businesses start to
dominate (Ramamurti, 2000). Third, a host government in a more developed emerging
economy tends to be more efficient and transparent in decision making and more
cooperative and supportive in relation to MNCs (Stopford, 1994). MNCs are, accordingly,
more willing to build cooperative MGRs from which they can benefit more. Lastly, a
stronger economy tends to maintain a stronger absorptive capability in assimilating
MNCs’ technological and organizational skills (Porter, 1990). Although resource
complementarity exists between MNCs and poorer economies as well, inferior learning
and absorptive abilities of local businesses in poorer economies restrain actual
cooperation. Alliance theory suggests that inferior absorptive capability undercuts the
possible link between cooperation and complementarity (Dyer and Singh, 1998) because
cooperation cannot take place if a receptor is unable to absorb. In light of the above, we
propose:
Proposition 1. In the coopetition matrix, cooperation will be positively, and competition
will be negatively, associated with an emerging economy’s development stage, ceteris
paribus.
Under this scenario, estranger MNCs may emphasize compliance more than circum-
vention as the economic status of a country improves. This is because firms may face less
institutional pressure and less governmental hindrance in a nation with better economic
development. Contender MNCs may opt for bargaining rather than picking challenges as
their first best choice. Challenging is a defying tactic that contests government policies
(Oliver, 1991). Bargaining is less resistant to, and contain more compromise with,
governmental interests, thus better fitting relatively liberal and developed economic
conditions. Partner MNCs may not need to focus on cooptation but on accommodation and
adaptation when they invest in a relatively developed emerging market. Importing
influential constituents through cooptation may be more fruitful when the regulatory
environment is opaque and difficult to predict, and may not be necessary when the
regulatory framework on FDI has been consummated (Poynter, 1985). Lastly, integrator
MNCs may emphasize influence or compromise, depending on whether economic
444 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

development strengthens a government’s bargaining power. Compromise may be preferred


if this power increases.

4.2. Political stability

Political stability concerns how stable of a focal country’s political environment is,
comprising not only governmental transition but also governmentally enacted legal and
political policies (Kobrin, 1982). The resource dependence theory suggests that environ-
mental instability increases the costs of dependence on external resources, thereby
hampering a firm’s cooperation behavior (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). The political
science perspective holds that a host country’s political stability influences not only
existing business operations but also future business plans (Kofele-Kale, 1992; Moran,
1985). Political stability constitutes a key element of the feasibility study when an MNC
enters a foreign market (Kobrin, 1982). It affects investment outlook as perceived by MNC
managers and impacts cash inflow as reflected in net income remittance (Dunning, 1995).
High stability creates better outlook and accentuates investment confidence, ceteris
paribus, which will likely make MNCs more cooperative in dealing with governments.
Low stability, in contrast, hampers investment confidence and generates more uncertainty,
which in turn give rise to higher transaction costs associated with local operations and
lower cooperation with governments. An example would be an escalated hostility between
MNCs (e.g., Exxon, Ford, Otis, Coca-Cola, and GM) and the government of Argentina in
1973–1974 when the political and legal systems were chaotic. Since MNCs entering
emerging markets tend to have a long-term orientation, political stability affects their
strategic planning, reinvestment, and global integration (Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989).
More stabilized political environments provide them with more predictable and verifiable
climates and thus help them better strategically plan and design their long-range
transactions (Caves, 1996). Under these circumstances, MNCs will commit more to
improving MGRs (Dunning, 1998). Cooperation is thus expected to be higher and
competition is lower when political environment is more stabilized. Instability such as
abrupt changes of the ruling party is likely to unpredictably change the regulatory
framework, thus increasing investment sunk costs, exit costs, and switch costs (Kobrin,
1982). In this event, firms have to focus on very short-term benefits and may fortify their
competition with governments. We thus predict:
Proposition 2. In the coopetition matrix, cooperation will be positively, and competition
will be negatively, associated with a host country’s political stability, ceteris paribus.
When political environment is more stabilized, estranger MNCs may choose
compliance, rather than circumvention, as the primary political response. This stability
ascertains lower costs or better returns associated with this compliance. Contender MNCs
may emphasize bargaining rather than challenging when they operate in a highly stabilized
political environment. Challenge is usually necessary if political environment is volatile
and unpredictable (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994). Partner MNCs may use all three tactics,
including accommodation, cooptation, and adaptation, with an emphasis on adaptation.
Political stability helps ensure steady income stream accrued from evolving adaptations.
Whether integrator MNCs should emphasize compromise or influence in this situation will
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 445

depend on the new status of an MNC’s strategic needs and bargaining power. Political
scientists suggest that under political stability, the political market still exists where
businesses can influence and internalize government decision makers (Moran, 1985).

4.3. Regulatory deterrence

Regulatory deterrence concerns the extent to which business operations are hampered
and deterred by administrative regulations enacted by host government authorities. This
deterrence prevents market efficiency by obstructing the movement of market force, often
resulting in more deviations from market equilibrium (Caves, 1996). From an organiza-
tional viewpoint, this deterrence elevates environmental impediments and increases
information search costs (Oliver, 1991). From the resource dependence viewpoint, this
deterrence increases the uncertainty of external resources, pushing the firm to either look
at resources from alternative sources or cut down the existing interdependence (Pfeffer
and Salancik, 1978). When regulatory deterrence is high, MNCs are likely to reduce their
dependence on government-instituted production input and operational resources.
Motorola built its own supply base in Tianjin, China, in the late 1980s, instead of
relying on state-controlled local suppliers, to respond to regulatory deterrence in the
telecom industry. With this response, it reduces both competition and cooperation with
the government in the area of telecom parts and components. Without this reduction,
firms are deemed to be highly susceptible to regulatory changes and interference, that is,
MNCs will engage greater economic exposure in local operations. To mitigate such
economic exposure, MNCs may keep some distance from government control and from
regulatory disturbance. In doing so, they may shift from previous dependence on
governmentally controlled resources to more collaboration with local business
community (suppliers, distributors, competitors, and marketers) or more dependence on
other units within the MNC network that is globally integrated (Bartlett and Ghoshal,
1989). This shift then reduces both cooperation and competition with the host
government. Thus, we envisage:
Proposition 3. In the coopetition matrix, both cooperation and competition will be
negatively associated with a host country’s regulatory deterrence, ceteris paribus.
When the regulatory environment becomes more hazardous, estranger MNCs may
emphasize circumvention more than on compliance. Circumvention is more efficient than
compliance in terms of diluting organizational vulnerability to regulatory hazards (Oliver,
1991). Contender MNCs may bargain or challenge governmental rules and policies if they
have relatively greater bargaining power over the government or appease if they do not
have this power. Partner MNCs may consider cooptation as the major tactic with
accommodation and adaptation as supplementary tactics. Because governments and
partner MNCs are highly interdependent, cooptation may forcefully attenuate regulatory
disturbance. Similarly, integrator MNCs may choose influence if they have enough
bargaining power compared to that of the government or choose compromise if they do
not. In any event, this bargaining power derives from the extent to which the other party
depends on this party and the extent to which this party actually contribute resources
anticipated by the other party.
446 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

4.4. Industrial growth

Alliance theorists maintain that firms favor cooperative strategies if they portray
industry growth opportunities that can only be seized by joint forces, or prefer competitive
strategies if their distinctive resources or bargaining power enable them to dominate the
competition (Khanna et al., 1998; Lado et al., 1997). Despite challenges, emerging foreign
markets provide foreign ventures with tremendous preemptive opportunities. These
opportunities, however, vary across different industries within an emerging market. Such
opportunities largely arise from decentralizing industrial structures previously controlled
by the government and dominated by a few state-owned monopolistic enterprises. The
growth variance in sales and profit across industries reflects the differences in market
demand, as well as the outcome of different government policies regulating different
industries (Porter, 1990). When the host industry in which an MNC participates grows
faster, the firm may face a greater need for cooperation as well as competition with
government authorities. For example, Anheuser-Busch saw increased cooperation (e.g.,
eliminating performance requirements and joint venture equity ceilings) as well as
competition (e.g., the government increased its institutional protection for the market share
of local brewers such as Grupo Modelo) with the Mexican government (the Zedilto
administration) in 1990–1991 when the beer industry there grew fast. More cooperation is
generally needed because MNCs and governments tend to be more interdependent in fast-
growing industries in which governments need MNCs’ technologies and organizing
principles to efficiently modernize these sectors, while MNCs need governments’
assistance in stabilizing their overseas operations. Luo (2002) demonstrates that fast-
growing industries in emerging economies are accompanied with greater structural
uncertainty. To reduce this uncertainty, MNCs need governmental support in ascertaining
resource procurement, product distribution, and mediation conflicts with local businesses.
Meanwhile, more competition with governments may also arise due to the fact that MNCs
rely more on local resources (e.g., capital and infrastructure) that are still controlled by
government agencies. Since governmental policies on FDI in fast-growing industries are
shifting from rigidity to elasticity (Dunning, 1998), MNCs have more leeway in
bargaining with governments for more, better, or cheaper resources. MNCs in fast-
growing sectors have generally brought distinctive resources to local operations, which in
turn increases their bargaining position. Thus, we hypothesize:
Proposition 4. In the coopetition matrix, both cooperation and competition will be
positively associated with the growth of a host industry in which an MNC participates,
ceteris paribus.
Estranger MNCs depend less on a host industry’s market conditions including industrial
growth. Thus, their political response will remain either compliance or circumvention.
Contender MNCs, however, may emphasize bargaining and focus less on challenge, given
the fact that faster growth of the industry often requires greater interdependence between
MNCs and governments. Partner MNCs may respond to the above situation by
emphasizing adaptation and accommodation. Participating in a prosperous local industry
necessitates more adaptation or polycentric orientation (Ring et al., 1990). Accommoda-
tion is needed because those MNCs in fast-growing industries may confront more pressure
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 447

from the indigenous society for social responsiveness. Lastly, integrator MNCs may select
a more active or offensive political tactic (i.e., influence) in response to the industry’s
stronger growth. In the presence of bargaining power, integrator MNCs may gain more
from MGRs by using influence strategy than using passive compromise when they operate
in a more promising industry.
The above four environmental factors are often interactive, jointly impacting
cooperation or competition. In this situation, MNCs need to identify the dominant
strategic response(s) from those we outlined above and unify these responses such that
they are not only consistent with each other but also congruent with the overriding
organizational needs and adaptive to the leading environmental factors. We also note that
the above political behavior to respond to these environmental factors by different types of
MNCs is suggested from the normative perspective based on the logic of the institutional
theory, resource dependence, network, and political behavior. It remains to be verified by
future empirical research or case studies.

5. Conclusion

In this article, we develop a conceptual and typological framework of coopetition that


in our observation describes the nature of MGRs in today’s global business environment.
The coopetition view suggests that such relations contain both cooperation and
competition elements that function simultaneously. It holds that MGRs are neither
dichotomous nor continuous between competition and cooperation. Instead, they are two
simultaneous dimensions in a matrix along which MNCs and governments interact. We
also offer a typology of coopetition that identifies MNCs with varying degrees of
cooperation and competition. Strategic needs of MNCs for local resources controlled by
governments are the central variant of distinguishing these types. Each type of MNC has
several options from which to choose as their political tactics. Not every MNC with the
same type should necessarily follow same tactics. This variation depends on an MNC’s
bargaining power vis-à-vis governments and the firm’s comparison of anticipated gains
between different tactics. This identity may remain within a period of time when changes
of environmental and organizational parameters come under certain limits. Beyond these
limits, however, the identity may change, requiring new political responses under new
conditions.
The coopetition view recognizes the importance of properly configuring—both initially
and evolutionarily—cooperation and competition based on environmental dynamics. We
articulate four environmental conditions—including economic development, political
stability, regulatory deterrence, and industrial growth—which altogether represent the key
profile of the institutional environment in a foreign emerging market. In the coopetition
matrix, cooperation and competition may or may not respond in a same direction to
conditions of these environmental segments. Cooperation may increase while competition
may decrease when a host country’s economic development or its political stability
improves. Cooperation and competition may both decrease as regulatory deterrence
increases. By contrast, cooperation and competition may both increase along industrial
growth.
448 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

To international executives, their political responses must align with the requirements
of competition and cooperation. When involving low competition (estranger and partner),
their political responses to governmental regulations should be less confrontational (e.g.,
compliance, circumvention, co-optation, or adaptation). When involving high competition
(contender and integrator), their responses should be more aggressive (e.g., bargain,
challenge, or influence). As cooperation increases from low (estranger and contender) to
high (partner and integrator), political responses become more socially responsive and
politically accommodated. For this purpose, international executives may use resource
commitment, personal relations, lobbying, and political accommodation to improve their
relations with governments, which in turn affect the outcome of international expansion.
These political responses should not remain at a standstill when the coopetition matrix
changes. International executives need to adjust their political behavior as well to align
with changed cooperation or competition with governments caused by new conditions of
environments and organizations. This adjustment is necessary because these new
conditions also change conditions under which expected gains of political tactics are
calculated. When economic, political, regulatory, and industrial environments become
more favorable or when an MNC’s resource complementarity and goal congruence with
governments are strengthened, MGRs become more cooperative and less competitive. In
this situation, estranger MNCs may emphasize compliance more than circumvention;
contender MNCs may use less defiant tactics such as bargaining instead of challenging;
partner MNCs may place political emphasis on adaptation; and integrator MNCs may
consider compromise or influence, depending on their bargaining power vis-à-vis
governments. When strategic orientation becomes more proactive, partner MNCs may
heighten accommodation and adaptation while contender and integrator MNCs may
sharpen bargaining or influence if their bargaining power is present.
Naturally, our propositions need to be empirically validated by future research. To
maintain conceptual clarity and parsimony in illustrating predictors of coopetition, we
have focused on several prominent variables that are most likely to affect the levels of
cooperation and competition. In our model, we might have missed other contingencies that
affect these levels. For example, cooperation or competition may be shaped by corporate
reputation, strategic goals, entry mode, and entry order. In testing our model, future efforts
may examine how cooperation and competition co-evolve along with new conditions of
environments and organizations and in what different domains cooperation and
competition simultaneously take place. Identifying their coevolvement and domains is
an intriguing area for further exploration.
A second promising area is to place the coopetition framework within a broader
organizational context—an MNC’s geographically dispersed yet globally integrated
network. Within this broader network, various foreign subunits will likely be characterized
with different identities. For example, a subsidiary in Latin America may be a contender
while its sister subsidiary in Asia may be a partner. In this situation, headquarters
coordination of MGRs with multiple host-country governments is warranted. Each MNC
might need to establish a system not only to share international experience in handling
MGRs but also to tie resource deployment with the coopetition types of different
subsidiaries. Resource deployment is an organizational lever to adjust individual subunits’
bargaining power and dependence on local resources (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994;
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 449

Kostova and Zaheer, 1999; Poynter, 1985). Coordination may also enable MNCs to better
bargain with individual governments. This occurs if MNCs pressure one government over
another when these governments are competing for inbound FDI. Coopetition includes
both simultaneous cooperation and competition with an individual government and
simultaneous interactions with multiple foreign governments. MNCs may leverage the
latter to bolster their bargaining power. Further, MGRs with a home government may be
interrelated with MGRs with a host government, as MNCs can use home government
resources or institutions (e.g., U.S. Trade Representative Office) to facilitate their
relationships with host governments.
Third, this article has not addressed how MNCs should specifically improve MGRs in
the coopetition framework. Recent studies find that resource commitment, personal ties,
social accommodation, and corporate credibility are important building blocks for
improving MGRs (Luo, 2001). Future efforts may seek to advance this line of research
by differentiating estrangers, contenders, partners, and integrators with respect to MGR
cultivation. Since MNCs with different coopetition identities are not homogeneous in
terms of their resource dependence on indigenous resources and their vulnerability to
regulatory disturbance, required commitments to establishing MGRs accordingly differ.
Thus, it would be useful to assess how such different MNCs emphasize different building
blocks and how they leverage their bargaining power to simultaneously benefit from
differently configured cooperation and competition.
Finally, this study emphasizes governments in developing economies, especially
emerging markets. Our conceptual model may be also applicable to developed market
economies since coopetitive MGRs are deemed to exist in every economy. Governments
in developed economies share many concerns such as domestic employment, export
growth, environmental protection, and technological advancement as those in emerging
economies. Nonetheless, specific strengths of cooperation and competition as well as
specific environmental parameters that influence cooperation or competition may vary
according to different types of economies. Because governments in developed economies
do not regularly intervene overall inbound FDI policies but instead carefully oversee
competition and antitrust situations in specific industries, coopetition may be more
contingent upon industry-level structural variables than national-level environmental
factors. Further, as most developed economies provide a national treatment to foreign
MNCs, domestic firms can be leading counterparts with which MNCs compete for local
resources. Similarly, with continued privatization, local firms in emerging markets are
becoming powerful rivals competing both local resources and market shares. Future
research, whether emphasizing developed or emerging economies, should incorporate
domestic firms as a moderating force in assessing MGRs.
In conclusion, this study presents a coopetition perspective toward MNC–host
government relations, with an emphasized interest in foreign emerging markets. This view
may help enrich our understanding of new profiles, behaviors, and structures of MGRs that
emerged in the beginning of this new century. We see this effort as important and necessary
because MGRs today differ from what we saw in previous decades and from what earlier
studies described. Nevertheless, this article represents only one of the systematic efforts
required in addressing this increasingly critical yet inherently complicated issue in a broader
economic, political, and social contexts in which such relations are so richly embedded.
450 Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451

Acknowledgement

The author would like to thank JIM’s anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments.

References

Bartlett, C.A., Ghoshal, S., 1989. Managing Across Borders. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Behrman, J.N., Grosse, R.E., 1990. International Business and Governments: Issues and Institutions. University
of South Carolina Press.
Behrman, J.N., Boddewyn, J.J., Kapoor, A., 1975. International Business–Government Communications.
Lexington Books, Lexington, MA.
Boddewyn, J.B., 1988. Political aspects of MNE theory. Journal of International Business Studies, 341 – 363.
(Fall).
Boddewyn, J.J., Brewer, T.L., 1994. International-business political behavior: new theoretical directions.
Academy of Management Review 19 (1), 119 – 143.
Brandenburger, A.M., Nalebuff, B.J., 1996. Co-opetition. Doubleday Currency, New York.
Brewer, T.L., 1992. An issue-area approach to the analysis of MNE–Government relations. Journal of
International Business Studies, Second Quarter, 295 – 309.
Buckley, P., Casson, M., 1988. The theory of cooperation in international business. In: Contractor, Lorange
(Eds.), Cooperative Strategies in International Business. Lexington Books, Toronto, pp. 31 – 34.
Caves, R.E., 1996. Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis, 2nd ed. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
Daniels, J.D., Radebaugh, L.H., Sullivan, D.P., 2004. International Business, 10th ed. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle
River, New Jersey.
DiMaggio, P.J., Powell, W.W., 1983. The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality
in organizational fields. American Sociological Review 48, 147 – 160.
Dowling, J.B., Shaeffer, N.V., 1982. Institutional and anti-institutional conflict among business, government and
the public. Academy of Management Journal 25, 683 – 689.
Dunning, J.H., 1995. Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA.
Dunning, J.H., 1998. An overview of relations with national governments. New Political Economy 3 (2),
280 – 284.
Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of inter-organizational
competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review 23, 660 – 679.
Encarnation, D.J., Wells, L.T., 1985. Sovereignty en garde: negotiating with foreign investors. International
Organization 39 (1), 32 – 47.
Fagre, N., Wells, L.T., 1982. Bargaining power of multinationals and host governments. Journal of International
Business Studies, 9 – 24. (Fall).
Gladwin, T.N., Walter, I., 1980. How multinationals can manage social and political forces. Journal of Business
Strategy, 54 – 68. (Summer).
Granovetter, M., 1985. Economic action and social structure. American Journal of Sociology 91, 481 – 510.
Khanna, T., Palepu, 1997. Why focused strategies may be wrong for emerging markets. Harvard Business Review
75 (4), 41 – 50.
Khanna, T., Gulati, R., Nohria, N., 1998. The dynamics of learning alliances: competition, cooperation, and
relative scope. Strategic Management Journal 19, 193 – 210.
Kim, W.C., 1988. The effects of competition and corporate political responsiveness on multinational bargaining
power. Strategic Management Journal 9, 289 – 295.
Kobrin, S., 1982. Managing political risk assessment: strategic responses to environmental changes. University of
California Press, Berkeley, CA.
Kofele-Kale, N., 1992. The political economy of foreign direct investment: a framework for analyzing investment
laws and regulations in developing countries. Law and Policy in International Business 23 (3), 619 – 772.
Kostova, T., Zaheer, S., 1999. Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: the case of the
multinational enterprise. Academy of Management Review 24 (1), 64 – 81.
Y. Luo / Journal of International Management 10 (2004) 431–451 451

Lado, A.A., Boyd, N.G., Hanlon, S.C., 1997. Competition, cooperation, and the search for economic rents: a
syncretic model. Academy of Management Review 22 (1), 110 – 141.
Lecraw, D.J., 1984. Bargaining power, ownership, and profitability of transnational corporations in developing
countries. Journal of International Business Studies 15 (1), 27 – 43.
Luo, Y., 2001. Toward a cooperative view of MNC–government relations: building blocks and performance
implications. Journal of International Business Studies 32, 401 – 420.
Luo, Y., 2002. Multinational Enterprises in Emerging Markets. Copenhagen Business School Press, Copenhagen.
Moran, T., 1985. Multinational Corporations: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. Lexington
Books, Lexington, MA.
Oliver, C., 1991. Strategic responses to institutional processes. Academy of Management Review 16, 145 – 179.
Osland, G., Bjorkman, I., 1998. MNC–host government interaction: government pressures on MNCs in China.
European Management Journal 16, 91 – 100.
Pfeffer, J., Salancik, G., 1978. The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence Perspective.
Harper and Row, New York.
Porter, M.E., 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. The Free Press, New York.
Poynter, T.A., 1985. Multinational Enterprises and Government Intervention. Saint Martin’s Press, New York.
Ramamurti, R., 2000. A multilevel model of privatization in emerging economies. Academy of Management
Review 25, 525 – 550.
Ramamurti, R., 2001. The obsolescing dbargaining modelT? MNC–host developing country relations revisited.
Journal of International Business Studies 32 (1), 23 – 40.
Ring, P.S., Lenway, S., Govekar, M., 1990. Management of the political imperative in international business.
Strategic Management Journal 11 (2), 141 – 151.
Rugman, A.M., Verbeke, A., 1998. Multinational enterprises and public policy. Journal of International Business
Studies 29 (1), 115 – 136.
Scott, W.R., 1987. The adolescence of institutional theory. Administrative Science Quarterly 32, 493 – 511.
Stevens, J.M., McGowan, R.P., 1983. Managerial strategies in municipal government organizations. Academy of
Management Journal 26, 527 – 534.
Stopford, J.M., 1994. The growing interdependence between transnational corporations and governments.
Transnational Corporations 3 (1), 53 – 76.
Stopford, J.M., Strange, S., 1991. Rival State, Rival Firms: Competition for World Market Shares. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge.
Strange, S., 1997. The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge.
Vernon, R., 1971. Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of US Enterprises. Basic Books, New York.

You might also like