You are on page 1of 15

Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Technological Forecasting & Social Change


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/techfore

Asymmetric effects of urbanization on shadow economy both in short-run


and long-run:New evidence from dynamic panel threshold model
Jingru Pang a, 1, Nan Li a, 1, Hailin Mu a, **, Xin Jin a, Ming Zhang b, 1
a
School of Energy and Power, Dalian University of Technology, Dalian, 116024, China
b
School of Economics and Management, China University of Mining and Technology, Xuzhou, 221116, China

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Urbanization and shadow economy are both common social problems in developing countries, yet rare studies
Urbanization have explored their potential relationships. Based on the provincial panel data in China, this paper estimates both
Shadow economy the short-run and long-run non-linear relationship between urbanization and shadow economy combining with
Short/long run
GMM (Generalized method of moments) and threshold analysis specifications, for symmetric analysis and
Asymmetry effect
Dynamic panel threshold model
asymmetric analysis, respectively. This paper also estimates if shadow economy is consistent with the EKC
(Environment Kuznets Curve) assumption, and including other explanatory variables such as energy consump­
tion, FDI (Foreign Direct Investment), tertiary industry and environmental regulation. Results show that ur­
banization does have an inversed U-shaped effect on shadow economy, so does economic growth, for both
symmetric and asymmetric analyses. Tertiary industry can redouble the scale of shadow economy, which is
consistent with all four analysis aspects. Other explanatory variables show slight differences in either symmetric/
asymmetric or short-run/ long-run results.

1. Introduction have the fastest urbanization developing rates, where the widespread
shadow economy is part of the reasons to prevent official economy from
Urbanization is becoming one of the most transformative trends in moving forward. Based on Schneider et al. (2010), the percentage of
the 21st century (UN, 2017). Over half of the population in the world shadow economy in the developing countries can be as large as 67.7% or
nowadays are living in the urban areas, and the proportion is predicted even more (the size of year 2002 and 2003 in Bolivia). Still, rare research
to reach to 68% by 2050 (Kookana et al., 2020). Urbanization can lead to has ever explored if it is a coincidence that both urbanization and
economic prosperity, as more than 80 percent of global GDP is created in shadow economy break out in the developing countries. To fill the above
urbans (WB, 2020). Nevertheless, it turns out that cities with faster gaps, by applying the provincial panel date of China from 2008 to 2017
growing rates have no more financial resources than the cities with with GMM and threshold analysis specifications, this study estimates
average growing rates. According to McDonald et al. (2014), 68% of the both the short-run and long-run non-linear relationship between ur­
metropolises are in countries with middle or even low capital income, banization and shadow economy for both symmetric and asymmetric
such as China, Mexico, and Central Asia. Especially, it is the two poorest aspects. Results show that urbanization does have an inversed U-shaped
regions that will have the largest increased urban population, relationship with the scale of shadow economy.
Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia, where the proportion is expected to This research advantages the previous articles with the followings:
double during the following twenty years (UN DESA, 2018). First, this is the pioneering study of the short-run and long-run non-
Considerable theories and empirical analysis have proved that ur­ linear relationship between urbanization and shadow economy in both
banization is integral to the development of economy (McGranahan, symmetric and asymmetric aspects. Comparing with the current studies
2015) and environmental pollution/climate changes (Dong et al., 2021; that focus mainly on the economic development (Qiu et al., 2019), en­
Luo et al., 2020; Meng et al., 2021). However, as an important compo­ ergy consumption (Sun and Huang, 2020; Wu et al., 2019) or environ­
nent of economic development, shadow economy and its consequences mental pollution (Hao et al., 2020; Kookana et al., 2020; Muñoz et al.,
have been inadvisably overlooked. It is the developing countries that 2020), this paper will bring new ideas for the following analysis. Most

** Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: hailinmu@dlut.edu.cn (H. Mu), zhangmingdlut@163.com (M. Zhang).
1
Jingru Pang, Nan Li, and Ming Zhang contributed equally to this work, and should be considered as co-first authors.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2022.121514
Received 15 April 2021; Received in revised form 8 December 2021; Accepted 15 January 2022
Available online 19 January 2022
0040-1625/© 2022 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

importantly, the conclusion will help the Chinese government including shadow economy.
many developing countries who experiencing fast urbanization rates Previous research has summarized some “push” factors from ur­
when making policies about environmental protection as well as econ­ banization to the increase of shadow economy. The first one is the rural-
omy development. Even though this is not the first paper that studies the to-urban transfer of the labor force. Elgin and Oyvat (2013) claim that
inversed U-shaped relationship between shadow economy and urbani­ urban informal sectors attract rural to urban population transfer due to
zation (Elgin and Oyvat, 2013; Rauch, 1993), but none of the previous higher incomes and better public services. The second one is the
articles have analyzed the inversed U-shaped relationship in either long industrialization caused by the urbanization process, which often results
term and short term or symmetric and asymmetric aspects. Second, from a shift from agricultural economic structure to industrial economic
using new sub catalogs in the entropy weight method to define urban­ structure, coupled with poor infrastructure and illegal settlements
ization, which is more comprehensive and representative. Compared (Colenbrander, 2016). The third one is the technological improvements,
with many research that only using urban population to represent ur­ as Boyce (1993) claims that the technological improvements in rural
banization (Wang et al., 2021; Wang et al., 2021; Wu et al., 2021), en­ sector are “labor-saving”, which may lead to the decrease of rural
tropy weight method covers more contents, which are all contributions income.
to the development of urbanization. The importance of comprehensive There are also some “pull” factors that may lead to the decrease of
definition of urbanization of the research is to reach more realizable the scale of shadow economy due to the development of urbanization.
results, which will not only benefit the future research direction but also The first one is monopoly capital. According to Aglietta (1998), urban­
the policy making. ization will contribute to the capital concentration and capital central­
The reminding article is organized with the followings. Section 2 ization, making traditional enterprises and small and medium-sized
addresses the literature review. Section 3 discusses the models and data enterprises hard to survive. And those enterprises are normally highly
applied in this study. Section 4 provides the estimation procedures and linked to shadow economy.
the empirical results. Section 5 lists the conclusions and regulation To summarize, the relationship between urbanization and shadow
recommendations. economy should exist, and the relationship should be non-linear. The
above hypothesis has been proved by previous articles. Rauch (1993) is
2. Literature Review the first one to propose the inverted-U relationship between urbaniza­
tion and urban informal sector and successfully prove it. Based on the
Shadow economy, or informal economy, is also titled as shadow database of 152 countries over 9 years from 1999 to 2007, Elgin and
sector or underground economy. Hart (2008) defines it as specific eco­ Oyvat (2013) investigate the empirical relationship and prove the
nomic activities outside the legal framework. Ihrig and Moe (2003) inverted-U effect from the level of urbanization on the scale of shadow
describe it as an economic sector with goods production but without economy. Xu et al., (2018) apply annual panel data of 131 countries and
following environmental regulations. The consequences of shadow regions based on 1999 to 2007 and prove the inverted-U relationship
economy can be serious and widespread, especially when shadow ac­ between urbanization and informal sector, too.
tivities have become one of the most prevalent problems over the world
(Goel and Nelson, 2016). The challenges posed by shadow economy 3. Models and Data
include but not limit to society, economy, culture, and policy imple­
mentation. The worst part is that shadow activities are happening 3.1. Short-run dynamic panel model
under-explored therefore difficultly deriving useful information by
policymakers. First, the concept speed pf adjustment will be introduced, as it ap­
Recent articles of shadow economy mostly focus on the relationship plies in the short-run dynamic panel model. For econometric specifica­
with pollution, environmental regulation, or other aspects (Chen et al., tion such as shadow economy, the adjustment of current situation
2018; Elgin and Öztunalı, 2014; Lazăr et al., 2019)). Articles about ur­ toward target normally takes a period, therefore called the dynamic
banization level are mostly concentrated on pollution (Luo et al., 2020; process.
Sheng et al., 2020) as well, but also on energy consumption (Liu et al., ( )
2021; Lv et al., 2020) or urban agriculture (Zhong et al., 2020), et al. Δyi,t = γ y∗i,t − yi,t− 1 + υi,t (1)
However, rare research has been working on the potential relationship
between urbanization level and scale of shadow economy, both are quite Where Δyi,t is the first difference of yi,t. yi,t and y*i,t represent the actual
prevalent especially in developing countries. Based on the articles from value and the observed value of the dependent variable of province i,
Schneider et al. (2010), the mean size of shadow economy in 98 year t, respectively. γ is the speed of adjustment, measuring how fast the
developing countries is 35.1% of the total GDP in 2007, while the one in percentage of shadow economy can be changed toward specific targets.
25 OECD countries is as small as 16.6% of the total GDP. After exam­ The higher the value of γ, the faster the speed of adjustment. υi,t is the
ining the twenty-two developing countries in Asia during 2002 to 2015, one way error component that will be explained later.
Huynh (2020) proves that those countries are facing great challenges The original dynamic panel model with panel data is given by:
coming from shadow economy. According to McGranahan (2015), the
yi,t = ρyi,t− 1 + β′ ⋅Xi,t + υi,t ; i = 1, 2, ⋯, N; t = 1, 2, ⋯, T (2)
rates in Asia have become the highest over the past half century even
though the global rates of urbanization have been declining. Where yi,t-1 represents the dependent variable of province i, year t-1. ρ is
Therefore, urbanization may be highly related to the size of shadow the coefficient of yi,t-1. Xi,t represents all the independent variables of
economy, especially in developing countries, such as China. Daniels province i, year t with β as the coefficients. υi,t is the one way error
(2004) lists some key informal activities in metropolis including snack component consisting of the individually provincial fixed effects:
vending, pedicab drivers, small artisans, and home-based workers.
Especially some positions with unnecessarily poor salaries may still υi,t = αi + εi,t (3)
generate significant volumes of underground productions, such as tele­
communications and computing services. Those activities normally will Where αi is the individual provincial fixed effect that varies only across
be included as shadow sectors, as it is difficult for the government to provinces instead of over time. εi,t is the white noise to represent the
trace them for taxes. But that article does not provide empirical analysis error term with a zero mathematical expectation and a constant
to prove the relationship between urbanization and shadow economy. variance.
To fill the above study gaps, more comprehensive analysis is required to Based on Equ (1) to Equ (3), the speed of adjustment can be calcu­
further explore the detailed relationship between urbanization and lated as:

2
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Table 1
Descriptive statistics of the variables applied in this research
Variables Definition Units Obs. Min. Max. Mean Stv.

se the percentage of shadow economy in total GDP % 300 0.07 0.25 0.13 0.03
urban urbanization level - 300 0.03 11.93 1.35 2.27
urban_s the square of urbanization level - 300 19.97 19.97 19.97 0.00
GDPgr the actual growth rate of GDP % 300 -0.02 0.56 0.13 0.09
GDPgr_s the square of the actual growth rate of GDP %^2 300 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.00
ev the energy consumption - 300 0.01 0.24 0.10 0.03
lnFDI log of the Foreign Direct Investment - 300 -2.38 2.77 0.92 1.06
TIgr the actual growth rate of the actual tertiary industry % 300 0.08 3.80 1.28 0.87
er environmental regulation % 300 0.00 0.04 0.01 0.01

γ =1− ρ (4) 3.2. Long-run panel model

While the estimation of ρ is biased downward as the regression is The adjustment mechanisms of the dependent variables may be
associated with unobserved fixed effects: αi (Nickell, 1981). The speed of complex, including not only homogeneous/heterogeneous rates (sym­
adjustment, γ, will then be biased upward. metry/asymmetry in short run) but also homogeneous/heterogeneous
The assumption under Eq. (1) is that shadow economy undertakes targets (symmetry/asymmetry in the long-run) (Dang et al., 2012). To
adjustments based on various of reasons in a symmetric fashion, which entertain some the intermediate scenarios in a more flexible manner,
will no longer be valid once the shadow economy changes infrequently this paper will apply both symmetric long-term target relationships and
at different rates. Fischer et al. (1989) firstly describe this transform asymmetrical short-term adjustment rates.
point as the “restructuring point”. To further capture this behavior, this The original short-run dynamic panel model, Equ. 2, will be adjusted
paper develops the dynamic threshold model with the regime-switching, as follows for long-term relationship estimation:
as follows:
yi,t = β′ ⋅Xi,t + υi,t ; i = 1, 2, ⋯, N; t = 1, 2, ⋯, T (8)
( ) ( )
(5)
′ ′
yi,t = ρ1 yi,t− 1 + β1 ⋅Xi,t 1{ri,t ≤c} + ρ2 yi,t− 1 + β2 ⋅Xi,t 1{ri,t >c} + αi + εi,t
The original short-run dynamic threshold model with the regime-
Where 1{•}represents the indicator function that takes the numerical switching will be developed to capture the long-run relationship esti­
value 1 once the assumption in the brace is true or 0 otherwise. The mation as follows:
transition variable of regime-switching is represented by ri,t, and the ( ′ ) ( ′ )
yi,t = β1 ⋅Xi,t 1{ri,t ≤c} + β2 ⋅Xi,t 1{ri,t >c} + αi + εi,t (9)
threshold parameter is represented by c. Therefore, the basic idea of this
dynamic threshold model is: after estimating the transition variable, the
The first-difference transformation version of Equ. 9 is:
restructuring point, c, will be determined to separate the equation into
{ ′ } { ′ }
two parts with different adjustment rates, ρ and β. Δy(i,t) = β1 ⋅ΔX1i,t + β2 ⋅ΔX2i,t + Δεi,t (10)
This paper then applies the Generalized Method of Moment (GMM)
with instrumental variables for the following estimation. Especially The difference between the short-run and the long-run is the lagged
when the regressors are correlated with the individual provincial fixed explained variable in the short-run model, which can show the short-run
effects, αi. Firstly the Eq. 5 is rewritten with first-difference dynamic process. This kind of distinguish is also applied in Dang et al.
transformation: (2012), who use dynamic panel threshold models to study the asym­
{ } { } metric capital structure adjustments. The reason why the lagged
(6)
′ ′
Δyi,t = ρ1 Δy1i,t− 1 + β1 ⋅ΔX1i,t + ρ2 Δy2i,t− 1 + β2 ⋅ΔX2i,t + Δεi,t
explained variable can show the short-run process is as the followings:
first, shadow economy is like many other variables, such as pollution,
Where Δy1i,t-1=Δyi,t-1•1{ri,t≤c}, Δy2i,t-1=Δyi,t-1•1{ri,t>c}; ΔX1i,t-1=ΔXi,t-
has time lag characteristic, which means that the current scale of
1•1{ri,t≤c}, ΔX2i,t-1=ΔXi,t-1•1{ri,t>c}. Also, the individual provincial fixed
shadow economy normally will be affected by the previous situation,
effect, αi, has been successfully removed.
and cannot be changed dramatically within short period. This kind of
If there is no heteroscedasticity limitation, the GMM estimators can
character can also show the dynamic process. Therefore, in the short
be calculated within one step. However, if εi,t is heteroscedastic, the
run, the current scale of shadow economy will be affected by the pre­
efficient two-step GMM estimation will be applied as in this paper. As Q
vious situations and cannot be ignored. In the long run, however, the
(c) is the generalized distance measure1, the threshold parameter, c in
effects from the previous situation can then be ignored, especially one
this study, can be estimated by:
year lagged effect.
c = argminc∈C Q(c)
̂ (7)

According to Dang et al. (2012), the threshold model with a 3.3. Data
regime-switching has advantages when comes to the examination of
asymmetries in dynamic adjustments. First, the threshold parameter is The data in this article are resourced from China Statistical Year­
estimated with a model instead of being chosen arbitrarily, such as the book, China Energy Statistics Yearbook and Statistical Yearbook for each
quantile regression. Second, dynamic threshold model makes it possible province. The descriptive statistics of each variable in this paper are
to switch regime over-time through the entire sample. Third, the first listed in Table 1 as follows:
different transformation can eliminate numbers of general regressor
problems. 3.2.1. Urbanization
The entropy weight theory will be used in this paper to calculate the
comprehensive urbanization. The basic theory is that: among various of
evaluated objects of the same indicator, the higher the differences
among the objects are, the more significant the indicator will be (Li
et al., 2016; Wu et al., 2019; Zhao and Tang, 2018). Plenty of research
2
For detailed explanation, please see Dang et al. (2012). that focus on urbanization development have drawn a consistent

3
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Total Urbanization

Population and Consumption


Living Condition Industrialization Education
Employment Ability

Urban population Night light data per Proportion of second Fiscal expenditure on
GDP per capital
density capital industry education
Fiscal educational
The value-added of
Urban population Total GDP Night light data expenditure
second industry
/Urban area /Total population /Total population /Total educational
/Total GDP
expenditure

Income ratio of
The proportion of Urban-rural Urban green area per Ratio of university
industrial enterprises
urban population consumption ratio capital degree or above
above designated size
Rural consumption Profit from main Population of
Urban population ration Urban green area operation university degree or
/Total population /Urban consumption /Total population /Income from main above per 100,000
ratio operation people

Urban sewage
Urban labor force Proportion of tertiary Ratio of industrial Collection of public
treatment per capital
participation rate industry R&D expenditure libraries per capital
per day
Urban total employed The value-added of Urban sewage Expenditure of R&D Total collection of
/Urban working age tertiary industry treatment per day /cost from main public libraries
population /Total GDP /Total population operation /Total population

Number of industrial
Urban self- Urban per capital
Total public transport enterprises above Number of universities
employment rate disposable income
designated size
Urban private Number of industrial
individual employed Urban per capital
Total public transport enterprises above Number of universities
disposable income
/Urban total employed designated size

Fig. 1. Construction of the total urbanization level. Note: each of the five indicators (population and employment, consumption ability, living condition, indus­
trialization, and education) has four individual objects, with their detailed calculation processes listed below for each object.

conclusion that comprehensive urbanization measurement cannot be ∑n ∑T ( )


completed by only one single indicator (Zhao and Chai, 2015). Based on ρ lnρq,it
ϵq = − i=1 t=1 q,it
(12)
Shen et al. (2015), for each indicator, the entropy method can evaluate ln(n + T)
the performance of both speed and quality, which can reflect the The weight of the entropy can be calculated by:
development and coordination of urbanization. How to measure the ( )
speed and quality quantitative during the calculation of urbanization 1 − ϵq
ω q = ∑Q ( ) (13)
level instead of only phenomenal descriptions will then be a problem, q=1 1 − ϵq
and the entropy method can make that a reality by representing the
speed and quality by associated indicators (Zhao and Chai, 2015). The comprehensive urbanization of the pth indicator can be calcu­
Compared with the subjective weighting method, the entropy weight lated by:
theory can not only overcome the disconnection and randomness ∑Q
urbanp = ωq ρpq (14)
problems, but also the overlapping information coming from multiple q=1

indicators (Yu et al., 2015). Also, the as the weights of each indicator can The total urbanization can be calculated by:
be weighted properly, the evaluation can then be processed more ∑P
effectively (Shemshadi et al., 2011). The detailed calculation processes urbanTotal = ωp ρp , p = 1, 2, ⋯, P; (15)
are listed as follows:
p=1

The proportion of each value of object q for each indicator p is Where urbanTotal is the total urbanization level, ωp is the weight of in­
calculated by: dicator p and ρp is proportion of each indicator p.
urbanq,it This study names five indicators with four objects respectively for the
ρq,it = ∑n ∑T (11) total urbanization calculation. As shown in Fig 1, the five indicators are
t=1 urbanq,it
population and employment, consumption ability, living condition,
i=1

i = 1, 2, ⋯, n; t = 1, 2, ⋯, T; q = 1, 2, ⋯, Q. industrialization, and education.


The scores and ranks of each indicator and the total urbanization
Where urbanq,it is the original value of each object q for province i year t. levels are listed in Table 2. Based on the scores under column Total
Then, the entropy of each object q can be calculated by: Urbanization, the urbanization levels of each province vary from each

4
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Table 2
Scores and Ranks of indicators and total urbanization levels in China from 2008 to 2017.
Provinces Population and Employment Consumption Ability Living Condition Industrialization Education Total Urbanization
Scores Ranks Scores Ranks Scores Ranks Scores Ranks Scores Ranks Scores Ranks

shanghai 0.32 10 0.50 5 45.74 1 0.78 13 21.84 18 28.56 1


tianjin 0.24 27 0.51 4 20.41 2 0.43 17 17.40 23 13.36 2
beijing 0.35 4 0.53 2 17.38 3 0.30 23 27.58 14 12.35 3
jiangsu 0.39 1 0.52 3 10.61 4 3.65 1 47.94 1 11.03 4
guangdong 0.35 5 0.37 21 7.76 5 3.22 2 42.18 2 8.79 5
shandong 0.26 23 0.43 12 7.43 7 3.04 3 42.01 3 8.53 6
zhejiang 0.37 2 0.54 1 7.68 6 2.97 4 31.84 10 7.87 7
hebei 0.24 28 0.39 17 3.98 8 1.05 10 35.05 8 5.37 8
liaoning 0.30 15 0.42 13 3.51 9 1.16 8 34.74 9 5.10 9
henan 0.25 26 0.36 22 3.04 11 1.62 5 36.29 6 5.09 10
anhui 0.30 14 0.37 20 2.62 13 1.22 7 35.13 7 4.63 11
fujian 0.33 7 0.49 6 3.25 10 1.24 6 26.60 15 4.35 12
hubei 0.31 13 0.40 16 1.65 16 1.05 11 37.80 4 4.22 13
hunan 0.29 19 0.39 19 1.13 20 1.07 9 36.96 5 3.86 14
shanxi 0.24 29 0.44 10 2.83 12 0.32 21 23.34 17 3.56 15
shaanxi 0.26 24 0.34 26 1.76 15 0.39 19 27.97 12 3.31 16
sichuan 0.28 20 0.44 8 0.92 24 1.04 12 30.82 11 3.25 17
jiangxi 0.29 18 0.45 7 1.03 22 0.67 14 27.93 13 2.98 18
heilongjiang 0.26 25 0.44 9 1.03 21 0.32 22 24.54 16 2.61 19
chongqing 0.37 3 0.31 29 1.54 17 0.46 15 18.21 21 2.45 20
guangxi 0.28 22 0.34 27 0.99 23 0.43 18 21.73 19 2.40 21
jilin 0.32 11 0.43 11 1.31 19 0.44 16 17.90 22 2.29 22
yunnan 0.30 17 0.35 24 0.78 26 0.29 25 20.44 20 2.14 23
guizhou 0.23 30 0.33 28 0.78 25 0.29 24 16.55 24 1.84 24
hainan 0.33 6 0.41 14 2.15 14 0.05 30 5.59 28 1.71 25
neimenggu 0.32 8 0.39 18 0.41 28 0.35 20 14.83 25 1.50 26
gansu 0.28 21 0.31 30 0.39 29 0.16 27 13.38 26 1.32 27
xinjiang 0.32 9 0.35 25 0.41 27 0.19 26 12.79 27 1.30 28
ningxia 0.31 12 0.36 23 1.31 18 0.10 28 5.55 29 1.23 29
qinghai 0.30 16 0.41 15 0.11 30 0.06 29 3.47 30 0.36 30

Fig. 2. Night light distribution in 2017 and the urbanization level rank of China.

5
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Fig. 3. The scale of provincial shadow economy from 2008 to 2017 of China.

other, especially the top one Shanghai. The top 9 are provinces that all 3.2.3. Other Variables
come from the east part of China. From the 10th to the 20th, provinces Economic Development: As one of the component parts of the total
mostly come from the middle part of China, while provinces from the GDP, the size of shadow economy is inextricably linked to the economic
21st to the last mostly comes from the west part. This result is highly development and progress. Therefore, the actual GDP growth rate will
consistent with the actual economic situation of China. The detailed be applied to be one of the explanatory variables. The calculation pro­
proportions for each indicator are 1.26% (Population and Employment), cess is using the difference between the current actual GDP and the
1.56% (Consumption Ability), 58.18% (Living Condition), 31.27% (Indus­ actual GDP of the previous period to divide the actual GDP of the pre­
trialization), and 7.73% (Education). Due to the above weights, the rank vious period. The squared actual GDP growth rate will also be applied in
of the urbanization level for each province is highly related to living this article to verify the ECK assumption.
condition indicator. The weight of industrialization indicator is lying Energy Consumption: Plenty of articles have been proved that en­
second. The night light data object itself under the living condition in­ ergy consumption is highly related to the scale of shadow economy. this
dicator has been used by many articles to study urbanization level (Ch paper employs the entropy weight method to calculate the value. The
et al., 2020; Ma et al., 2012; Stokes and Seto, 2019; Wang et al., 2020; Yi indicators are the consumptions of coal, gasoline, diesel, fuel oil, natural
et al., 2016), which can explain the highest weight of the living condi­ gas, and electricity.
tion indicator. To make it clearer, Fig 2 lists the urbanization rank for Foreign Direct Investment: Foreign direct investment can also
each province and the nigh light distribution of China in 2017, which are easily lead to shadow economy. After all, the higher the level of ur­
highly consistent with each other. banization is, the more foreign investment tends to be. However, the
influence from FDI can also be ambiguous. Based on Elgin and Oyvat
3.2.2. Shadow Economy (2013), international trades may not be helpful when comes to gov­
As the other important variables in this article that is shadow ernment supervision for shadow production. In this paper, the logged
economy, the measurement can be exceedingly difficult given its clan­ value of FDI is applied.
destine characteristic. This article will apply the prevalent measurement The Tertiary Industry: The development of urbanization stands for
method called the Multiple Indicators Multiple Causes (MIMIC) method the development of tertiary industry. The transformation from indus­
(Frey and Weck-Hanneman, 1984). The calculation process and data trialization to tourist city is the general process of urbanization. Besides,
resource are consistent with the ones of Pang et al. (2020) and Pang tertiary industry is highly related to shadow economy, too. For example,
et al. (2021), which is also shown in Appendix A. The calculated scale of tourism is prone to irregular fees and often uses cash, giving shadow
shadow economy on GDP are shown in Fig. 3. economy a run for its money. Even consumers tend to use cash to avoid
To sum up, the size of shadow economy for each province lies be­ taxes. In this study, the actual proportion of the tertiary industry on GDP
tween 8% to 25% from 2008 to 2017. Anhui is lying first with the is employed.
smallest size while Heilongjiang is lying last with the largest size. the Environmental Regulation: The impact of environmental regula­
differences within each province from years to years are relatively small, tion on shadow economy is self-evident and has been proved by plenty
except for provinces including Qinghai, Hebei, Guangdong, Beijing, and literatures (Baksi and Bose, 2010; Chen et al., 2018; Mazhar and Elgin,
Heilongjiang. Based on the above results, the size of shadow economy in 2013). This paper uses the provincial proportion of the total investments
China is hard to be ignored and deserves more public attentions. in environmental pollution management on GDP to respect

6
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Table 3
Short-Run Dynamic panel-data estimation, two-step system GMM
Dependent Variables: se
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

se(-1) 0.7517*** 0.6551*** 0.6563*** 0.3050* 0.5916*** 0.4197**


(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.064) (0.000) (0.028)
urban 0.0042* 0.0083* 0.0079 0.0498* 0.0143** 0.0112*
(0.087) (0.096) (0.110) (0.067) (0.033) (0.059)
urban_s -0.0005* -0.0008* -0.0008* -0.0033* -0.0011** -0.0009**
(0.072) (0.059) (0.076) (0.066) (0.022) (0.024)
GDPgr 3.0025*** 3.1360*** 2.1715 0.7310 0.7549
(0.001) (0.000) (0.304) (0.454) (0.614)
GDPgr_s -14.6179*** -15.2599*** -14.4819 -8.3000 -13.5855
(0.001) (0.001) (0.191) (0.296) (0.247)
ev 0.0011 0.0231 0.0029 0.0005
(0.789) (0.293) (0.420) (0.920)
lnFDI -0.0300* -0.0089** -0.0059
(0.041) (0.017) (0.232)
Tigr 0.9679** 0.2797
(0.014) (0.355)
er -0.2292
(0.725)
cons 0.0343*** -0.0972** -1.0495** 0.0250 0.0329 0.0945**
(0.000) (0.046) (0.031) (0.817) (0.391) (0.009)
speed of adjustment γ 0.2483 0.2990 0.3437 0.6950 0.3424 0.5803

AR(1) -2.28 -2.00 -1.99 -1.31 -2.48 -1.89


(0.023) (0.045) (0.047) (0.189) (0.013) (0.059)
AR(2) 0.68 -1.01 -1.08 -0.23 -1.07 1.13
(0.496) (0.314) (0.281) (0.821) (0.283) (0.256)
Hansen 0.38 2.57 2.37 0.10 0.76 0.41
(0.943) (0.276) (0.124) (0.748) (0.685) (0.814)

Notes: *, **, *** represent statistically significant at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The z-values are in parentheses. The GMM estimators are obtained by Stata
module xtabond2 (Roodman, 2009), which is a non-commercial and downloadable program module on Statistical Software Components (SSC).

Table 4
Long-Run panel-data estimation, two-step system GMM
Dependent Variables: se
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

urban 0.0043 0.0022 0.0016 0.0118* 0.0127** 0.0139**


(0.525) (0.697) (0.690) (0.063) (0.027) (0.019)
urban^2 -0.0005 -0.0005 -0.0047 -0.0011** -0.0011*** -0.0013***
(0.402) (0.340) (0.176) (0.015) (0.008) (0.005)
GDPgr 2.2323* 2.1049** 2.3877** 1.6615 1.9876**
(0.075) (0.023) (0.011) (0.205) (0.011)
GDPgr^2 -26.7536*** -25.9637*** -27.9305*** -23.3874** -24.0062***
(0.007) (0.001) (0.000) (0.035) (0.003)
ev -0.0085 -0.0030 -0.0023 -0.0036
(0.319) (0.653) (0.671) (0.599)
lnFDI -0.0067** -0.0075** -0.0083***
(0.034) (0.013) (0.004)
TIgr 0.4636 -0.2371
(0.369) (0.660)
er -0.8256
(0.192)
cons 0.1364*** 0.1394*** 0.1567*** 0.1453*** 0.1302** 0.1887***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.027) (0.001)

AR(1) -1.68 -1.44 -1.72 -1.86 -2.24 -2.86


(0.093) (0.151) (0.086) (0.063) (0.025) (0.004)
AR(2) -0.65 1.04 1.11 1.14 1.42 0.88
(0.516) (0.298) (0.265) (0.254) (0.155) (0.381)
Hansen 2.24 2.70 1.71 1.87) 2.03 1.29)
(0.135) (0.440) (0.425) (0.601) (0.363) (0.525)

Notes: *, **, *** represent statistically significant at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The z-values are in parentheses. The GMM estimators are obtained by Stata
module xtabond2 (Roodman, 2009), which is a non-commercial and downloadable program module on Statistical Software Components (SSC).

environmental regulation. 4. Estimation Results

4.1. GMM Estimation-symmetric effects analysis

The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) (Hasen, 1982) will be


applied for the analysis of the non-threshold but symmetric effects on

7
J. Pang et al.
Table 5
Short-Run Dynamic Panel Threshold Models
Dependent variables: se Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
lower upper lower upper lower upper lower upper lower upper lower upper

se(-1) -0.0753** 0.4258*** -0.9177*** 0.3650*** -0.4944*** 0.5189*** -1.0764*** 0.4283*** -0.3725 0.3665*** -0.6803*** 0.4725***
(0.042) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.128) (0.004) (0.005) (0.000)
urban 0.2037** 0.0657 6.6268*** 0.0618*** 4.2852*** 0.2107*** 2.5693** 0.0063*** 2.4153 0.7340 2.6516** 0.0880**
(0.025) (0.119) (0.002) (0.001) (0.000) (0.002) (0.013) (0.004) (0.117) (0.269) (0.032) (0.040)
urban^2 -0.1502** -0.0035** -6.2223*** -0.0033*** -3.7484*** -0.0093*** -0.9815 -0.0022 -2.4093 -0.0348 -1.8822** -0.0057**
(0.024) (0.027) (0.006) (0.006) (0.003) (0.003) (0.263) (0.260) (0.152) (0.157) (0.010) (0.010)
GDPgr 1.2279** 0.0673* 1.1343*** 0.0434* 0.4257 1.4837 1.2349* 0.2424 0.1244 0.1260
(0.023) (0.056) (0.002) (0.074) (0.456) (0.249) (0.073) (0.168) (0.879) (0.999)
GDPgr^2 -4.1624** -0.7990 -4.4329*** -1.3888 -0.4309 -5.4615 -4.4673* -1.8065 -2.1056 -1.7727
(0.047) (0.180) (0.003) (0.285) (0.859) (0.267) (0.097) (0.404) (0.616) (0.959)
ev -0.0440 -0.0269 0.0655** -0.0781*** 0.0475 -0.0158 0.1268* 0.1259
(0.102) (0.616) (0.040) (0.002) (0.185) (0.280) (0.050) (0.994)
lnFDI 0.0051 -0.0460*** -0.0170* -0.1026*** -0.0218** -0.0460
8

(0.774) (0.000) (0.094) (0.001) (0.021) (0.145)


TIgr -0.3647 0.1101* 0.2179 0.4385
(0.150) (0.079) (0.258) (0.265)
er -2.8158*** 0.7399***
(0.001) (0.001)
cons 0.1200 0.9907** 0.6571* 0.8060*** 0.1349 -2.7191***
(0.910) (0.012) (0.051) (0.000) (0.683) (0.001)
speed of adjustment γ 1.075 0.574 1.918 0.635 1.494 0.481 2.076 0.572 1.373 0.634 1.680 0.527
r 1.0816*** 0.8776*** 0.8776*** 1.0816* 0.8776*** 2.0274***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.067) (0.000) (0.000)
% of lower regime 75.96% 66.89% 66.89% 75.96% 66.89% 77.83%

Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514


95% conf. interval of r [0.8757, 1.2875] [0.7983, 0.9569] [0.7170, 1.0382] [0.0740, 2.2372] [0.5490, 1.2061] [1.2582, 2.7967]
# of moment conditions 116 204 256 316 344 396
linearity test (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Notes: *, **, *** represent statistically significant at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The z-values are in parentheses. The dynamic panel threshold estimators are obtained using Stata module xthenreg (Seo et al.,
2019), which is a non-commercial and downloadable program module on Statistical Software Components (SSC). Please note that the module xthenreg returns the coefficients and z-values of the lower regime and the
difference (between the lower regime and the upper regime). The coefficients of upper regime are calculated, and the z-values are the z-values of the difference.
J. Pang et al.
Table 6
Long-Run Panel Threshold Models
Dependent variables: se Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
Lower Upper Lower Upper Lower Upper Lower Upper Lower Upper Lower Upper

urban 1.6966*** 0.0711*** 0.4197** 0.1451 2.2934** -0.0599** 4.2239*** 0.2999*** 4.4643*** 0.0136*** 3.9210** 0.1260**
(0.000) (0.000) (0.025) (0.132) (0.014) (0.010) (0.001) (0.0020) (0.002) (0.002) (0.019) (0.015)
urban^2 -2.1165*** -0.0044*** -0.2941** -0.0068** -0.8798 0.0025 -2.3528** -0.0160** -2.9211** -0.0030** -4.0323** -0.0075**
(0.000) (0.000) (0.017) (0.020) (0.250) (0.248) (0.029) (0.0300) (0.019) (0.019) (0.034) (0.034)
GDPgr 0.1272*** 0.2859 0.9185*** 0.3394*** 0.4432** 0.0987 0.0299 0.1170 -0.8924*** 0.3900**
(0.003) (0.100) (0.000) (0.003) (0.021) (0.2750) (0.896) (0.786) (0.005) (0.019)
GDPgr^2 -0.1516 -2.2738*** -1.5288*** -2.7727*** -0.9518** -0.3351 -0.1129 -0.3151 2.2909*** -2.1256***
(0.123) (0.000) (0.000) (0.008) (0.013) (0.3490) (0.807) (0.746) (0.003) (0.001)
ev -0.0523** 0.0157*** -0.0714*** 0.0093* -0.0711** -0.0104 0.0144 0.1213**
(0.044) (0.002) (0.004) (0.0820) (0.032) (0.258) (0.532) (0.031)
lnFDI -0.0057 -0.0551*** 0.0241*** -0.0511*** 0.0057 -0.0764***
(0.153) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.279) (0.000)
9

TIgr 0.3446*** -0.0446*** 0.7215*** 0.0491***


(0.002) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
er -0.4088 0.3627
(0.351) (0.464)
cons -0.4745*** (0.6811) *** 1.2056*** 1.6973*** 1.8037*** 0.3916
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.391)
r 1.0816*** 2.0645*** 0.9518** 0.9147*** 0.9147*** 0.8961***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.021) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
% of lower regime 75.96% 79.38% 72.15% 69.45% 69.45% 68.27%
95% conf. Interval of r [1.0717, 1.0915] [1.9377, 2.1914] [0.1411, 1.7624] [0.5761, 1.2533] [0.5432, 1.2862] [0.6204, 1.1718]

Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514


# of moment conditions 90 171 216 261 288 315
linearity test (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Notes: *, **, *** represent statistically significant at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The z-values are in parentheses. The dynamic panel threshold estimators are obtained using Stata module xthenreg (Seo et al.,
2019), which is a non-commercial and downloadable program module on Statistical Software Components (SSC). Please note that the module xthenreg returns the coefficients and z-values of the lower regime and the
difference (between the lower regime and the upper regime). The coefficients of upper regime are calculated, and the z-values are the z-values of the difference.
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

the size of shadow economy, which has been widely used for symmetric value of the magnitude is 0.0149 for the short term and 0.0075 for the
analysis (Zhang et al., 2019). Table 3 and Table 4 list the GMM esti­ long term. The effect in the short term is stronger as the magnitude is
mation results that given by Equ. (2) and Equ. (8). The short-run dy­ relatively larger. Most statistically significant coefficients of the tertiary
namics are shown in Table 3, while the long-run results are reported in industry carry positive signs, signifying the increase of the shadow
Table 4. The advantage of GMM is that it can correct the bias from economy scale. In general, cash transaction can be quite common in the
potentially endogenous problems caused by instrumenting endogenous tertiary industry, which can be a large component of shadow economy
variables, such as the lagged ones. Afterall, searching for valid external as easy taxes evasion. Especially in China, where illegal peddlers do
instruments can be exceedingly difficult. The system GMM estimator is business in tourist attractions due to non-standard management system.
better than the difference GMM estimator as it allows more instrument The negative sign of the environmental regulation shows that the scale
variables to make the results more efficient. To be more specific, the of shadow economy can be controlled by the environmental regulation.
two-step system GMM estimator is better than the one-step system GMM But either of the coefficients are statistically significant, meaning that
estimator, which does not consider the heteroscedasticity. To sum up, the symmetric effects from environmental regulation are not obvious.
this article will employ the two-step system GMM estimator.
The dependent variables are shadow economy for both Table 3 and 4.2. Dynamic Panel Threshold Estimation- asymmetric effects analysis
Table 4. Columns (1) to (6) presents results by adding the key explan­
atory variables one by one. The statistically significant AR(1) test and Table 5 and Table 6 report the estimation results for the asymmetric
statistically insignificant AR(2) test prove no self-correlation problems panel threshold model given by Equ. (6) and Equ. (9), respectively. The
in any of the error terms among those models. Also, the statistically short-run dynamics are shown in Table 5, while the long-run results are
insignificant Hansen test indicates the effectiveness of the chosen in­ reported in Table 6. This study names the urban (urbanization level) as
strument variables. the transition variable. And the threshold value is shown as r, which is
Firstly, the short-term results in Table 3 show that the lagged shadow procured through a grid search of the transition variable over the range
economy has positive and statistically significant effects on the current between the 15th and 85th percentiles. The 95% confidence interval for
size of shadow economy. The current size can be hardly removed within the estimation of the threshold parameter is obtained with the method
a short period and therefore can be greatly affected by previous situa­ proposed by (Hansen, 1999). The situations will be summarized as the
tion, which can also be called as the accumulating impacts. The speed of lower or upper regime once the magnitude of the transition variable is
adjustment, γ, ranges between 24.8% and 69.5%. These results indicate less than (including equaled value) or greater than the estimated
that the previous scale of shadow economy can increase at least 30.5% of threshold magnitude. The bottom line of the table is the p-value of the
the current scale within a year. bootstrap test of linearity. The null hypothesis is H0 : β1 = β2 , against
Secondly, urbanization level has a positive effect while the squared the alternative hypothesis: H1 : β1 ∕ = β2 2. The number of bootstrapping
urbanization level shows a negative effect on the size of shadow econ­ for linearity test in this study is 1,000. Explanatory variables are added
omy, indicating an inversed U-shaped relationship, for both short-term one by one under Model 1 to Model 6 under respective columns.
and long-term estimation. For the statistical significance of the co­ The coefficients under lower regimes for the first lagged shadow
efficients, the ones of the short-term outputs are more significant than economy are negative while the ones under upper regimes are positive.
the ones of the long-term outputs. For the magnitudes of the coefficients, All the coefficients are statistically significant at least at 0.05 level,
the mean value of the urbanization level and its square in the short run/ except the one for lower regime under Model 5. In that case, the current
long run are 0.0160/0.0078 and -0.0012/-0.0015, respectively. 1% in­ scale of shadow economy will be affected negatively by the previous
crease of the urbanization level will lead to 1.60% increase of the situation when urbanization level is under or equal to the threshold
shadow economy’s size in the short term and 0.78% increase in the long value. And the situation will be reversed when the urbanization level
term. As the scale and speed accelerate during the beginning of urban­ reaches and exceeds the threshold value. In all the six models, the speeds
ization process, the size of shadow economy can easily get increased. of adjustment under lower regimes are at least twice bigger than the
Afterall, the unsound economic system can lead to various consequences ones under upper columns.
to the market. Non-standard competition may result in more pressures The opposite signals of the coefficients between urbanization level
coming from high cost. However, when the development of urbanization and its squared term confirm the relationship with an inversed U-shape
reaches to a certain extent, the scale of shadow economy can be fully of urbanization with the scale of shadow economy, not only for both
managed with the sound economy system. lower and upper regimes but also for both short-rung and long-run
Thirdly, there is an inversed U-shaped relationship between eco­ estimation, except the coefficient for the upper regime under Model 3
nomic growth and the scale of shadow economy as well, which is in Table 6. The size of shadow economy will be redoubled as the
consistent with the EKC assumption. During the beginning of the eco­ development of urbanization, especially during the beginning. But when
nomic development, shadow economy will increase along with the the urbanization level reaches to the point where the economic system is
official economy. But the developed economic system can prevent from well-developed and the regulations are strong, the scale of shadow
the above situation, as the differences between the developing countries economy can be effectively controlled. The above phenomenon is well
and the developed countries. The coefficient under the long-term esti­ explained by the difference between the developed countries and the
mation is more statistically significant than the one under the short-term developing countries. The coefficients in the long-run results are more
estimation. Like the urbanization, the impact from economic develop­ statistically significant than the ones in the short run, indicating that the
ment on the scale of shadow economy tends to reflect more in the long inversed U-shape tends to happen more in long-term effects, which is
run. The mean values of the economic growth and its squared term are opposite with the short-term preference results in GMM estimation. To
1.9592/2.0748 and -13.2490/-25.6083 for the short run/long run, sum up, the symmetry tends to happen in the short-term relationship
respectively. while the asymmetry tends to happen in the long-term relationship. The
None of the coefficients of the energy consumption is statistically magnitudes for the coefficients in the short run/ long run of urban for
significant or shows opposite effects in the short-term and long-term the lower regime are 3.1253/ 2.8365, for the upper regime are 0.1944/
outcomes. In this empirical analysis, there is no strong evidence com­ 0.1311. The magnitudes for the coefficients in the short run/ long run of
ing from the estimation results to prove the effect from energy con­ the squared urban for the lower regime are -2.5657/ -0.2099, for the
sumption on the scale of shadow economy. On the contrary, the
coefficients for the FDI are negative and statistically significant at least
at the 0.1 level, indicating that FDI can be helpful when comes to the 3
Monte Carlo simulation studies will be conducted for bootstrap-based
shadow economy management in both short and long terms. The mean testing procedure. For details, please see (Seo et al., 2019).

10
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

upper regime are -0.0098/ -0.0075. The short-run impacts are stronger level may come with tough competition and a lot of pressures, and
than the long-run impacts. companies will face more cost coming from environmental protection.
Economic growth also has an inversed U-shaped relationship with Strengthening regulations may lead to more shadow productions with
shadow economy as the coefficients of GDPgr are positive while the ones which companies can keep profits.
for GDPgr_s are negative, which are consistent with both symmetric and
asymmetric analysis for both short term and long term. The only dif­ 4.3. Comparation
ference is the coefficients under Model 6 for lower regime in Table 6.
Some costs must be paid during the beginning of economic develop­ Based on the above results, the contributions of this study can be
ment, such as illegal economic activities spring up by taking advantages proved. First, this is the first study that analyses both the short-run and
of unsound economic system, which will be improved with development long-run relationship between urbanization and shadow economy. The
of economy. As for urbanization, this situation is beautifully illustrated results are consistent with the previous studies. Second, this is also the
in the comparison of status quo between developing countries and first study that analyzes both symmetric and asymmetric relationship
developed countries. The coefficients in the short-run results are less between urbanization and shadow economy. the results are also
statistically significant than the ones in the long-run results, indicating consistent with the previous studies. To sum up the above two contri­
that the asymmetric inverted U-shaped relationship tends to exist in the butions, this study proves the robustness of the previous conclusions
long term, which is consistent with the symmetric GMM estimation re­ about the relationship between shadow economy and urbanization
sults. The average magnitude of the GDPgr in the short run/ long run for through new aspects: short-run/ long-run aspect and symmetric/
lower regime and upper regime are 0.8294/ 0.1253 and 0.3926/ 0.2462, asymmetric aspect. Third, this study also uses new sub catalogs under
respectively. The average magnitude of the GDPgr_s in the short run/ entropy weight method to calculate urbanization. As current research
long run for lower regime and upper regime are -3.1198/ -0.0908 and does not have consistent official calculation of the level of urbanization,
-2.2457/ -1.5645, respectively. As the results of urbanization, the short- the sub catalogs this study applies can make contributions. Many
term effects are stronger than the long-term effects. research only uses urban population to define urbanization level, which
Only few coefficients for energy consumption in the short-term is obviously not enough. Industrialization is also another popular indi­
analysis are statistically significant. According to three coefficients cator for urbanization level measurement. However, the current devel­
with high significance, conclusions can be drawn that energy con­ oping pattern of metropolis is industrial restructuring, that is the
sumption has negative effect for the lower regime while has positive transition from the secondary industry to the tertiary industry. There­
effect for the upper regime. The signals under the long-term analysis are fore, the determining factor of urbanization should be redefined. In this
consistent with the ones for the short-term analysis. Therefore, when the study, the night light data object under the living condition indicator
urbanization level is low, the increasing of energy consumption can be plays the most important role, which has been used by many articles to
helpful for the controlling of shadow economy but turns to be harmful study urbanization level (Ch et al., 2020; Ma et al., 2012; Stokes and
when the urbanization level reaches to the turning point. The co­ Seto, 2019; Wang et al., 2020; Yi et al., 2016), along with many other
efficients in the long-term analysis are much more statistically signifi­ objects to fully cover all important influence factors. In that case, the
cant. In that case, the effects from energy consumption on the scale of calculated measurement of urbanization in this study has been proved to
shadow economy tends to be a long-run relationship. be more comprehensive.
In the short-term asymmetric analysis, the statistically significant
coefficients of FDI show positive effects on the scale of shadow economy, 5. Conclusion
both for lower regime and upper regime. In the long-term asymmetric
results however, the effect for the lower regime is positive while for the This study investigates the effect of the urbanization level on the
upper regime is negative. In fact, the influence of FDI on economic scale of shadow economy by applying the panel data for each province of
development has always been two-sided. On the one hand, FDI can bring China from 2008 to 2017. In particular, this research proposes brand
high technologies and effective equipment, which will be beneficial to new empirical analysis approaches by modelling short-term and long-
the development of both economy and society. On the other hand, FDI term outcomes in both symmetries and asymmetries aspects. Two
often comes along with more polluted industries importing to devel­ quality specifications, MIMIC and entropy weight theory are utilized
oping countries to achieve self-profitability at the expense of the envi­ respectively to estimate the top two variables, the scale of shadow
ronment over there. economy and the urbanization level. Other variables including the
The coefficients of the tertiary industry in the long run are more economic growth, energy consumption, FDI, tertiary industry and the
statistically significant than the ones in the short run, indicating that the environmental regulation has also been estimated for their effects on the
effects from tertiary industry are inclined to have long-term properties. scale of shadow economy. Most of the previous studies mainly focus on
Except the one under Model 5 of Table 6 for the upper regime, most pollution, climate change or official economy, yet rare research has
positive signals demonstrate that tertiary industry has positive effects on analyzed the relationship between shadow economy and urbanization,
the scale of shadow economy, which is consistent with the symmetric as the situation that two of them are both common in the developing
analysis. Overusing of cash in the tertiary industry can provide plenty of countries can scarcely be coincidence.
opportunities for the development of shadow economy. It is not saying The results from the estimation show that the differences between
that all cash transaction will be summed up as part of shadow economy. the symmetric and asymmetric analyses are rarely small, for both short
Only because cash transactions can be difficult to trace therefore can run and long run. The urbanization level does influence the scale of
easily evade taxes, which will be included as components of shadow shadow economy, which is an inversed U-shaped relationship in
economy. particular. The urbanization level will firstly increase the size of shadow
The asymmetric effect of environmental regulation in the short-run economy then decrease the size when its development process reaches to
outcome is statistically significant at 0.01 level, while the one in the the turning point. The differences between developed countries and
long-run outcome is not. The influence from environmental regulation developing countries in consideration of the above two situations
tends to show more in the short term. Compared with symmetric anal­ confirm this result. Also, this paper proves the EKC relationship between
ysis, the asymmetric results show opposite effects when the urbanization the scale of shadow economy and economic growth. The beginning of
is lower (with equaled value) or higher than the threshold value. For economic growth must take some consequences for fast development
places with lower urbanization level, the implementation of environ­ rate, and widespread shadow economy is one of those consequences. But
mental regulation is helpful to control the scale of shadow economy, but this situation will be controlled and then eliminated when the sound
not for places with higher urbanization level. Developed urbanization regulation system has been established along with developed economy.

11
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Those above two results are consistent in both symmetric and asym­ shadow sectors when living in urban areas.
metric analyses for both short run and long run. The symmetric effect In the later stage during the development of urbanization, its impacts
from energy consumption on shadow economy is not statistically sig­ on the scale of shadow economy are generally negative. First, industri­
nificant and shows opposite results between short run and long run, so alization process and technology development: The industrialization
does the asymmetric effect. The influences from energy consumption process and the development of science and technology have two-side
may be complicated therefore hard to be summarized. The effect from influences. In the early stage, as mentioned above, it will help the ur­
FDI is mainly positive, indicating that FDI is not beneficial in view of banization to increase the scale of shadow economy, but in the later
controlling shadow economy. Tertiary industry primarily shows positive stage during the development of urbanization, it will help the urbani­
impact on shadow economy, while environmental regulation shows zation to decrease the scale of the shadow economy. First, the growth of
negative symmetric impact. In the asymmetric analysis, environmental urbanized population will further increase the pressure of urban life,
regulation reveals negative effect for the lower regime but positive effect thus reducing the migration of rural population to urban area. Second,
for the upper regime. rural laborers who live in urban will accumulate wealth over time,
eliminating their needs to engage in shadow productions, which are
5.1. Theoretical Contributions risky and have no basic insurances. Technological development will
reduce labor demand but also increase production efficiency, increasing
5.1.1. Why urbanization can influence shadow economy rural incomes and eliminating the needs to work in urban area in the
A large part of the urbanization process is reflected in the migration long run. In addition, China has a huge population base, with the rapidly
of rural population to urban areas. The impact of this phenomenon on economic development rates in China during recent years, people’s
shadow economy can be roughly divided into pull and push factors, living standards have improved greatly, leading to the increases in the
which has been studied by many previous research. In view of the demands for total grain productions. The government has also imple­
inversed U-shaped impacts of urbanization on shadow economy, this mented a series of policies to support and subsidize agricultural pro­
paper will analyze why the impact of urbanization on the scale of ductions. In addition, the rapid development of the internet and various
shadow economy will switch overtime with the development of livestreaming platforms in China has also provided farmers with more
urbanization. ways to sell their products. Combined with the prosperity of China’s
In the early stage during the development of urbanization, its im­ postal service and express delivery industry, even during natural di­
pacts on the scale of shadow economy are generally positive. First, sasters, rural labors can still sell agricultural products throughout the
driven from the advantages of urbanization: The development of ur­ country or even overseas in the form of live broadcasting and express
banization will bring people many benefits. First, there will be more and delivery, which increases incomes but greatly reduces losses at the same
diversified employment opportunities, making it easier for people to time. But those above transactions can easily evade supervisions from
find satisfying working opportunities. Secondly, the income levels in government and go under shadow sections.
urban are generally much higher than those of rural areas. Finally, ur­ Second, capital accumulation: Traditional economic production ac­
banization will also provide more, better, and comprehensive social tivities are more likely to include shadow production, such as handicraft
services, making living conditions in urban area more comfortable and productions and traditional industrial activities. The impact of the
pleasant. Specifically in China, Hukou system has brought urban life emergence of large enterprises on traditional economic activities can be
with more significant advantages over rural life. Urban hukou can enormous. Large firms prefer capital monopoly because it can help them
provide more conveniences in aspects including but not limited to ed­ increase revenues while reducing risks. The process of capital concen­
ucation, health care, and housing purchase, which are the most impor­ tration is also known as Monopoly Capital (Foster et al., 2011).
tant three influence factors for living standard. Therefore, the various Compared with small firms that are easier to process shadow produc­
advantages of urban will attract many rural labors to migrate to urban tion, large firms have the advantages with higher capital storage, more
area. However, the rural labors often lack education level and profes­ diversified products, stronger research and development, wider access
sional skills, yet cannot compete with the urban labor force, therefore to information and more government supports. Therefore, it is difficult
are difficult to find satisfy positions. In addition, urban life is superior for small and medium-sized enterprises to survive under the squeeze
but also expensive, forcing rural labor to turn to shadow section to from large enterprises, which then reduces the opportunities for small
support family. In particular, the wages of many shadow sections in and medium-sized enterprises to carry out shadow productions.
urban are no less than those of official jobs, which, coupled with low Third, marketing: Marketing is the product of the development of the
entry barriers and no training requirements, are more attractive to rural new era, the development of marketing makes many traditional pro­
labor force. ductions gradually replaced by emerging markets. Traditional pro­
Second: environmental pollution: The development of urbanization ductions, as mentioned above, often involves a certain amount of
may also lead to climate change and heavy pollution. The government shadow economy. Compared with homogeneous conventional pro­
will then formulate environmental regulations to forbit that yet giving ductions, emerging markets are more diverse and therefore are easier to
companies more pressures for environmental protection. As the primary attract young consumers.
purpose of any companies is benefits, they would rather conduct shadow
production even they have to weigh between cost saving and expensive 5.1.2. Significances on asymmetric
punishment. In the symmetric results, the coefficients of urbanization and its
Third, industrialization process and technology development: The square term in the short term are 0.0160 and -0.0012, respectively. The
process of industrialization is a very important factor to promote the ones in the long term are 0.0078 and -0.0015, respectively. Therefore,
process of urbanization. And the degree of scientific and technological there is not much difference between the symmetric impacts in either
development is closely related to industrialization. In the early stage the short term or the long term when comes to the relationship between
during the development of urbanization, industrialization brings more urbanization and shadow economy, but not the asymmetric impacts.
advanced science and technology to urban areas. And the imbalance of The significance of asymmetry lies in that although the impact of ur­
science and technology progress will lead to the imbalance of income; banization on shadow economy is inverted U-shaped in both the short
The development of industrialization will also lead to decreasing agri­ and long term, the level of the impact is not invariable. In the lower
cultural productions. At the same time, the technological progress regime, before the restructuring point, the short-term effects of urban­
brought by industrial development will greatly improve labor produc­ ization and its squared term are 3.1253 and -2.5657, respectively; The
tivity, thus reducing labor demand, making rural labors have no choice long-term effects are 2.8365 and -2.0994, respectively. However, in the
but to migrate to urban areas. And rural labor normally engaged in upper regime, after the restructuring point, the short-term effects

12
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

become 0.1944 and -0.0098, while the long-term effects become 0.0993 population, solving the difficulties for rural labor to find formal and
and -0.0059. By comparison, although there is an inverted U-shaped legal jobs in cities. As the World Bank says, the ultimate goal of ur­
relationship both before and after the restructuring point, the co­ banization is to create a sustainable green city community.
efficients can vary greatly, and the magnitudes of the coefficients before
the restructuring point are much higher than those after the restruc­ 5.3. Limitations
turing point.
Although this paper provides new ideas for the following studies, it
5.2. Practical contributions fails to find out the specific ways of energy consumption’s influence on
shadow economy. Also, the basic assumption of this study is that the
The asymmetric results from this study can provide new ideas for the interaction between shadow economy and pollution is simple linear. But
governance and policy makers on how to control the scale of shadow it could be non-linear interaction relationship between those two, too.
economy caused by the development of urbanization. For example, the Then how urbanization and other influence factors have the non-linear
governances and supervisions of the shadow economy should be espe­ effects on the interaction relationship should be further discussed. Those
cially strengthened before the development of urbanization reaches the can be used as new ideas for the following research.
restructuring point, as during that period the influences can be
remarkably strong. In addition, the threshold method employed in this CRediT author statement
article can accurately find the position of the restructuring point, which
reduces a lot of difficulties for practical implementations. After all, Jingru Pang: Conceptualization, Methodology, Program, Data
perfect symmetric relationships are often absent from any empirical collection, Writing- Original draft preparation.
analysis, which is why many studies use not just one restructuring point, Nan Li: Discussion, Investigation.
but two or even three. And restructuring point exists does not mean that Hailin Mu: Discussion, Supervision, Funding acquisition.
the linear relationship has a fundamental change. For example, in this Xin Jin: Data collection, Program.
paper, the relationship before and after the restructuring point is Ming Zhang: Writing- Reviewing and Editing, Supervision, Program
consistent with each other, the only difference is the slope of the curve. Administration, Funding acquisition.
According to the above analysis, urbanization development in the later
stage is conducive to the suppression of the scale of shadow economy. Acknowledgments
That is why, in the results of this paper, the degree of influences from
urbanization before the restructuring point is higher than that after the The authors would like to gratefully acknowledge the financial
restructuring point. support from National Natural Science Foundation of China (72174195,
Government should also try to reduce the size of shadow economy 51976020, 71603039). We would like to thank the anonymous referees
from the perspective of urbanization. For example, addressing the for their constructive suggestions and valuable comments on the earlier
imbalance in the distribution of urban and rural employment draft of this paper, upon which we have improved the content.

Appendix

A. MIMIC Model

The multiple indicators and multiple indexes model is one kind of structural equation model. The general principle of structural equation model is
to find the indicators and the causes related to the unobservable variable, and then establish the model through the relationship among the three
variables, so as to simulate the observed value of the unobservable variable. It mainly contents two parts: the first part is the structural equation
representing the relationship between the observed data and the causes leading to its generation. The second part is the measurement equation
representing the relationship between the observed data and the indicators that will be affected by it. The formula of the specific equation is shown in
Fig. A1:

α1 β1

α2 β2
Unobservable
Variable
… …

αp βq

Fig A1. Schematic Diagram for MIMIC Model

13
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

The structural equation for MIMIC model is:


X = p1 α1 + p2 α2 + ⋯ + pm αm + ξ (A1)
Where X represents the size of shadow economy, α1, α2 and αm represent the causes that will lead to shadow economy, p1, p2 and pm are the
coefficients, ξ is the random disturbance term.
The measurement equation of MIMIC model is:


⎪ β = q1 X + ε1
⎨ 1
β2 = q2 X + ε2
(A2)

⎪ ⋯

βn = qn X + εn

Where β1, β2 and βn represent indicators that will be affected by shadow economy. q1, q2 and qn are the coefficients, ε1, ε2 and εn are the error terms.
It is assumed that the mean values of random disturbance term ξ and the measurement error term ε are both 0 and independent, and the mea­
surement error term ε is not related to the invisible economy X. Then: E(ξε′ ) = 0, E(ξξ) = θ2 , E(εε ) = σ2 .

Combining Equ. A1 with Equ. A2 to express it in the form of multiple regression equation:

(A3)
′ ′
β = q(p α + ξ) + ε = qp α + qξ + ε = α+μ

Where Σ=qp’ represents the coefficient matrix, μ=qξ+ε represents the disturbance vector. Therefore, the error covariance matrix of the multiple
regression equation can be expressed as:

(A4)
′ ′
E(μμ ) = E(qξ + ε)(qξ + ε) = θ2 qq + σ2
Before estimating β in the equation, it is necessary to presuppose vector q as a certain value before normalization. Normally it will be set as 1.
In this study, there will be five causes (tax, resident income, unemployment rate, self-employment rate, and government regulation) and two
indicators (the actual GDP growth rate and the labor force participation rate). All the data are acquired from China Statistical Yearbook. The detailed
definitions for all the causes and indicators are shown in Table A1.

Table A1
Frey, BS, Weck-Hanneman, H., 1984. The hidden economy as an ’unobserved’ variable.
Detailed definitions for all the causes and indicators European Economic Review 26, 33–53.
tax the percentage of government tax on GDP Goel, RK, Nelson, MA., 2016. Shining a light on the shadows: Identifying robust
determinants of the shadow economy. Economic Modelling 58, 351–364.
resident income per capita disposal income
Hansen, BE., 1999. Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: Estimation, testing, and
unemployment rate unemployment rate for the city
inference. Journal of Econometrics 93, 345–368.
self-employment rate percentage of individual private on total employment
Hao, Y, Zheng, SQ, Zhao, MY, Wu, HT, Guo, YX, Li, YW., 2020. Reexamining the
government regulation the percentage of government expenditures on GDP relationships among urbanization, industrial structure, and environmental pollution
the actual GDP growth the growth rate of the market value of all final products in in China—New evidence using the dynamic threshold panel model. Energy reports 6,
rate the current year calculated using the price of one previous 28–39.
year as the base period Hart, K., 2008. Informal Economy. In: Durlauf, S.N., Blume, L.E. (Eds.), The New
the labor force the percentage of the total employment on the total Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Macmillan, Palgrave.
participation rate population between age 15 to 64 Hasen, L., 1982. Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators.
Econometrica 50, 1029–1054.
Huynh, CM., 2020. Shadow economy and air pollution in developing Asia: what is the
role of fiscal policy? Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 1–25.
References
Ihrig, J, Moe, KS., 2003. Lurking in the shadows: the informal sector and government
policy. Journal of Development Economics 73, 541–577.
Aglietta, M., 1998. A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: The US Experience. Verso, New Kookana, RS, Drechsel, P, Jamwal, P, Vanderzalm, J., 2020. Urbanisation and emerging
York. economies: Issues and potential solutions for water and food security. The Science of
Baksi, S, Bose, P., 2010. Environmental Regulation in the Presence of an Informal Sector. the total environment 732, 139057-139057.
Departmental Working Papers. Lazăr, D, Minea, A, Purcel, A., 2019. Pollution and economic growth: Evidence from
Boyce, JK., 1993. The Philippines: the political economy of growth and impoverishment Central and Eastern European countries. Energy Economics 81, 1121–1131.
in the Marcos era. : The Philippines: the political economy of growth and Li, BQ, Chen, CL, Hu, BL., 2016. Governing urbanization and the New Urbanization Plan
impoverishment in the Marcos era. in China. Environment & Urbanization 28, 515–534.
Ch, R, Martin, DA, Vargas, JF., 2020. Measuring the size and growth of cities using Liu, W, Zhan, JY, Zhao, F, Wei, XQ, Zhang, F., 2021. Exploring the coupling relationship
nighttime light. Journal of Urban Economics. between urbanization and energy eco-efficiency: A case study of 281 prefecture-level
Chen, HY, Hao, Y, Li, JW, Song, XJ., 2018. The impact of environmental regulation, cities in China. Sustainable Cities and Society 64, 102563.
shadow economy, and corruption on environmental quality: Theory and empirical Luo, XM, Sun, K, Li, L, Wu, SM, Yan, D, Fu, XS, et al., 2020. Impacts of urbanization
evidence from China. Journal of Cleaner Production 195, 200–214. process on PM2.5 pollution in "2+26" cities. Journal of Cleaner Production.
Colenbrander, S., 2016. Cities as engines of economic growth: the case for providing Lv, YL, Chen, W, Cheng, JQ., 2020. Effects of urbanization on energy efficiency in China:
basic infrastructure and services in urban areas. International Institute for New evidence from short run and long run efficiency models. Energy Policy 147,
Environment and Development Working. 111858.
Dang, VA, Kim, M, Shin, Y., 2012. Asymmetric capital structure adjustments: New Ma, T, Zhou, CH, Pei, T, Haynie, S, Fan, JF., 2012. Quantitative estimation of
evidence from dynamic panel threshold models. Journal of Empirical Finance 19, urbanization dynamics using time series of DMSP/OLS nighttime light data: A
465–482. comparative case study from China’s cities. Remote Sensing of Environment 124.
Daniels, PW., 2004. Urban challenges: the formal and informal economies in mega-cities. Mazhar, U, Elgin, C., 2013. Environmental regulation, pollution, and the informal
Cities 21, 501–511. economy. SBP Research Bulletin 9, 62–81.
Dong, HM, Xue, MG, Xiao, YJ, Liu, YS., 2021. Do carbon emissions impact the health of McDonald, RI, Weber, K, Padowski, J, Flörke, M, Schneider, C, Green, PA, et al., 2014.
residents? Considering China’s industrialization and urbanization. Science of the Water on an urban planet: Urbanization and the reach of urban water infrastructure.
Total Environment 758. Global Environmental Change 27, 96–105.
Elgin, C, Oyvat, C., 2013. Lurking in the cities: Urbanization and the informal economy. McGranahan, G., 2015. Urbanization. International Encyclopedia of the Social &
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 27. Behavioral Sciences (Second Edition) 958–964.
Elgin, C, Öztunalı, O., 2014. Environmental Kuznets Curve for the Informal Sector of Meng, GF, Guo, Z, Li, JL., 2021. The dynamic linkage among urbanisation,
Turkey (1950-2009). Panoeconomicus 61, 471–485. industrialisation and carbon emissions in China: Insights from spatiotemporal effect.
Fischer, EO, Robert, H, Zechner, J., 1989. Dynamic Capital Structure Choice: Theory and Science of the Total Environment 760.
Tests. The Journal of Finance 44, 19–40. Muñoz, P, Zwick, S, Mirzabaev, A., 2020. The impact of urbanization on Austria’s carbon
Foster, JB, Mcchesney, RW, Jonna, RJ., 2011. Monopoly and Competition in Twenty- footprint. Journal of Cleaner Production 263, 121326.
First Century Capitalism. Monthly Review: An Independent Socialist Magazine 62, 1. Nickell, SJ., 1981. Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects. Econometrica 49.

14
J. Pang et al. Technological Forecasting & Social Change 177 (2022) 121514

Pang, JR, Li, N, Mu, HL, Zhang, M., 2021. Empirical analysis of the interplay between Wu, JS, Cheng, DJ, Xu, YY, Huang, Q, Feng, Z., 2021. Spatial-temporal change of
shadow economy and pollution: With panel data across the provinces of China. ecosystem health across China: Urbanization impact perspective. Journal of Cleaner
Journal of Cleaner Production 285, 124864. Production 326.
Pang, JR, Mu, HL, Zhang, M., 2020. Interaction between shadow economy and pollution: Xu, T, Lv, ZK, Xie, LQ., 2018. Does Country Risk Promote the Informal Economy? A
empirical analysis based on panel data of northeast. China. Environmental Science Cross-National Panel Data Estimation. Global Economic Review 47.
and Pollution Research 27, 21353–21363. Yi, KP, Zeng, Y, Wu, BF., 2016. Mapping and evaluation the process, pattern and
Qiu, G, Song, R, He, SW., 2019. The aggravation of urban air quality deterioration due to potential of urban growth in China. Applied Geography 71, 44–55.
urbanization, transportation and economic development – Panel models with Yu, BL, Shi, KF, Hu, YJ, Huang, C, Chen, ZQ, Wu, JP., 2015. Poverty Evaluation Using
marginal effect analyses across China. Science of The Total Environment 651, NPP-VIIRS Nighttime Light Composite Data at the County Level in China. IEEE
1114–1125. Journal of Selected Topics in Applied Earth Observations and Remote Sensing 8,
Rauch, JE., 1993. Economic Development, Urban Underemployment, and Income 1–13.
Inequality. The Canadian Journal of Economics /Revue canadienne d’Economique Zhang, M, Liu, XX, Ding, YT, Wang, WW., 2019. How does environmental regulation
26. affect haze pollution governance?—An empirical test based on Chinese provincial
Roodman, D., 2009. How to do Xtabond2: An Introduction to Difference and System panel data. Science of the Total Environment 695, 133905.
GMM in Stata. The Stata Journal 9, 86–136. Zhao, JF, Tang, JM., 2018. Industrial structure change and economic growth: A China-
Schneider, F, Buehn, A, Montenegro, C., 2010. Shadow Economies All Over The World: Russia comparison. China Economic Review 47, 219–233.
New Estimates For 162 Countries From 1999 To 2007. The World Bank. Zhao, JJ, Chai, LH., 2015. A novel approach for urbanization level evaluation based on
Seo, MH, Kim, S, Kim, Y., 2019. Estimation of dynamic panel threshold model using information entropy principle: A case of Beijing. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and
Stata. The Stata Journal 19, 1–12. its Applications 430.
Shemshadi, A, Shirazi, H, Toreihi, M, Tarokh, MJ., 2011. A fuzzy VIKOR method for Zhong, C, Hu, RF, Wang, MY, Xue, WH, He, LF., 2020. The impact of urbanization on
supplier selection based on entropy measure for objective weighting. Expert Systems urban agriculture: Evidence from China. Journal of Cleaner Production 276, 112686.
With Applications 38.
Shen, LY, Zhou, JY, Skitmore, M, Xia, B., 2015. Application of a hybrid
Jingru Pang: she is a PhD student at Dalian University of Technology, who majored in
Entropy–McKinsey Matrix method in evaluating sustainable urbanization: A China
energy and environment. Her research interests include shadow economy, environmental
case study. Cities 42.
protection, and urbanization. She has published 2 SCI papers in the field of environmental
Sheng, PF, Zhai, MX, Zhang, YC, Kamal, MA., 2020. The effects of urbanization on
protection.
household wastewater emissions in China: Efficient- and inefficient- emissions.
Environmental Pollution 267, 115350.
Stokes, EC, Seto, KC., 2019. Characterizing urban infrastructural transitions for the Nan Li: he is an associate professor at Dalian University of Technology, who majored in
Sustainable Development Goals using multi-temporal land, population, and energy and environment and received his PhD degree in 2014. He is interest in the research
nighttime light data. Remote Sensing of Environment 234, 111430. of energy supply and demand modeling, technology and policy of greenhouse gas emission
Sun, W, Huang, CC., 2020. How does urbanization affect carbon emission efficiency? reduction, and regional convergence theory demonstration and modeling. He has pub­
Evidence from China. Journal of Cleaner Production 272, 122828. lished more than 25 academic papers.
UN, 2017. Habitat III- New Urban Agenda. http://habitat3.org/(last accessed 16 Dec
2019).
HaiLin Mu: he is a professor at Dalian University of Technology, who got his PhD degree of
UNDESA, 2018. World urbanisation prospects 2018. UN Department of economic and
Internal Combustion Engine in 1994, and PhD degree of engineering in 2004 at Saitama
social affairs: population dynamics. https://population.un.org/wup/(last accessed
University, Japan. He has published more than 100 SCI paper on journals including En­
16 Dec 2019).
ergy, Applied Energy, Energy Policy, and Energy Economics.
Wang, YH, Liu, ZF, He, CY, Xia, P, Liu, ZW, Liu, HM., 2020. Quantifying urbanization
levels on the Tibetan Plateau with high-resolution nighttime light data. Geography
and Sustainability 1. Xin Jin: he is graduate student at Dalian University of Technology, who will receive his
Wang, ZB, Qi, GZ, Wei, WD., 2021. China’s coastal seawater environment caused by master’s degree in 2021. His research interests focus on the regional convergence theory
urbanization based on the seawater environmental Kuznets curve. Ocean and Coastal demonstration and modeling.
Management 213.
Wang, ZH, Yang, ZY, Zhang, B, Li, H, He, WJ., 2021. How does urbanization affect Ming Zhang: he is a professor at China University of Mining and Technology, who received
energy consumption for central heating: Historical analysis and future prospects. his PhD of engineering in 2009. His research interests include low-carbon economy and
Energy and Buildings. environmental management. He has published more than 100 academic papers on journals
WB. The World Bank. Urban Development: Overview. https://www.worldbank. including Journal of Cleaner Production, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Energy
org/en/topic/urbandevelopment/overview (Last accessed 20 April 2020)., 2020. Policy, Ecological Economics, Ecological Indicators, Applied Energy, and Energy.
Wu, HT, Hao, Y, Weng, J., 2019. How does energy consumption affect China’s
urbanization? New evidence from dynamic threshold panel models. Energy Policy
127, 24–38.

15

You might also like