You are on page 1of 81

INFLUENCE OF INFLATION TARGETING ON GROWTH AND EMPLOYMENT IN

AGRICULTURAL SECTOR IN THE PHILIPPINES

Undergraduate Thesis
Submitted to the Faculty of the
College of Economics, Management and Development Studies
Cavite State University
Indang, Cavite

In partial fulfilment
Of the requirements for the degree
Bachelor of Science in Economics

Jeanivhic P. Maragat
Ericka P. Valerio
April 2019
BIOGRAPHICAL DATA

Ericka P. Valerio was born on the 24th of March 1999 in San Carlos City,

Pangasinan. She is the eldest of Mr. Frederic T. Valerio and Mrs. Dorina P. Valerio. She

has one brother whose name is Frederic P.Valerio Jr.

She finished primary education in 2011 at Langkaan Elementary School,

Langkaan 1 Dasmariñas Cavite. She took up her secondary education at St. Joseph

Academy of Dasmariñas Inc. and graduated in 2015.

In June of 2016, she enrolled at Cavite State University, Indang, Cavite and

pursued Bachelor of Science in Economics major in Business Economics. She obtained

the degree in June 2019.


BIOGRAPHICAL DATA

Jeanivhic P. Maragat was born on March 26, 1999 in San Jacinto Victoria Tarlac.

She is the youngest child of Mr. Victor Maragat and Mrs. Jeanette Maragat. Currently

she is residing at 172 Langkaan I, Dasmariñas City, Cavite.

She finished her elementary education at Langkaan Elementary School in the

year 2000 and her secondary education at St. Joseph Academy of Dasmariñas Inc. in

the year 2015. She is pursuing her College in taking up Bachelor of Science in

Economics major in Business Economics at Cavite State University.


ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

The authors would like to express their gratitude first of all to Almighty GOD, for

the streghth and blessings that he provides in order yo finish this study.

Also, the authors would like to show their appreciation to the following persons,

for their countless support, encouragement and contribution in orer to complete the

study:

Ms. Jenny Beb F. Ebo, thesis adviser, for her guidance, support, understanding

and insightful comments, and for all the untiring efforts exerted during the proposal until

the last portion of the study;

Dr. Gilchor P. Cubillo, technical critic, for all the valuable suggestions and effort

in checking the technical aspect of the study;

Mr. Marlon A. Mojica, thesis coordinator and department chair, for her advice,

guidance and insightful comments to improve the study;

Dr. Florindo Ilagan, dean of CEMDS, for his pieces of advice, comments and

encouragement which led to the completion of the study;

The teachers and professors of the university, for the cooperation of sharing their

knowledge and information;

All 4th year economics students, especially Business Economics, for sharing all

the happy and unforgettable memories, hardship moments and the countless thought

they shared;

Their dearest friends to lean on, Belmira Tuazon, Martin Barbarona, Irah

Cabrera, Julienne Escopete, Lhymhel Inguanzo, Elijah Herero, Mathews Ed Ramos,


Angelo Ampado and Jem for the unforgettable ups and downs moments they shared

and for the love and support that they give all the time;

Their beloved families, Jeannette Maragat, Dorina Valerio, Victor Maragat and

Frederic Valerio, for their undying love and support, for providing all their needs

financially and morally, for their patience and understanding during their tiring days, for

their never fading advices and for being there for us no matter what.

Their relatives, for the trust and moral support;

Lastly, to their ALMA MATER, Cavite State University, for making their college

days colorful and wonderful.

To all of them, this piece of work is wholeheartedly dedicated.

THE AUTHORS
ABSTRACT

MARAGAT, JEANIVHIC P., and VALERIO, ERICKA P., “Influence of Inflation


targeting on selected agricultural commodities prices in the Philippines”
Undergraduate Thesis. Bachelor of Science in Economics major in Business Economics,
College of Economics, Management and Development Studies. Cavite State University,
Don Severino delas Alas Campus, Indang, Cavite. April 2019. Adviser: Ms. Jenny Beb F.
Ebo.

Both policymakers and economists increasingly accept that main medium-to

long-run goal of monetary policy is the pursuit of price stability, defined as maintaining a

low and stable rate of inflation. To accomplish the objective of price stability, money

related approach in numerous nations was for quite a while directed by depending on

middle of the road targets, for example, financial totals or exchange rates.This new way

to deal with the issue of controlling inflation through financial arrangement is known as

inflation targeting. It basically makes inflation (as opposed to yield or joblessness) the

essential objective of financial strategy.

This study aimed to seek the influence of inflation targeting on growth and

employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines; to describe the pattern of inflation

rate, GDP and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines, to determine if there

is any significant difference between actual and target inflation rate, and to determine the

significant influence of inflation on growth and employment in agricultural sector.

The data were gathered from the database of Philippine Statistics Authority

(PSA), BangkoSentralngPilipinas (BSP) and Department of Agriculture (DAR). Since the

approach of the research is descriptive- corelational using time series, Simple Linear

Regression was used.

Statistical result showed particularly, t test that the actual and target inflation

using minimum value is significant with t-value of -3.10 at one percent level of
significance and lowest inflation rate experienced by the country is 1.26 percent below

the target inflation while in maximum value the actual and target inflation using maximum

value is significant with t-value of 0.06 at one percent level of significance. The actual

and target inflation rate using maximum value is significant at 0.04 percent which

experience by the country.

However, in testing if inflation targeting can influence the employment and GDP

in agricultural sector, the result of regression showed that there is no influence in

employment and GDP. Furthermore, the result in Durbin Watson test shows that the

inflation targeting, employment and GDP had no serial correlation. Models were not

found to be mis-specified as independent and dependent variables passed the test for

specification error using Ramsey RESET Test.


TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

BIOGRAPHICAL DATA........................................................................................ iii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT........................................................................................ v

ABSTRACT............................................................................................................ vii

LIST OF TABLES.................................................................................................. ix

LIST OF FIGURES................................................................................................. x

LIST OF APPENDIX TABLES............................................................................... xi

LIST OF APPENDIX FIGURES............................................................................. xii

LIST OF APPENDICES......................................................................................... xiii

INTRODUCTION................................................................................................... 1

Statement of the Problem............................................................................ 4

Objective of the Study.................................................................................. 4

Theoretical Framework of the Study............................................................ 5

Conceptual Framework of the Study............................................................ 6

Significance of the Study.............................................................................. 7

Scope and Limitation of the Study............................................................... 7

Definition of Terms....................................................................................... 8

REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE................................................................. 9

METHODOLOGY.................................................................................................. 21

Research Design.......................................................................................... 21

Sources of Data........................................................................................... 21

Null Hypothesis............................................................................................ 21

Statistical Treatment of Data........................................................................ 22


Empirical Model............................................................................................ 22

Research Model........................................................................................... 23

RESULTS AND DISCUSSION..............................................................................

Pattern of Inflation rate, GDP and employment in agricultural


Sector in the Philippines for 2002 to 2017.........................................

Significant difference between actual and target inflation rate..................... 32

Significant influence of inflation targeting on growth and


Employment in agricultural sector......................................................

SUMMARY, CONSLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION..................................... 83

Summary...................................................................................................... 83

Conclusion.................................................................................................... 84

Recommendation......................................................................................... 84

REFERENCES....................................................................................................... 85

APPENDICES........................................................................................................ 87
LIST OF TABLES

Table Page

Philippines actual and target inflation rate in minimum


1
and maximum value........................................................................ 33

T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate


2
using minimum value...................................................................... 34

T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate


3
using maximum value..................................................................... 35

The result of Augmnted Dickey Fuller test of all variables


4
at level form.................................................................................... 37

The result of Augmented Dickey Fuller test of all variables


5
at first difference............................................................................. 38

The result of Augmented Dickey Fuller test of all variables


6
at second difference....................................................................... 40

The regression result using ordinary least square regression


7
on Actual Maximum Inflation........................................................... 41

The regression result using ordinary least square regression


8
on Actual Minimum Inflation............................................................ 41

9 Durbin Watson Statistics result of Employment and GDP........................ 42

10 Ramsey Reset Result of Actual Maximum Inflation.................................. 43

11 Ramsey Reset Result of Actual Minimum Inflation................................... 43


LIST OF FIGURES

Figure Page

Schematic diagram illustrating the influence of inflation


1 targeting on growth and employment in agricultural
sector in the Philippines.................................................................. 5

2 Philippine Inflation Rate, 2002-2017......................................................... 30

3 Philippine Employment and Gross Domestic Product.............................. 33

The graph of the independent and dependent variables at


4
level form........................................................................................ 36

The graph of the independent and dependent variables at


5
first difference................................................................................. 37

The graph of the independent and dependent variables at


6
second difference........................................................................... 39
LIST OF APPENDIX TABLES

Appendix
Table Page

Actual and Target Yearly Inflation Rate at Minimum


1
and Maximum in the Philippines............................................... 6

Total number of employed persons in agriculture


2
by region, Philippines, 2006-2017 (in „000 persons)................. 27

3 Yearly Employment Rate in Agricultural Sector in the Philippines 28

Yearly Economic Growth (GDP) Rate in Agricultural


4
Sector in the Philippines........................................................... 30

T-test result comparing actual and target inflation


5
rate using minimum value......................................................... 32

T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate


6
using maximum value............................................................... 35
LIST OF APPENDIX FIGURES

Appendix
Figure Page

Unit Root Result of all Independent and Dependent


1
Variables at Level Form............................................................ 6

Unit Root Result of all Independent and Dependent


2
Variables at First Difference..................................................... 27

Unit Root Result of all Independent and Dependent


3
Variables at Second Difference................................................ 28

4 Regression Result of all Dependent Variables................................... 30

Durbin Watson Result of all Independent and


5
Dependent Variables................................................................ 32

Ramsey Reset Result of all Independent and Dependent


6
Variables................................................................................... 35
LIST OF APPENDICES

Figure Page

Schematic diagram illustrating the influence of inflation


1 targeting on growth and employment in agricultural
sector in the Philippines.................................................................. 5

2 Philippine Inflation Rate, 2002-2017......................................................... 30

3 Philippine Employment and Gross Domestic Product.............................. 33

The graph of the independent and dependent variables at


4
level form........................................................................................ 36

The graph of the independent and dependent variables at


5
first difference................................................................................. 37

The graph of the independent and dependent variables at


6
second difference........................................................................... 39
INFLUENCE OF INFLATION TARGETING ON GROWTH AND EMPLOYMENT IN
AGRICULTURAL SECTOR IN THE PHILIPPINES

Jeanivhic P. Maragat
Ericka P. Valerio

An undergraduate thesis manuscript submitted to the faculty of the Department of


Economics, College of Economics, Management and Development Studies, Cavite State
University, Indang, Cavite in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of
Bachelor of Science in Economics major in Business Economics with Contribution
No._________________. Prepared under the supervision of Prof. Jenny Beb F. Ebo.

INTRODUCTION

Both policymakers and economists increasingly accept that main medium-to long-

run goal of monetary policy is the pursuit of price stability, defined as maintaining a low

and stable rate of inflation. A high and variable inflation rate is socially and economically

costly. These costs include price distortions, lower savings and investment, hedging, and

capital flight (Agenor, 2001). The attempt to achieve these conflicting goals tends to

generate an inflationary bias in the conduct of monetary policy to achieve higher output

and employment.

To accomplish the objective of price stability, money related approach in

numerous nations was directed to target financial totals or exchange rates. In 1990s,

some countries started to control inflation through financial arrangement known as

“inflation targeting”. This strategy empowered national bank to foresee the future

conduct of costs. (Agenor, 2001) The expansion target gives straightforwardness in the

execution of money related arrangement that empowers budgetary organizations in the

market to predict the future with less vulnerability and carry on appropriately. The

inflation target provides transparency in the implementation of monetary policy that


enables financial institutions in the market to foresee the future with less uncertainty and

behave accordingly.

In the Philippines, inflation target-setting is based on the existing framework for

coordination between economic agencies. The national government, through the

Development Budget Coordinating Committee (DBCC), sets the inflation target based on

the consumer price index (CPI) two years ahead in consultation with the Bangko Sentral

ng Pilipinas (BSP). The BSP has full powers over and responsibility for the

announcement of the inflation target and the determination of appropriate monetary

policy to achieve the target. (Guiniguindo, 2005)

Statement of the Problem

Inflation targeting is a monetary policy where the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas and

the government set a specific inflation rate as its goal and growth is the one who affects

it. Hence the study aimed to determine the influence of inflation targeting on growth and

employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines.

Specifically, it sought to answer the following questions:

1. What is the pattern of inflation rate, GDP and employment in agricultural

sector in the Philippines for 2002 to 2017?

2. Is there a significant difference between actual and target inflation rate?

3. What is the significant influence of inflation targeting on growth and

employment in agricultural sector?

Objectives of the Study


In general, the study aimed to determine the influence of inflation targeting on

growth and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines.

Specifically, it aimed to:


1. Describe the pattern of inflation rate, GDP and employment in agricultural

sector in the Philippines for 2002 to 2017.

2. Determine if there is a significant difference between actual and target

inflation rate.

3. Determine the significant influence of inflation on growth and employment in

agricultural sector.

Theoretical Framework

John Maynard Keynes and his followers emphasized that increased in aggregate

demand as the source of demand-pull inflation. The aggregate demand comprises

consumption, investment and government expenditure. According to Keynes, demand-

pull inflation theory is the policy that causes decrease in each component of total

demand is effective in reduction of pressure demand and inflation. One of the reductions

in government expenditures is tax increase and to control volume of money alone or

together, can be effective in reducing effective demand and inflation control. In difficult

condition, hyperinflation during war that control volume of money or decrease in general

expenditure may not be practical increase in tax can get along with direct action for

control on demand.

Cost-push inflation is caused by wage increases enforced by unions and profit

increases by employers. The basic cause of Cost-push Inflation is the rise in money

wages more rapidly than the productivity of labour. The labour unions press employers

to grant wage increases considerably, thereby raising the cost of production of

commodities. Employers in turn, raise the prices of their products. Higher wages enable

workers to buy as much as before, in spite of higher prices. On the other hand, the

increase in prices induces unions to demand still higher wages. (Totonchi, 2011)
These theories would support the study and simple linear regression analysis

would served as the instrument in measuring the influence of inflation targeting on

growth and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines.

Conceptual Framework

The conceptual framework of the study is shown in Figure 1. The independent

variable is the target and actual inflation rate while the dependent variable is the GDP

and employment.

Figure 1 shows the perceived influence of inflation targeting measured in terms

of actual and target inflation on economic growth. Economic growth was measured in

terms of GDP and employment.

Actual Inflation Target Inflation


(Inflation Rate) (Inflation Rate)

Economic Growth
(GDP, Employment)

Figure 1. Schematic diagram illustrating the influence of inflation targeting on growth


and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines

Significance of the Study

The result of the study would provide information and insights to various sectors:

First, this study would be helpful for instructors to provide factual information about
inflation targeting and it would also serve as a sample in discussing how to conduct a

research study or thesis.

Second, the result of this study would extend the knowledge of the researchers

and students that would provide information and ideas about inflation targeting in the

Philippines. Furthermore, they would also identify the influence of inflation targeting on

growth and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines.

Third, this study would be helpful for future researchers who would be interested

in doing advance research on same topic that would serve as a basis of reference for

conducting a research study.

This study would also be helpful to the citizen of the Philippines to understand

how and why the central bank set target inflation rate and its impact in their decision

making.

Scope and Limitation of the Study

The study focused on the influence of inflation targeting on growth and

employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines. The study was based in Bangko

Sentral ng Pilipinas in determining the target inflation rate in the Philippines, consumer

price index (CPI) is the main basis in determining the target inflation rate. The study

would limit to 16 years (192 months) observation in answering the influence of inflation

targeting on growth and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines and the data

would be analyzed by simple linear regression analysis.

Definition of Terms

Consumer Price Index (CPI) represents the average price for a given period of

a standard basket of goods and services consumed by a typical Filipino family.


Cost-Push Inflation refers to the macroeconomic theories that support the

inflation targeting on agricultural commodities prices in the Philippines.

Demand-Pull Inflation refers to the macroeconomic theories that support the

inflation targeting on agricultural commodities prices in the Philippines.

Economic Growth refers to the increase in the inflation-adjusted market value of

the goods and services produced by an economy over time.

Employment refers to people who perform a service or operations involved in

the production of food, fibber or other agricultural products.

Gross Domestic Product (GDP) refers to the broad measurement of a nation‟s

overall economic activity. It is the monetary value of all the finished goods and services

produced within a country‟s borders in a specific time period.

Inflation Rate refers to the rate of change in the weighted average prices of

goods and services typically purchase by consumer.

Inflation Target refers to the average year-on-year change in the consumer

price index (CPI) over the calendar year. (BSP)


REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE

This chapter presents different literature and related studies. These will

contribute and help the researchers on the direction of the study.

Inflation Rate

Inflation is a well-established fact of life in virtually every economy throughout the

world. Whether slow, moderate, or rapid, an ongoing rise in the average level of prices

has been a prominent feature on the economic landscape of most nations for at least

past 50 years. The continued rise in the price level is the backdrop against which all our

decisions are made. As a result, capital market transactions that involve agreements

extending years or even decades into an unknown future become especially vulnerable

to unexpected changes in the inflation rate.

Most of us also come to think of inflation as a process that lowers our standard of

living every bit as much as unemployment. However, a closer look at the actual costs of

inflation reveals it to be much less damaging than commonly thought. Because higher

prices also become higher money incomes, it is wrong to think that 5 percent inflation

has somehow stolen 5 percent of our nation‟s purchasing power or output. In fact,

excluding huge triple-digit inflations that lead to demonetisation and other inefficiencies,

the main costs of inflation itself come from frequent price changes and the fact that

inflation erodes the real value of money holdings leading us to hold smaller money

balances and thereby creates inefficiencies. Although these costs can‟t be neglected,

they are small in comparison to popular views of cost of inflation. A greater cost is

associated with the variability of inflation as distinct from its level by adding uncertainty

and risk to so many of our decisions, it encourages choices that use scarce resources

and that would not be needed in a world with a morale stable, predictable inflation rate.
Foreign Literature

As is well known, inflation targeting was introduced in New Zealand in 1990. As

Murray (2006) points out, when inflation targeting was implemented in New Zealand, it

was viewed as a special case, because New Zealand was a small open economy that

had just announced a number of audacious reforms. The Policy Targets Agreement was

a creative and reasonable extension of this first wave of reforms. It was designed to lend

more discipline and accountability to the conduct of monetary policy. The Governor

would be given explicit policy goals, and his performance would be judged accordingly.

These actions were not necessarily viewed with distress, since New Zealand was an

emerging economy, small enough not to cause any problems for any other country.

Receptiveness and straightforwardness in the lead of financial arrangement are

vital approaches to enhance validity in an expansion focusing on framework by making

the national bank freely responsible for its choice, they raise the motivating force to

accomplish the swelling target and in this manner improve people in general's trust in the

capacity of the fiscal experts to do as such. They may likewise prompt enhanced basic

leadership with respect to the national banks by presenting to open scrutiny the

procedures through which fiscal strategy choices are taken. The way that fiscal

arrangement experts must declare approach changes and clarify the explanation behind

these progressions to the general population may build the adequacy of money related

strategy under swelling focusing on. At last, straightforwardness lessens vulnerability

about the national bank's inclinations, which may prompt a lower expected rate of

swelling and a lower affinity to react to supply stuns.

Adaptation of Inflation Targeting


In the aftermath of the money related emergency that influenced Mexico's

economy all through 1995, one of the objectives of the financial program was to balance

out the economy in a deliberate manner and as fast as could reasonably be expected,

with the end goal to ensure that a monetary strength circumstance would not emerge. As

argued by Ramos-Francia and Torres García (2005), in doing so, the three challenges

posed by the crisis were met: (i) the government fulfilled all of its obligations; (ii) the

economy adjusted swiftly to a new macroeconomic environment (the current account

deficit fell from 7.1 percent of GDP in 1994 to 0.61 percent in 1996 and 1.8 percent in

1997); and (iii) a meltdown of the financial system was avoided.

As Ramos-Francia and Torres García (2005) point out, the challenge faced by

policymakers at Banco de México was to establish monetary policy as the nominal

anchor of the economy at a time when there was widespread uncertainty about the

bank‟s commitment and its ability to achieve both financial and price stability. The

strategy consisted mainly of three elements: (i) improve the transparency of the

implementation of monetary policy; (ii) maintain a clear restrictive bias in order to induce

a sustainable reduction in inflation; and (iii) respond appropriately to inflationary shocks.

Several main points are of note in the process that led to the adoption of an

inflation targeting regime in Mexico. In this process, inflation has decreased from close

to 52 percent in 1995 to levels close to 3 percent over recent years, under a flexible

exchange rate regime.

As a result of the progress to an undeniable expansion focusing on structure,

both the goal and usage of money related arrangement have turned out to be more

straightforward and open to open examination. This procedure has additionally

enhanced the responsibility of Banco de México and secured swelling desires.

Effects of Inflation on Output


Cost-push and demand-pull factors are important in the determination of the

price level. The price of imported goods has the highest elasticity, followed by wages

and money supply (Lira, 1996). The theory of cost-push inflation explains rising prices in

terms of factors that raise per-unit production cost at each level of spending. A per unit

production cost is the average cost of particular level of output. Rising per-unit

production cost squeeze profits and reduce amounts of output firms are willing to supply

at the existing price level. The major source of cost-push inflation has been so-called

supply shocks. Specifically, abrupt increases in the cost of raw materials or energy

inputs have on occasion driven up per-unit productions cost and thus product prices.

An interesting study is that of Lim (1987) which is based on the possibility that

the working capital cost-push effect may offset the monetarist effect so that inflation may

even rise after a reduction in money supply. The increase in inflation is caused by the

rise in the interest rate which raises the cost of borrowing for working capital. The

empirical results indicate a positive relation between relevant interest rates and inflation.

Lim then concludes that "the simple quantity theory of money is oversimplified and hides

the full impact of monetarist prescriptions to inflation and that it neglects the transmission

mechanism of credit made monetary cutback which may entail a drastic fall in income,

investments, personal consumption expenditure and most likely, government spending."

Usually, changes in the price level are caused by an excess of total spending

beyond the economy‟s capacity to produce. When resources are already fully employed,

the business sector cannot respond to this excess demand by expanding output. So the

excess demand bids up the prices of the limited real output, causing demand-pull

inflation. Demand-pull inflation involves inflation rising as real Gross Domestic Product

rises and unemployment falls, as the economy moves along the Phillips curve. Demand-

pull inflation is commonly described as “too much money chasing too few goods”. More

accurately, it should be described as involving “too much money spent chasing too few
goods”, since only money that is spent on goods and services can cause inflation. This

is not expected to happen unless the economy is already at a full employment level.

Demand-pull inflation is mostly associated with Keynesian economics.

To encounter demand-pull inflation, governments and central banks would have

to implement tight monetary and fiscal policy like increasing the interest rate or lowering

government spending or raising taxes. An increase in the interest rate would make

consumer spend less on durable goods and housing. Through this the investment

spending will increase by firms and businesses. Also in demand-pull inflation is rising too

fast, so these contractionary policies would lower the rise, meaning inflation would still

occur but at a lower rate.

Local Literature

Inflation in the Philippines

Inflation refers to the rate of exchange in the average prices of goods and

services typically purchased by consumers. If inflation is low and stable, then we say

that there is price stability. Studies based on the experience of many countries have

shown that maintaining price stability supports economic growth because it allows

households and businesses (including export enterprises) to plan ahead and arrive at

better informed decisions about consumption, investment, savings and production

needs. In the case of export firms, price stability allows them to price their products

competitively, reducing the risks related to the rising cost of raw materials.

(BangkoSentral ng Pilipinas).

The inflation movement rate of Philippine economy in the past six decades, after

experiencing years of positive economic growth from 1960‟s to 1970‟s, the inflation

volatility of the country increased significantly for the period of 1973 to 1986 because

Philippine economy during these times, suffered from a downturn due to a mixture of

domestic and international problems. These were the years that saw the country under
President Ferdinand Marcos and martial law, the assassination of Benigno Aquino, Jr.,

changes to the Philippine energy law and the success of the EDSA People Power

Revolution (Kushida, 2008)

By fall 1984, highest increase of inflation rate was recorded because of

somewhat negative picture of the Philippines emerged. By the year‟s end, the nation

external debt was almost doubled from the projected $18 billion to $30 billion, and the

balance-of-payment deficit climbed above $2 billion. In September, industrial production

fell for the first time in many years, and huge lay out seemed imminent in the first quarter

of the next year, given an extremely low inventory of materials in manufacturing firms.

The rate of inflation doubled following two devaluations of the peso in June and October.

Also, the country faced its worst liquidity crisis since 1945 due to an estimated $1 billion

capital flight from late August to December (Kushida, 2008). After these periods, the

efforts of Philippine administration for radical changes and democratic reforms lead to

the recovery of the economy that is felt up to the present. Despite remarkable

movements of the country‟s inflation rate, generally, our economy remains to be stable.

Gross Domestic Product (GDP)

The economy of the Philippines is the world's 34th largest economy by nominal

GDP according to the 2017 estimate of the International Monetary Fund's statistics, it is

the 13th largest economy in Asia, and the 3rd largest economy in

the ASEAN after Indonesia and Thailand. The Philippines is one of the emerging

markets and is the sixth richest in Southeast Asia by GDP per capita values, after the

regional countries of Singapore, Brunei, Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia.

The Philippines is primarily considered a newly industrialized country, which has

an economy in transition from one based on agriculture to one based more on services
and manufacturing. As of 2017, GDP by purchasing power parity was estimated to be at

$1.980 trillion.

Primary exports include semiconductors and electronic products, transport

equipment, garments, copper products, petroleum products, coconut oil, and fruits.

Major trading partners include Japan, China, the United States, Singapore, South Korea,

the Netherlands, Hong Kong, Germany, Taiwan and Thailand. The Philippines has been

named as one of the Tiger Cub Economies together with Indonesia, and Thailand. It is

currently one of Asia's fastest growing economies. However, major problems remain,

mainly having to do with alleviating the wide income and growth disparities between the

country's different regions and socioeconomic classes, reducing corruption, and

investing in the infrastructure necessary to ensure future growth.

The Philippine economy is projected to be the 5th largest in Asia and 16th

biggest in the world by 2050. According to the Price water house Coopers, it estimates

that it will be the 12th to 14th richest economy in the world by 2060. While this opposes

other reports from HSBC Holdings PLC, that by the year 2050, the Philippines will have

been stated to surpass the economy of Indonesia due to its yearly higher GDP growth

rate of 6.5% (Second, after China). However, the economic statistics may still vary

depending on the performance of the government every year.

The performance of the Philippine economy is monitored by looking at the year-

on-year growth of Gross Domestic Product (GDP), which measures the country‟s output

of goods and services during an accounting period. At current prices, GDP reflects the

total peso value of production and accounts for the effects of price changes. At constant

prices, the influence of price changes is eliminated; hence, it provides an overall index of

the physical volume of goods and services produced by the economy over the period.

GDP per capita refers to the ratio of the country‟s total value of goods and services to

the total population. It reflects the pace of growths of the country‟s economy with the
growth of the population. The Gross Domestic Product adjusted with the net primary

income from and to the rest of the world is the Gross National Income (GNI).

At constant prices, Gross Domestic Product amounted to P7.16 trillion in 2014. It

grew by 6.1 percent. Per capita GDP at P71, 726 was up by 4.3 percent. Gross National

Income was estimated at P8.64 trillion in 2014. It registered a 5.8 percent growth which

was lower than the 2013 increment of 8.1 percent.

Gross Domestic Product at current prices reached P12.64 trillion, an increase of

9.5 percent. In per capita terms, GDP amounted to P 126,579 and posted an increase of

7.7 percent. Gross National Income valued at P15.33 trillion moved up at a slower pace

of 9.1 percent in 2014 compared to last year‟s growth of 10.4 percent.

Government Policies

Monetary Policy Strategy in the Philippines

Throughout the crisis, the primary objective of the BangkoSentral ng Pilipinas

(BSP) remained to be “to maintain price stability”. Nonetheless, financial stability is an

important pursuit. Policy instruments were used in increasingly innovative ways, and the

BSP policy toolkit was broadened to address evolving economic conditions. This

strategy ensures that monetary policy is not overburdened in achieving both price and

financial stability.

According to Section 3 of Republic Act No. 7653 or the New Central Bank Act the

BSP‟s Ultimate Target is to provide that the primary objective of the BSP is to maintain

price stability conducive to a balanced and sustainable growth of the economy. The BSP

is also tasked to promote and maintain monetary stability and the convertibility of the

Philippine peso. In this connection, the BSP formulates and implements monetary

policies to support the objective of price stability. The BSP‟s framework for conducting

monetary policy is based on the interplay of a set of policy variables, as follows: (1) the
ultimate policy objective; (2) instruments of monetary policy; and (3) operating and

intermediate targets.

Sustainability of monetary policy in uncertain times, a speech made by William

Poole of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, emphasizes that the inflation objective

of the Fed is to maintain a low and stable rate of inflation which is a long-run economic

performance in terms of employment growth and maximized economic growth is

achieved.

Fiscal Policy

Just like there are different schools of thoughts on what causes inflation, there

are different opinions on how to deal with it. Demand-side policies are used to increase

or a decrease demand, to either expands or contracts the economy. These policies

focus on the aggregate demand, which is basically a combination of government and

consumer spending, investment, and net exports which are exports minus imports.

Demand policies can be based on fiscal policies, which have to do with government

spending or taxes, or monetary policies, which have to do with the money supply or

interest rates.

There is an issue relating to fiscal policy for sustainable growth is the impact of

government spending and debt on economic growth. The debt burden keeps the

government from providing services to the people and the necessary infrastructure to

help improve the economy. The trend in the government‟s budgetary policy is a rising

allocation of general public services and a decreasing budget for economic services.

This means that the government is in the essence of spending more for less important

matters and spending less on the areas that are more crucial in achieving sustainable

growth.

Fiscal stability after the financial crisis in 1990s remains in jeopardy. To raise its

sustainable growth rate, the Philippines needs to close its fiscal policy without
necessarily scarifying essential physical and social infrastructures. Posting a well-

behaved fiscal position after the Asian contagion set in, the government indulged in

deficit-spending in an attempt of stimulate the economy out of a mild recession. Both the

revenue (tax collection) and expenditures sides require tremendous restructuring efforts

and commitment.

Foreign Studies

An earlier study of R. Bautista (1983) who estimated an inflation equation based

on the annual growth of CPI. His results show that a large part of inflation for the period

1965- 1982 can be attributed to foreign price increases and the depreciation of the peso.

He does not find the growth of money supply and changes in the wage rate to be

significant.

Meanwhile, a further refinement to the studies of inflation is the empirical model

of C. Bautista (1991). By estimating a macroeconomic vector auto regression model

(VAR) and applying variance decomposition, Bautista shows that the forecast error

variance of inflation due to exchange rate movements is higher than that of money

supply growth. This lends support to the BOP view of inflation which maintains that the

exchange rate is the main cause of price changes. The empirical results do not show,

however, that the fiscal view of inflation, which contends that the main determinant is

money supply growth fuelled by fiscal deficits, is unimportant.

In the study of Takeshi Inoue, Yuki Toyoshima and Shigeyuki hamori it stated

that before inflation targeting (IT), the four Asian countries, that is, Korea, Indonesia,

Thailand, and the Philippines, commonly adopted monetary targeting. Due to financial

innovation and deregulation, however, the relationship between money supply and

output growth became less stable over time, which encouraged these countries to switch

their policy framework from monetary targeting to IT. Looking at the achievement of
inflation targets, these countries show different outcomes. In Thailand and Korea, actual

inflation has relatively fallen well within the target range, while Indonesia and the

Philippines have quite often failed to meet the target. Therefore, the achievement of the

inflation target varied across these countries, although the basic statistics such as the

mean and standard deviation indicate that the numbers were generally smaller than 18

those prior to the IT period, suggesting that the IT framework in Asia seems to have

succeeded in attaining the objectives of low and stable inflation. In recent years, a

growing body of empirical studies has been conducted to analyze IT in the Asian

emerging countries. These empirical studies tend to characterize IT by estimating the

monetary reaction function for each country and generally confirm that the central banks

under the IT regime have paid substantial attention to inflation developments when

conducting monetary policy. In this article, we investigate the impact of IT on the

economy from a different viewpoint than the surveyed literature. Specifically, we analyze

whether and to what extent the adoption of IT in these countries has affected

international business synchronization by employing the dynamic conditional correlation

(DCC) model developed by Engle (2002). From this analysis, we find that IT in Asia has

little effect on business cycle synchronization with the rest of the world and that the

effect is positive in some of the countries, if any. As relevant literature, Flood and Rose

(2010) examine whether the advent of IT in developed and developing countries

including the Asian countries can be linked to the rising international synchronization of

the business cycle by applying different methods, and they point out that countries that

target inflation seem to have cycles that move slightly more closely with foreign cycles.

Therefore, the findings basically seem to be consistent with the evidence from Flood and

Rose.
Advantages of IT:

The IT regime has several advantages as a monetary policy strategy when

compared with the other policy regimes: IT provides a nominal anchor for monetary

policy and inflation expectations; In contrast to the exchange rate targeting, IT gives

opportunity to respond shocks hitting to the economy and to focus domestic

considerations; IT does not require a stable relationship betweenmonetary aggregates

and inflation as in monetary targeting. It uses all available information in the formation of

the policy setting; as it is explained above, monetary policy shows its impact on the

economic activity with long and variable lags. IT regime gives an explicit role to the lags

of monetary policy in the choice of policy instruments; It is possible in the IT regime to

decrease the possibility of falling into time inconsistency trap by decreasing the pressure

coming from the politicians in order to stimulate the economic activitity; and other

advantage of the IT regime is its great emphasis on the regular communication with the

public and transparency. This property have important role in the success of the IT in the

industrialized countries. The policymakers in the developed countries use every

opportunity to communicate with the public like public speeches and a step further by

means of inflation reports; Transparency of the policy has inclination to make the policy

more accountable to the public and continuous success of the policy in reaching to

numerical targets increases the public support for the central bank; One of the

advantages of IT regime is its clarity for public understanding compared with the nominal

income targeting. In the nominal income-targeting regime, there is no decomposition for

the income component and price component. So, it might be difficult for the public to

built price expectations. In addition, the inflation targeting regime serves as an anchor for

wage and the price setters and the existence of such an anchor increases the credibility

of the policy.
Disadvantages of IT:

Inflation Targeting has disadvantages and here are somes: The inflation-

targeting regime has been criticized due to its overemphasis on inflation, its rigid

structure, its negative impacts on the economic growth and its exclusion other goals like

output stabilization.7 However, the countries‟ announcement of the targets above the

zero inflation rates reflects the fact that the central banks does not ignore the output

growths totally and it takes into account a possible deflation and the undesirable impacts

of deflation on the economic activity; It is claimed that there is only weak central bank

accountability in IT because in contrast to exchange rate and monetary aggregates,

inflation is difficult to control and the policy instruments show their impact on inflation

with long and variable lags.This problem is especially severe in the developing countries

when the rates of inflation are being brought down from high levels. In this situation,

there will be large forecast errors and frequent target misses. Therefore, it will be difficult

for the central bank to explain the reason for the deviations from the target and to gain

credibility, which is central to the IT regime. According to Masson etc. (1997) IT will be

more effective if it is started to implement this regime after successful disinflation.

Another factor that has influence on the ability of the central banks to control inflation is

the large existence of the government-controlled prices and this factor is of significant

importance for the developing countries. Successful IT implementation requires high

coordination between the people who determine these prices and the monetary

policymakers or the exclusion of these prices from the targeted rate in this circumstance.

Moreover, inflation forecasting procedure in these countries should take into account the

timing and magnitude of the changes in those prices; IT may not prevent fiscal

dominance. In the long run, large fiscal deficits will cause either monetization of the

deficits or devaluation and they will result in high inflation; Exchange rate flexibility

required by IT might cause financial instability; There are some economists (e.g. Calvo
1999b, Calvo and Mendoza 2000) who argue that the IT regime is too discretionary and

it may cause policy makers to follow overly expansionary policies. However, as it is

explained in this paper, IT regime increases the accountability and transparency of the

policy. Accountability increases the costs of policy mistakes for policy makers and

transparency makes difficult to conduct overly expansionary policy without it being

noticed. So, it does not seem plausible to assert that the monetary policy in the IT

regime is too discretionary; and some economists argue that IT is too rigid and it

impedes the monetary authorities from responding to the shocks hitting the economy.

However, it can be argued that IT is far from being a rigid rule; it can be evaluated as

„constraint discretion. It does not impose simple rules about the conduct of the monetary

policy. Contrary to simple rules, IT regime obligates policy makers to use all available

information in order to achieve the target.

Phillips Curve

The Phillips curve is the economic relationship between the change of

inflation on the one hand and unemployment on the other. It was observed in 1958

by an English economist by the name of A. W. Phillips, and it provides a connection

between the change of nominal wages and unemployment (Phillips, 1958). This

model was adopted and extended in subsequent years, with similar patterns also

found for the U.S. (Samuelson and Solow, 1960). This relationship was considered

permanent and presented policy makers with a choice between high unemployment

with low inflation or an alternative a low unemployment with high inflation. However,

Friedman and Phelps criticized this because they considered the origin of the

negative relationship in a bias of the inflation expectations of workers (Friedman

1968; Phelps 1968). Therefore, the inverse relationship between inflation and

unemployment was only found up to an adjustment of inflation expectations, and

subsequently moves back to the natural rate of unemployment. By this chain of


reasoning, the first version of the Phillips curve had a natural rate of unemployment

as well as containing inflation expectations. The consequence of this model was that

inflation only has a short run effect on unemployment. After an adjustment process to

the natural rate of unemployment, there will be only an increase in inflation.

Therefore, there are no advantages of raising inflation to a higher level, and thus it

should rather remain low and constant.

How the chain of arguments as presented by the Phillips curve was

understood as a form of adaptive expectations formation (2.01). However, this

changed during the 1970s and the occurrence of the two oil price shocks, owing to

the change in the expectation formation of wage setters. Previously inflation was

subject to certain fluctuations around a general level of inflation, while in the 1970s

inflation rose continuously. The probability that a higher inflation rate followed a high

inflation rate in the next year rose, thus avoiding the previous tradeoff between

inflation and unemployment. In the following years, a large number of countries

observed a simultaneous increase in inflation and unemployment, and this stagflation

led to a new modification of the Phillips curve with forward-looking inflation

eexpectations (Lucas, 1972/1973).

Local Studies

In the study of Joseph T. Yap about the inflation and Economic in the Philippines,

the results shows that The Machiavellian approach to controlling inflation has not been

effective in the Philippines. Certainly, Krugman's warning about the serious

repercussions of some methods of disinflation is quite relevant especially when

juxtaposed against the potential costs of inflation. Financial managers responded

appropriately during the crisis periods but were rather short-sighted during the recovery

phases particularly during the period 1986-95. For one thing, a more aggressive debt

management strategy should have been adopted. But even with the "honor flay debt"
commandment in place, monetary, fiscal and exchange rate policy should not have been

formulated in a manner that sacrifices long-term growth. Definitely, an inflation of 10-15

percent could have been tolerated as long as the source was productivity-enhancing

government expenditure. A steady depreciation to maintain a realistic real exchange rate

could have been accommodated in this scenario. As it stands now, economic managers

have to contend with volatile capital flows and as a result, the wisdom of liberalizing the

capital account ahead of the trade sector is being questioned. To prevent further

appreciation of the real effective exchange rate in the presence of these capital flows, it

has been proposed that instead of targeting monetary aggregates, the Central Bank

targets interest rates and an appropriate real exchange rate (De Dios, 1995).

Nevertheless, the key to macroeconomic stability is strong fiscal performance via a

higher tax effort. This is what preoccupies the government at present and the outcome of

the tax reform program still hangs in the balance.


METHODOLOGY

This chapter describes the methodology of research study, research design,

sources of data and statistical treatment of data. In this study methodologies used to

analyzed and interpret the influence of inflation targeting on growth and employment in

agricultural sector in the Philippines.

Research Design

This study used descriptive-co relational method. It was descriptive since it

involved collection, analysis and interpretation of data. Correlation, on the other hand, it

utilized to depict and find out to which at least two variables were connected.

The descriptive-co relational method used in order to determine the influence of

inflation targeting on growth and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines.

Sources of Data

The study used secondary data taken from the Philippine Statistics Authority

(PSA) and Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) from 2002-2017. The researchers

personally collected the data within the permission of the personnel.

Null Hypothesis

= Actual Inflation does not have significant effect on Employment

= Actual Inflation does not have significant effect on Economic Growth

Actual and target inflation rate using minimum value does not have significant

difference

Actual and target inflation rate using maximum value does not have significant

difference
Statistical Treatment of Data

Simple Linear Regression is a model with a single regressor x that has a

relationship with a responses y that is straight line. This simple linear regression model

can be expressed as:

Y= (1)

Where the intercept and the slope are unknown constants and is a

random error component.

Empirical Model

The empirical model was based on the theoretical and conceptual framework of

the study, the theoretical is based on the theory of demand pull and cost push theory

while the conceptual framework proposes the inflation targeting on growth and

employment in agricultural sector. The independent variable is inflation targeting and

dependent variables are economic growth and employment. The researchers proposed

four models in depicting the influence of inflation targeting that may result in economic

growth in terms of GDP and employment.

Model 1: Actual Inflation= f (Target Inflation)

Model 2: Target Inflation= f (Actual Inflation)

Model 3: Employment= f (Actual Inflation)

Model 4: Economic Growth (GDP) = f (Actual Inflation)

Research Model

The following economic models are designed to provide statistical basis for

accepting the null hypothesis of this study. The models will be estimated using the

simple linear regression analysis.


Model 1: (2)

Model 2: (3)

Model 3: (4)

Model 4: (5)

Where:

AI = Actual Inflation

EG = Economic Growth

TI = Target Inflation

E = Employment

GDP = Gross Domestic Product

t-1 = Lagged Term

Test of significant difference of two parameters

The parameters of the model will be tested for statistical significance at 5 percent

level using t-test. T-test is a test of significance. It is a ratio of estimated regression

coefficient divided by its standard error. It is a procedure by which mean sample results

are used to verify the truth or falsity of null hypothesis. (Gujarati, 2003)

(6)

Where: parameter of the kth variable

standard error of the parameter of the kth variable

If the computed t-ratio of a coefficient exceeds, in absolute value, the critical

value of the t-ratio at 5 percent level of significance, then the parameters are statistically

significant.
Unit root

To test the stationary or (non-stationary) in a time series the unit root test will be

used. This can be written as:

+ (7)

If the coefficient of is equivalent to 1, then the variable at that point is said to

have a unit root and as a result non-stationary. Regressing non-stationary variables are

trending up or down, as often the case for economic variables.To find out whether the

variables of a model are stationary or non-stationary, the Augmented Dickey-fuller (DF

test with provision for intercept, for domestic time trend, t, augmented by lagged terms

of the variable) will be used as follow:

(8)

Where:

= the level series of y lagged by 1 period

= original series has intercept

t = series has deterministic time trend

= lagged term

= white noise

If the coefficient is more negative than 1%, 5% and 10% levels of

significance, based on Mickinnon critical values, then the series at level is said to have a

unit root while its first difference, is a stationary. All variables would be tested for unit

root while its first difference is stationary.


Durbin Watson Test

In order to test the autocorrelation in the residuals from a statistical regression

analysis Durbin Watson test will be use. The Durbin Watson statistics is always between

0 and 4, a value of 2 means that there is no autocorrelation in the sample.


D.W = ∑
(9)

Ramsey Reset (Regression Specification Error Test)

In the design of economic models, the ambiguity of the underlying theory may

lead the researcher to commit error in the specification of the functional relationships.

Such errors could have arisen due to omission of variables, inclusion of unnecessary

variables, or wrong functional form. In any case, this could result to larger variances and

render the parameters statistically insignificant.

To minimize the incidence of these lapses, Ramsey‟s regression specification

error test (RESET) was applied on each of the models. The testing procedures were as

follows:

1.) Assuming that a model is potentially mis-specified, its estimated mean value was

obtained.

2.) The model is re-run by introducing Y, in some form, as an additional repressor(s).

3.) The R2 for both regression results will be obtained and the F test were applied

on it as follows:

n- no. of parameters in new model

4.) If the computed F is statistically significant, then the model is missed specified.

The result of this test determines whether to accept or reject hypothesis.


RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

This chapter includes the analysis and the interpretation of all the gathered data.

It includes the analysis of the pattern of inflation rate, employment and Gross Domestic

Product in the Philippines for 2002 to 2017; significant difference between actual and

target inflation rate; and significant influence of inflation targeting on employment and

Gross Domestic Product in the Philippines.

Pattern of inflation rate

Inflation is typically defined as the annual percentage change in the Consumer

Price Index (CPI). The CPI represents the average price of a standard basket of goods

and services consumed by a typical Filipino family for a given period. This standard

basket contains hundreds of consumption items (such as food products, clothing, water

and electricity) whose price movements are monitored to determine the change in the

CPI, or the level of inflation (Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas). Figure 1 shows the Philippine

Inflation rate from 2002 to 2017.

The Philippine inflation rate is in positive state from the year 2002 to 2007, it is

the year when the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) formally adopted inflation targeting

or announces an explicit inflation target with a strong commitment of achieving it over a

policy horizon using various monetary policy instruments. Meanwhile, the last double-

digit monthly inflation rate recorded was in September 2008, when it hit 10.1 percent

(using base year 2012) under the Arroyo administration. Before that, it was 10.2 percent

in July and 10.5 percent in August also in 2008. Some economies said that it is because

of the influx of rice imports and the global crisis, which slowed down overall economic

growth. This last double digit monthly inflation rate recorded last September 2008 was

followed by September 2018 with the rate of 6.7. It is recorded as the highest inflation
rate over the last 9 years. It was also the 9th consecutive monthly inflation rate increase,

which started in January 2018.

In the year 2002 until 2017, the Philippines highest actual inflation rate in

minimum value is 5.9 percent in the month of December year 2005 while the maximum

is 10.5 percent in the month of August year 2008. Meanwhile, target inflation is annually

announces by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) and the highest target inflation rate

in minimum value is 4.5 percent in the year 2002, 2003 and 2010 while the maximum is

5.5 percent in the year 2002, 2003 and 2010.

12

10

0
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

ACTUALM AX ACTUALM IN
TARGETM AX TARGETM IN

Figure 2. Philippine Inflation Rate, 2002-2017

Employment

Indicators relating to labor market such as employment measures the rate of

absorption of available manpower supply in the production of goods and services. On

the other hand, unemployment indicates the inefficiency of the labor market to absorb

the available human resources to contribute to production activities.


The number of gainfully employed persons in agriculture measures the extent of

absorption of the available manpower supply in agriculture and its contribution to the

total economy. In 2016, about 11.06 million persons were employed in agriculture. This

comprised 27.0 percent of the country‟s total employment. The biggest counts of the

employed persons in agriculture were recorded in Western Visayas at 1.10 million and

Central Visayas at 0.94 million. Agricultural employment was also bigger in Cagayan

Valley, Bicol Region, Northern Mindanao, SOCCSKSARGEN and ARMM ranging from

0.73 million to 0.84 million persons. In contrast, the least employment in agriculture was

located in NCR with 25,000 persons.

At the regional level, agriculture accounted for a bigger share in ARMM at 65.0

percent of the region‟s total employment. This was followed by Cagayan Valley with

about half of the total employment were absorbed by the agriculture sector. Agricultural

employment contributed 41.8 percent to 44.4 percent in CAR, MIMAROPA, Zamboanga

Peninsula and SOCCSKSARGEN. The least shares were in CALABARZON at 9.7

percent and in NCR at 0.5 percent.

In 2002 until 2008 the percentage of the employment in agriculture is increasing

because Philippines is still in agricultural based.

Countrywide, there were 12.04 million persons employed in agriculture in 2009.

The number of employed persons expanded by an average of 1.0 percent yearly from

2006 to 2009. The sector‟s share in total employment went down to 34.3 percent. The

shares contracted by an average of 1.4 percent annually.

In 2013, the country‟s labor productivity in agriculture amounted to P 109,575 at

current prices or P 59,706 at constant prices. Average yearly increases corresponded to

4.3 percent and 3.8 percent during the period 2011 to 2013.
In 2015, a total of 11.29 million persons were employed in the agriculture sector.

This accounted for a share of 29.2 percent in the country‟s total employment. At the

regional level, the most number of employed persons in agriculture was located in

Western Visayas at 1.17 million.

In 2016, about 11.06 million persons were employed in agriculture. This

comprised 27.0 percent of the country‟s total employment and in 2017, there were 10.26

million persons who were employed in agriculture. This was equivalent to a share of 25.4

percent in the country‟s total employment.

Gross Domestic Product

The trend of the Gross Domestic Product in agricultural sector in the Philippines

in decreasing over the time, the composition of the gross domestic product is broadly

split among the agricultural, industrial and service sectors. According to 2017 World

Bank data, agriculture accounted for 9.7 percent of GDP, marking the lowest contribution

to GDP in the country's history. To put that into perspective, agriculture accounted for

one-quarter of the country's GDP during the 1980s and almost one-third in the 1970s.

Meanwhile, the industrial and service sectors accounted for 30.5 percent and 60

percent, respectively in 2017. Note that the share of industrial output has steadily fallen

as well over time, while the services sector has risen substantially.

The Philippines has gradually shifted from an agrarian to an industrial and

service-oriented economy. In 1980, agriculture accounted for about one-fourth of the

nation‟s GDP, but that has dwindled over the years. The agricultural sector (including

forestry, hunting, fishing, the cultivation of crops and livestock production according to

the World Bank) now accounts for only 9.6 percent of the GDP. That said, it accounts for

about 30 percent of the workforce. The main agricultural products are sugarcane,

coconuts, rice, corn, bananas, cassava (manioc), tapioca, pineapples, mangoes, pork,

eggs, beef and fish.This low level of productivity and slow growth in the Philippines‟
agricultural sector has resulted in a high incidence of poverty within the sector. The lack

of government initiatives has been primarily responsible for the decline of the agricultural

sector, which has suffered from poor infrastructure and low levels of investment. These

factors got accentuated with the long seasons of drought that the country suffered.

40

36

32

28

24

20

16

12

8
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
EM PLOYM ENT GDP
Figure 3. Philippine Employment and Gross Domestic
Product, 2002-2017

Significant difference between actual and target inflation rate

Table 1. Philippines actual and target inflation rate in minimum and maximum value
Year Minimum Maximum Minimum Maximum
Actual actual Target Target
2002 2.1 3.4 4.5 5.5
2003 1.9 2.8 4.5 5.5
2004 2.9 7.1 4 5
2005 5.9 7.3 5 6
2006 4.1 6.6 4 5
2007 2.6 3.8 4 5
2008 4.6 10.5 4 5
2009 1.7 7.2 3.5 4.5
2010 3.2 4.1 4.5 5.5
2011 4 5.2 4 5
2012 2.6 4 4 5
2013 2.1 4.1 4 5
2014 2.7 4.9 4 5
2015 0.4 2.5 3 4
2016 0.9 2.6 3 4
2017 2.7 3.5 3 4

Table 2. T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate using minimum value

Variances Mean T- value P Value Remarks

Actual 2.78 -3.10 0.00* Reject

Target 3.94 -3.10 0.00* Reject

* significant at 1 percent level p<0.01

The T-test statistics shows that the actual and target inflation using minimum

value is significant with t-value of -3.10 at one percent level of significance. Table 2

showed that target inflation is higher than the actual. The result showed that the lowest

inflation rate experienced by the country is 1.16 percent below the target inflation. In

implication to it in the economy, why actual inflation is lower than the target is because of

limitations to the effectiveness of monetary policy and deviations from the inflation target

may sometimes occur due to factors beyond the control of the central bank. It include

price pressures arising from: volatility in the prices of agricultural products; natural

calamities or events that affect a major part of the economy; volatility in the prices of oil

products; and significant government policy changes that directly affect prices such as

changes in the tax structure, incentives and subsidies that result to the fluctuating or

changes in the price of goods and the decision making of the citizens in relation with

money.
Table 3. T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate using maximum value

Variances Mean T- value P Value Remarks

Actual 4.98 0.07 0.00* Reject

Target 4.94 0.07 0.00* Reject

* significant at 1 percent level p<0.01

The T-test statistics shows that the actual and target inflation using maximum

value is significant with t-value of 0.07 at one percent level of significance. Table 3

showed that actual inflation is higher than the target. The result showed that actual and

target inflation rate using maximum value is significant at 0.04 percent which experience

by the country. Monetary policy typically operates with a lag, so that policy actions

undertaken during a particular year would exert most of their impact on the economy

only after some time lag which, in the case of the Philippines, is estimated to be about

two years. This implies that the actions of the BSP at any given time are always based

on its assessment of the outlook for inflation and output two years ahead.

Influence of Inflation on Growth and Employment in Agricultural Sector

In this study, the independent variable was actual inflation determined by Bangko

Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) while the dependent variables are the growth in terms of GDP

and employment in agricultural sector. The relationship between independent and

dependent variables was measured using ordinary least square regression.

Unit Root Test. It was conducted before regressing the variables in order to

determine whether a time series variables is non-stationary and possesses a unit root.

The model is stationary when time series observations in the variables possess a

constant mean, variance, co-variance over time. If the model does not meet the

requirements, the variables and the model are prone to random walk and can lead to
said unauthentic and uncertain regression result. The test starts with the initial

identification of random walk behavior in variables on its level form. This was the

analyzed form graphical illustration of the variable such as; actual inflation, GDP and

employment.

The graph of employment and GDP showed a decreasing pattern, and it

represent a random walk. Therefore, employment and GDP in agricultural sector has a

mean that grows around a fixed trend, which is constant and independent of time. On

the other hand, actual minimum inflation and actual maximum inflation shows a neither

upward nor downward trend. It is shown that the fluctuation in the variables indicates a

non stationary series. The graph of the independent and dependent variables at level

form was shown in Figure 4.


ACTUALMIN ACTUALMAX
6 11

10
5
9
4 8

7
3
6

2 5

4
1
3

0 2
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
GDP EMPLOYMENT
15 38

14 36

13 34

12 32

11 30

10 28

9 26

8 24
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

Figure 4. The graph of the independent and dependent variables at level form
The result of the Augmented Dickey Fuller test of all variables at level form was

shown in Table 4 and proven that there is an existence of unit root in inflation targeting.

Table 4. The result of Augmnted Dickey Fuller test of all variables at level form.
VARIABLES 1% C.V. 5% C.V. 10% C.V ADF STAT
LEVEL FORM
Actual Inflation -4.73 -3.76 -3.32 -3.27
(Maximum)

Actual Inflation -4.80 -3.79 -3.34 -3.73


(Minimum)

GDP -4.89 -3.83 -3.36 -0.91

Employment -4.10 -3.88 -3.39 1.13

The computed ADF statistics were -3.27 for actual maximum inflation, -3.73 for

actual minimum inflation, -0.91 for GDP, and 1.13 for employment. The ADF statistics

results of variables are lower than the computed ADF critical values at 1 percent, 5

percent, and 10 percent and it indicates that unit root may exist in the observations. The

results at ADF level form show that there is a unit root that exists in the variables and

must be subjected to ADF at first difference to replace the level form. The graph of the

independent and dependent variables at first difference was shown in Figure 5. This

illustrates a decreasing and increasing trend. It is shown that the fluctuation in the

variables indicates that there is still unit root in the variables.


DACTUALMIN DACTUALMAX
4 8

3 6

2
4
1
2
0
0
-1

-2 -2

-3 -4
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
DGDP DEMPLOYMENT
1 1

0
0

-1

-1
-2

-2 -3

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
Figure 5. The graph of the independent and dependent variables at first
difference

The results of Augmented Dickey Fuller test of all variables after differencing was

shown in Table 5. The computed ADF statistics were -4.58 for actual maximum inflation,

-4.58 for actual minimum inflation, -4.58 for GDP and -0.44 for employment. The

computed ADF statistics for all the variables did not passed the critical values at 1

percent, 5 percent, and 10 percent levels of significance and it is subjected to ADF at

second difference to replace the first difference.

Table 5. The result of Augmented Dickey Fuller test of all variables at first difference.
ADF STAT
VARIABLES 1% C.V. 5% C.V. 10% C.V FIRST
DIFFERENCE
Actual Inflation -4.89 -3.83 -3.36 -4.58
(Maximum)

Actual Inflation -4.89 -3.83 -3.36 -4.58


(Minimum)

GDP -5.30 -4.01 -3.46 -4.58

Employment -5.12 -3.93 -3.42 -0.44

The graph of the second difference of actual minimum inflation, actual maximum

inflation, GDP and employment in agricultural sector shows its consistent fluctuations
which can be an indicator of constancy in the mean. The graph of the second difference

was shown in Figure 6.


DACTUALMAX DACTUALMIN
12 6

8 4

4 2

0 0

-4 -2

-8 -4

-12 -6
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
DGDP DEMPLOYMENT
2 2

1
1

0
0

-1

-1
-2

-2 -3
02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

02

03

04

05

06

07

08

09

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
Figure 6. The graph of the independent and dependent variables at second difference

The results of Augmented Dickey Fuller test of independent and dependent

variables after second differencing was shown in Table 6. The computed ADF statistics

were -5.79 for actual maximum inflation, -10.91 for actual minimum inflation, -6.26 for

GDP and -4.33 for employment. The computed ADF statistics for all the independent

and dependent variables has passed in the critical values at 1 percent, 5 percent, and 10

percent levels of significance. In other words, the regression of time series variables

passed in the second difference in unit root.


Table 6. The result of Augmented Dickey Fuller test of all variables at second difference.
ADF STAT
VARIABLES 1% C.V. 5% C.V. 10% C.V SECOND
DIFFERENCE
Actual Inflation -5.79 -4.11 -3.52 -5.79
(Maximum)

Actual Inflation -5.52 -4.11 -3.52 -10.91


(Minimum)

GDP -5.30 -4.01 -3.46 -6.26

Employment -5.52 -4.11 -3.52 -4.33

Regression Result. In able to determine whether GDP and employment was

related to actual inflation, Ordinary Least Square Regression (OLS) was used in the

study. In addtion, the test was engaged to estimate the parameters of the reggression

model. The regression result using ordinary least square on actual inflation was shown

in Table 7 and Table 8.

A higher inflation rate may cause to reallocation of scarce resources to

unproductive activities and thus distort economic efficiency and reduce output growth.

According to Fischer and Modigliani (1980) suggested that a negative and nonlinear

relationship between the rate of inflation and economic growth through the new growth

theory mechanism proposed a model where the agents decide the level of labor output,

and increase inflation reduces labor supply, and producing a decrease in economic

production. Gillman and Nakov (2004) examined the relationship between inflation and

output growth in some developing countries and found out that inflation affects the

growth negatively.

The relationship between inflation and employment was emphatically the

opposite assumed by the Phillips Curve. Seyfried, W., among the G7 countries, a
positive and significant relationship between growth and employment was found only in

Germany and US. In addition, according to Verdoon (1949) and Kaldor (1966), an

increase in output growth of 1 percent leads to an increase in productivity and

employment growth, but there are several studies have been conducted to examine the

correlation exists between employment and inflation rate. Spithoven, A.H.G.MA (1995)

studied that evidently there was no fixed relationship between unemployment and

inflation.The result in Table 8 and Table 9 showed that there is no significant relationship

between independent and dependent variables.

Table 7. The regression result using ordinary least square regression on Actual
Maximum Inflation
VARIABLES
PARAMETER T-VALUE P-VALUE REMARKS
DEPENDENT INDEPENDENT ESTIMATES

Employment Intercept -0.15 -0.65 0.53**

Inflation Rate 0.09 1.81 0.10* Accept

GDP Intercept -0.36 -2.61 0.02*

Inflation Rate 0.01 0.41 0.69** Accept

*significant at 1 percent level P<0.01


**significant at 5 percent level P<0.05

Table 8. The regression result using ordinary least square regression on Actual
Minimum Inflation
VARIABLES
PARAMETER T-VALUE P-VALUE REMARKS
DEPENDENT INDEPENDENT ESTIMATES

Employment Intercept
-0.15 -0.65 0.53**
Inflation Rate Accept
0.09 1.81 0.10*
GDP Intercept
-0.35 -2.73 0.02*
Inflation Rate Accept
-0.07 -1.49 0.16*

*significant at 1 percent level P<0.01


**significant at 5 percent level P<0.05
The models explain that in Actual Maximum Inflation, Employment and GDP had

no significant relationship. An increase in inflation rate at 0.09 would decrease the

employment by -0.15 and I an increase in inflation rate at 0.01 would decrease the GDP

at -0.36. The null hypothesis 1 and 2 was accepted.

The models explain that in Actual Minimum Inflation, Employment and GDP had

no significant relationship. An increase in inflation rate at 0.09 would decrease the

employment by -0.15 and an increase in inflation rate at 0.01 would decrease the GDP

at -0.35. The null hypothesis 1 and 2 was accepted.

Table 9. Durbin Watson Statistics result of Employment and GDP


Actual Maximum Inflation Actual Minimum Inflation
Employment 2.65 2.72
GDP 3.15 2.80

The computed Durbin Watson test statictics values in both maximum and

minimum inflation targeting in farmgate, wholsale and retail prices does not lies between

the lower and upper limit tabulated values of dL= 0.738 and dU=1.253 respectively, the

null hypothesis is rejected. This suggests that there is no serial correlation among

residuals of the variables.

Futhermore, the computed R squared illustrates that 1 percent for GDP and 21

percent for employment the variation of the independent variables which is actual

maximum inflation was explained by the dependent variables such as the results

indicated further that the fitted model was statistically significant.


The computed R squared illustrates that 15 percent for GDP and 24 percent for

employment the variation of the independent variables which is actual minimum inflation

was explained by the dependent variables such as the results indicated further that the

fitted model was statistically significant.

Test of specific errors. In able to determine specification error, Ramsey Reset

was applied. If the computed F value is significant, one can accept the hypothesis that

the model is mis-specified. The test verifies if there are important variables disregard in

the model. Table 10 shows the summary of the Ramsey reset result of the model.

Table 10. Ramsey Reset Result of Actual Maximum Inflation


F Statistics Probability
Employment 0.03 0.86
GDP 1.45 0.25

Results suggest that employment obtaining a F-statistics of 0.03 and GDP

obtaining a F-statistics of 1.45 shows a specification. Therefore, the hypothesis

indicating that the model is mis-specified is rejected.

Table 11. Ramsey Reset Result of Actual Minimum Inflation


F Statistics Probability
Employment 2.57 0.11
GDP 4.38 0.04

Results suggest that employment obtaining a F-statistics of 2.57 and GDP

obtaining a F-statistics of 4.38 shows a specification. Therefore, the hypothesis

indicating that the model is mis-specified is rejected.


SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION

This chapter included the summary of findings, conclusion and

recommendations. The summary provides a discussion for each of the findings, using

anchor verbiage that justifies rather than distorts the intent of the findings. Furthermore,

the conclusions discussed the theoretical and practical implications of the findings that

will lead to the novel contribution knowledge. This concluding part displayed an in-depth

understanding of the researcher that adds to the scientific body of knowledge. Lastly, the

recommendation for future research highlighted the limitation and suggestions for future

research base on analysis made.

Summary

The purpose of the study was to analyze the influence of inflation targeting on

growth and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines; to describe the pattern

of inflation rate, GDP and employment in agricultural sector in the Philippines, to

determine if there is any significant difference between actual and target inflation rate,

and to determine the significant influence of inflation on growth and employment in

agricultural sector. The conceptual framework was constructed by having the actual and

target inflation rate as the independent variables while the dependent variables are the

employment and economic growth.

The methodology used was descriptive-co relational method using secondary

data taken from the Philippine Statistics Authority (PSA) and Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas

(BSP).

Statistical result showed particularly, t test that the actual and target inflation

using minimum value is significant with t-value of -3.10 at one percent level of
significance and lowest inflation rate experienced by the country is 1.26 percent below

the target inflation while in maximum value the actual and target inflation using maximum

value is significant with t-value of 0.06 at one percent level of significance. The actual

and target inflation rate using maximum value is significant at 0.04 percent which

experience by the country. However, in testing if inflation targeting can influence the

employment and GDP in agricultural sector, the result of regression showed that there is

no influence in employment and GDP. Furthermore, the result in Durbin Watson test

shows that the inflation targeting, employment and GDP had no serial correlation.

Models were not found to be mis-specified as independent and dependent variables

passed the test for specification error using Ramsey RESET Test.

Conclusion

Based on the empirical results the following conclusions were drawn: The

null hypothesis that the actual and target inflation using minimum value doesn‟t have a

significance diffrence was rejected while using maximum value is accepted. In

implication to it to the economy the result would affect the price of goods and the

decision making of the citizen of a country if the monetray policy is not effective and if it

is effective it would help the country to have a stable price which the Bangko Sental ng

Pilipinas main objective. On the other hand, the null hypothesis that the inflation

targeting does not have influence in employment and GDP was accepted. There is no

significant influence between all variables because in every increase of inflation rate

would give negative effect in employment and gross domestic product.

Recommendation

The empirical result from the simple linear regression shows that inflation

targeting does not have an influence on growth and employment in agricultural sector in
the Philippines. Nonetheless, the study recommends the government to implement

another monetary policy that will help the inflation stable and do another alternative

policy that is more effective than the inflation targeting. It‟s also recommended strongly

that special attention be given to policy implementation. In this regard, the

government should set up a policy implementation body or committee in the presidency

for the purpose of monitoring government policies and ensuring that they are

implemented according to prescriptions. Further investigation on what more economic

variables that can be affected by inflation targeting is recommended.


REFERENCES

Agenor, P.R. (2001). Monetary Policy under Flexible Exchange Rates: An Introduction to
Inflation Targeting.

Batini, N., Breuer, P., Kochhar, K, & Roger, S. (March 16, 2006). Inflation Targeting and
the IMF

Debelle, G., Masson, P., Savastano, M., & Sharma, S. (October 1998). Inflation
Targeting as a Framework for Monetary Policy.

Caporale, G.M. & Skare, M. (June 2011). Employment Growth, Inflation and Output
Growth: Was Phillips Right?

Froyen, R.T. Third Edition. Macroeconomic Theories and Policies

Gokal, V. & Hanif, S. (December 2004). Relationship between Inflation and Economic
Growth.

Guiniguindo, D.C. (2005). Measurement of Inflation and the Philippine Monetary Policy
Framework. Retrieved from https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org

Guiniguindo, D.C. (2005). The Inflation Target. Retrieved from www.bsp.gov.ph

Hasanov, M. & Omay, T. (July 2010). The Relationship between Inflation, Output
Growth, and their uncertainties: Evidence from selected CEE countries.

Hazzlitt, H. Inflation Versus Employment. Retrieve from https://fee.org/articles

Inoue, T., Hannori, K., & Toyoshima, Y. (January 2012). Inflation Targeting in Korea,
Indonesia, Thailand, and the Philippines: The Impact on business cycle
synchronization between each country and the world

Kadioglu, F., Ozdemir, N., &Yilmaz, G. (September 2000). Inflation Targeting in


Developing Countries.

Kovalchuk, A. (2012). Inflation Targeting in Developing Countries: Influence on Growth


and Inflation Volatility, Master‟s Thesis.

Martinez, G. O. (November 2008). Inflation Targeting.

McElroy, M. (2011). The Macroeconomy (Private choices, public actions, and aggregate
outcomes). Retrieved from Cavite State University Library.

Mishkin, F.S & Bernanke, B.S. (nd). Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for Monetary
Policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives – Volume 11, Number 2 – Spring 1997
– Pages 97 – 116.

Mishkin, F.S. & Schmidt-Hebbel, K. (December 30, 2013). A Decade of Inflation


Targeting in the World: What do we know and what do we need to know?
Mokgola, A. (2015). The Effects of Inflation Targeting on Economic Growth in South
Africa, Dissertation for the Degree of Master of Commerce in Economics.

Totonchi, J. (2011). Macroeconomic Theories of Inflation. Retrieved from Cavite State


University Library.

Tutar, E. (2002). Inflation Targeting in Developing Countries and Its Applicability to the
Turkish Economy, Master‟s Thesis.

Unknown Author (2016). Relationship between Inflation and Employment Rates and
GDP. Retrieve from www.ukessays.com.

Unknown Author (2016). Inflation Report: 4th Quarter 2016. Retrieve from Bangko
Sentral ng Pilipinas.

Unknown Author (January 2019). Philippine GDP grows 6.1 percent in the fourth quarter
of 2018; 6.2 percent in 2018. Retrieve from Philippine Statistics Authority.

Vermeulen, J.C (2017). Inflation and Unemployment in South Africa: Is the Phillips Curve
still dead?. Southern African Business Review, Volume 21.

Yap, J.T. (September 1996). Inflation and Economic Growth in the Philippines.
Discussion Paper Series No.96-11

Yelwa, M., David, O.O.K, & Awe, E.O. (August 2015). Analysis of the Relationship
between Inflation, Unemployment and Economic Growth in Nigeria: 1987-2012.
APPENDICES
Appendix 1. Actual and Target Yearly Inflation Rate at Minimum and Maximum in the
Philippines
Year Minimum Maximum Minimum Maximum
Actual Actual Target Target
2002 2.1 3.4 4.5 5.5
2003 1.9 2.8 4.5 5.5
2004 2.9 7.1 4 5
2005 5.9 7.3 5 6
2006 4.1 6.6 4 5
2007 2.6 3.8 4 5
2008 4.6 10.5 4 5
2009 1.7 7.2 3.5 4.5
2010 3.2 4.1 4.5 5.5
2011 4 5.2 4 5
2012 2.6 4 4 5
2013 2.1 4.1 4 5
2014 2.7 4.9 4 5
2015 0.4 2.5 3 4
2016 0.9 2.6 3 4
2017 2.7 3.5 3 4
Appendix 2. Total number of employed persons in agriculture by region, Philippines,
2006-2017 (in „000 persons)
REGION 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Philippines 11,682 11,786 12,030 12,043 11,956 12,268

NCR 36 36 29 31 25 31
CAR 352 360 369 367 375 366
Ilocos Region 715 690 706 734 752 764
Cagayan Valley 808 810 793 832 797 848
Central Luzon 757 780 792 795 802 830
CALABARZON 766 757 763 763 759 742
MIMAROPA 581 581 602 619 618 649
Bicol Region 882 877 916 875 844 852
Western Visayas 1,178 1,197 1,205 1,155 1,155 1,220
Central Visayas 800 817 851 856 863 906
Eastern Visayas 760 758 761 756 743 769
Zamboanga 659 667 675 696 712 699
Peninsula
Northern 784 768 814 801 805 826
Mindanao
Davao Region 693 699 729 703 683 746
SOCCSKSARGEN 764 789 811 836 819 832
Caraga 407 400 416 410 392 388
ARMM 740 800 797 814 812 799

REGION 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017

Philippines 12,093 11,835 11,801 11,294 11,064 10,261

NCR 31 29 31 26 25 26
CAR 351 348 372 365 335 315
Ilocos Region 698 649 662 635 596 513
Cagayan Valley 844 846 819 823 754 658
Central Luzon 820 846 832 751 659 586
CALABARZON 721 669 725 649 554 536
MIMAROPA 626 598 596 578 546 495
Bicol Region 887 866 859 871 841 698
Western Visayas 1,140 1,107 1,206 1,173 1,103 1,025
Central Visayas 874 880 904 898 941 911
Eastern Visayas 788 807 501 442 690 622
Zamboanga 661 659 632 614 683 612
Peninsula
Northern 846 773 849 759 729 733
Mindanao
Davao Region 716 690 703 641 695 667
SOCCSKSARGEN 843 837 829 810 775 803
Caraga 386 391 393 386 397 402
ARMM 861 840 888 874 741 659
Appendix 3. Yearly Employment Rate in Agricultural Sector in the Philippines
YEAR EMPLOYMENT RATE
2002 37
2003 37
2004 36
2005 36
2006 36
2007 35
2008 35
2009 34
2010 33
2011 33
2012 32
2013 31
2014 31
2015 29
2016 27
2017 25
Appendix 4. Yearly Economic Growth (GDP) Rate in Agricultural Sector in the
Philippines
YEAR GDP RATE
2002 14
2003 14
2004 14
2005 13
2006 13
2007 13
2008 13
2009 13
2010 12
2011 12
2012 11
2013 11
2014 10
2015 10
2016 9
2017 9
Appendix 5. T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate using
minimum value
t-Test: Two-Sample Assuming Equal
Variances
Variable 1 Variable 2
Mean 2.775 3.9375
Variance 1.907333333 0.329166667
Observations 16 16
Pooled Variance 1.11825
Hypothesized Mean Difference 0
df 30
t Stat -3.10934206
P(T<=t) one-tail 0.002043013
t Critical one-tail 1.697260851
P(T<=t) two-tail 0.004086026
t Critical two-tail 2.042272449
Appendix 6. T-test result comparing actual and target inflation rate using
maximum value
t-Test: Two-Sample Assuming Equal
Variances
Actual Target
Mean 4.975 4.9375
Variance 4.874 0.329166667
Observations 16 16
Pooled Variance 2.601583333
Hypothesized Mean Difference 0
df 30
t Stat 0.065759332
P(T<=t) one-tail 0.474002854
t Critical one-tail 1.697260851
P(T<=t) two-tail 0.948005707
t Critical two-tail 2.042272449
Appendix 1. Unit Root Result of all Independent and Dependent Variables at Level
Form

Null Hypothesis: ACTUALMIN has a unit root


Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Null Hypothesis: ACTUALMAX has a unit root
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3) Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3)
t-Statistic Prob.*
t-Statistic Prob.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -3.733190 0.0548
Test critical values: 1% level -4.800080 Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -3.266925 0.1094
5% level -3.791172 Test critical values: 1% level -4.728363
10% level -3.342253 5% level -3.759743
Null Hypothesis: EMPLOYMENT has a unit root
10% level -3.324976
Null Hypothesis: GDP has a unit root Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Lag Length: 3 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3)
Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Lag Length: 2 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3)
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 14 Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
t-Statistic Prob.*
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 15
t-Statistic Prob.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic 1.129801 0.9995
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -0.907263 0.9224 Test critical values: 1% level -4.992279
Dependent Variable: D(ACTUALMIN) Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation
Test critical values: 1% level -4.886426 5% level -3.875302
Method: Least Squares Dependent Variable: D(ACTUALMAX)
5% level -3.828975 10% level -3.388330
Date: 04/26/19 Time: 19:06 Method: Least Squares
10% level -3.362984
Sample (adjusted): 2004 2017 Date: 04/26/19 Time: 19:07
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Included observations: 14 after adjustments Sample (adjusted): 2003 2017
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
Included observations: 15 after adjustments
Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations and may not be accurate for a sample size of 12
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 13
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
ACTUALMIN(-1) -1.311703 0.351362 -3.733190 0.0039
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation
D(ACTUALMIN(-1)) 0.220681 0.260317 0.847738 0.4164 ACTUALMAX(-1) -0.857119 0.262362 -3.266925 0.0067
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(EMPLOYMENT)
C 5.967986 1.633475 3.653552 0.0044 C 6.095493 2.007652 3.036131 0.0103
Dependent Variable: D(GDP) Method: Least Squares
@TREND("2002") -0.256669 0.097200 -2.640619 0.0247 @TREND("2002") -0.217547 0.131919 -1.649101 0.1250
Method: Least Squares Date: 04/27/19 Time: 20:40
Date: 04/26/19 Time: 22:18 Sample (adjusted): 2006 2017
R-squared 0.643216 Mean dependent var 0.057143 R-squared 0.481712 Mean dependent var 0.006667
Sample (adjusted): 2005 2017 Included observations: 12 after adjustments
Adjusted R-squared 0.536181 S.D. dependent var 1.799450 Adjusted R-squared 0.395331 S.D. dependent var 2.705673
Included observations: 13 after adjustments
S.E. of regression 1.225503 Akaike info criterion 3.479536 S.E. of regression 2.103945 Akaike info criterion 4.502362
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
Sum squared resid 15.01857 Schwarz criterion 3.662123 Sum squared resid 53.11900 Schwarz criterion 4.643972
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
Log likelihood -20.35675 Hannan-Quinn criter. 3.462634 Log likelihood -30.76771 Hannan-Quinn criter. 4.500853
EMPLOYMENT(-1) 0.662510 0.586396 1.129801 0.3017
F-statistic 6.009387 Durbin-Watson stat 2.372400 F-statistic 5.576573 Durbin-Watson stat 2.181978
GDP(-1) -0.355588 0.391935 -0.907263 0.3908 D(EMPLOYMENT(-1)) -0.537822 0.824603 -0.652219 0.5384
Prob(F-statistic) 0.013111 Prob(F-statistic) 0.019383
D(GDP(-1)) -0.367565 0.449597 -0.817543 0.4373 D(EMPLOYMENT(-2)) -0.063175 0.769811 -0.082066 0.9373
D(GDP(-2)) 0.227401 0.364874 0.623233 0.5505 D(EMPLOYMENT(-3)) 0.891937 0.664606 1.342053 0.2281
C 5.121955 5.988362 0.855318 0.4173 C -25.48795 23.13538 -1.101687 0.3128
@TREND("2002") -0.151736 0.136448 -1.112045 0.2984 @TREND("2002") 0.308396 0.320964 0.960841 0.3737

R-squared 0.525269 Mean dependent var -0.384615 R-squared 0.734880 Mean dependent var -0.916667
Adjusted R-squared 0.287904 S.D. dependent var 0.506370 Adjusted R-squared 0.513946 S.D. dependent var 0.792961
S.E. of regression 0.427304 Akaike info criterion 1.421081 S.E. of regression 0.552833 Akaike info criterion 1.959333
Sum squared resid 1.460711 Schwarz criterion 1.638370 Sum squared resid 1.833749 Schwarz criterion 2.201786
Log likelihood -4.237029 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.376419 Log likelihood -5.755997 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.869568
F-statistic 2.212913 Durbin-Watson stat 1.360388 F-statistic 3.326247 Durbin-Watson stat 1.385369
Prob(F-statistic) 0.157508 Prob(F-statistic) 0.087829
Appendix Figure 2. Unit Root Result of all Independent and Dependent Variables at First
Difference
Null Hypothesis: D(ACTUALMIN) has a unit root Null Hypothesis: D(ACTUALMAX) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3) Lag Length: 1 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3)

t-Statistic Prob.* t-Statistic Prob.*

Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.576614 0.0160 Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.583688 0.0158
Test critical values: 1% level -4.886426 Test critical values: 1% level -4.886426
5% level -3.828975 5% level -3.828975
10% level -3.362984 10% level -3.362984

*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.


Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 13 and may not be accurate for a sample size of 13

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation


Dependent Variable: D(ACTUALMIN,2) Dependent Variable: D(ACTUALMAX,2)
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/26/19 Time: 19:07 Date: 04/26/19 Time: 19:07
Sample (adjusted): 2005 2017 Sample (adjusted): 2005 2017
Included observations: 13 after adjustments Included observations: 13 after adjustments

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

D(ACTUALMIN(-1)) -2.413146 0.527278 -4.576614 0.0013 D(ACTUALMAX(-1)) -2.121054 0.462740 -4.583688 0.0013
D(ACTUALMIN(-1),2) 0.691143 0.307494 2.247663 0.0512 D(ACTUALMAX(-1),2) 0.516168 0.270042 1.911435 0.0883
C 1.408439 1.259061 1.118643 0.2923 C 1.504302 1.855997 0.810509 0.4386
@TREND("2002") -0.174416 0.133766 -1.303883 0.2246 @TREND("2002") -0.202918 0.194014 -1.045894 0.3229

R-squared 0.788480 Mean dependent var 0.061538 R-squared 0.803972 Mean dependent var -0.261538
Adjusted R-squared 0.717973 S.D. dependent var 2.999872 Adjusted R-squared 0.738630 S.D. dependent var 4.597742
S.E. of regression 1.593119 Akaike info criterion 4.016925 S.E. of regression 2.350568 Akaike info criterion 4.794851
Sum squared resid 22.84226 Schwarz criterion 4.190755 Sum squared resid 49.72652 Schwarz criterion 4.968681
Log likelihood -22.11001 Hannan-Quinn criter. 3.981195 Log likelihood -27.16653 Hannan-Quinn criter. 4.759121
F-statistic 11.18302 Durbin-Watson stat 1.442421 F-statistic 12.30395 Durbin-Watson stat 2.481424
Prob(F-statistic) 0.002165 Prob(F-statistic) 0.001549

Null Hypothesis: D(DGDP) has a unit root


Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Null Hypothesis: D(DEMPLOYMENT) has a unit root
Lag Length: 3 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3) Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 2 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=3)
t-Statistic Prob.*
t-Statistic Prob.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.580590 0.0243
Test critical values: 1% level -5.295384 Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -0.443572 0.9666
5% level -4.008157 Test critical values: 1% level -5.124875
5% level -3.933364
10% level -3.460791
10% level -3.420030
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 10
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 11

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation


Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation
Dependent Variable: D(DGDP,2)
Dependent Variable: D(DEMPLOYMENT,2)
Method: Least Squares
Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/26/19 Time: 22:25 Date: 04/27/19 Time: 20:41
Sample (adjusted): 2008 2017 Sample (adjusted): 2007 2017
Included observations: 10 after adjustments Included observations: 11 after adjustments

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

D(DGDP(-1)) -3.244530 0.708321 -4.580590 0.0102 D(DEMPLOYMENT(-1)) -0.592391 1.335501 -0.443572 0.6729
D(DGDP(-1),2) 1.094413 0.577461 1.895215 0.1310D(DEMPLOYMENT(-1),2) -0.816176 0.956422 -0.853364 0.4262
D(DGDP(-2),2) 0.940256 0.370632 2.536901 0.0642D(DEMPLOYMENT(-2),2) -0.819373 0.481125 -1.703035 0.1395
D(DGDP(-3),2) 0.526759 0.170866 3.082874 0.0368 C 0.395780 0.568381 0.696329 0.5123
C -0.523225 0.311637 -1.678954 0.1685 @TREND("2002") -0.065217 0.059658 -1.093197 0.3162
@TREND("2002") 0.036407 0.028734 1.267054 0.2739
R-squared 0.945428 Mean dependent var 0.000000
R-squared 0.991651 Mean dependent var 0.100000Adjusted R-squared 0.909047 S.D. dependent var 1.732051
Adjusted R-squared 0.981215 S.D. dependent var 1.791957S.E. of regression 0.522358 Akaike info criterion 1.842029
S.E. of regression 0.245600 Akaike info criterion 0.313481Sum squared resid 1.637148 Schwarz criterion 2.022890
Sum squared resid 0.241277 Schwarz criterion 0.495033Log likelihood -5.131157 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.728021
Log likelihood 4.432593 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.114320F-statistic 25.98682 Durbin-Watson stat 1.719452
F-statistic 95.02356 Durbin-Watson stat 2.801805Prob(F-statistic) 0.000623
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000302
Appendix Figure 3. Unit Root Result of all Independent and Dependent Variables at
Second Difference
Null Hypothesis: D(DACTUALMAX,2) has a unit root Null Hypothesis: D(DACTUALMIN,2) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 2 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=2) Lag Length: 2 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=2)

t-Statistic Prob.* t-Statistic Prob.*

Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -5.788992 0.0075 Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -10.90985 0.0001
Test critical values: 1% level -5.521860 Test critical values: 1% level -5.521860
5% level -4.107833 5% level -4.107833
10% level -3.515047 10% level -3.515047

*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.


Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 9 and may not be accurate for a sample size of 9

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation


Dependent Variable: D(DACTUALMAX,3) Dependent Variable: D(DACTUALMIN,3)
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/26/19 Time: 19:28 Date: 04/26/19 Time: 19:30
Sample (adjusted): 2009 2017 Sample (adjusted): 2009 2017
Included observations: 9 after adjustments Included observations: 9 after adjustments

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

D(DACTUALMAX(-1),2) -4.513596 0.779686 -5.788992 0.0044 D(DACTUALMIN(-1),2) -5.306967 0.486438 -10.90985 0.0004
D(DACTUALMAX(-1),3) 1.942762 0.572351 3.394354 0.0274 D(DACTUALMIN(-1),3) 2.404849 0.344386 6.982993 0.0022
D(DACTUALMAX(-2),3) 0.551835 0.246940 2.234694 0.0891 D(DACTUALMIN(-2),3) 0.707362 0.149783 4.722571 0.0092
C -9.346331 9.854252 -0.948457 0.3966 C -2.851335 2.587877 -1.101805 0.3324
@TREND("2002") 0.771874 0.871299 0.885889 0.4257 @TREND("2002") 0.266988 0.228458 1.168651 0.3074

R-squared 0.977924 Mean dependent var -2.244444 R-squared 0.995956 Mean dependent var -0.588889
Adjusted R-squared 0.955849 S.D. dependent var 31.56518 Adjusted R-squared 0.991912 S.D. dependent var 18.84685
S.E. of regression 6.632549 Akaike info criterion 6.922036 S.E. of regression 1.694970 Akaike info criterion 4.193388
Sum squared resid 175.9628 Schwarz criterion 7.031606 Sum squared resid 11.49169 Schwarz criterion 4.302957
Log likelihood -26.14916 Hannan-Quinn criter. 6.685586 Log likelihood -13.87025 Hannan-Quinn criter. 3.956938
F-statistic 44.29867 Durbin-Watson stat 1.303048 F-statistic 246.2768 Durbin-Watson stat 1.784244
Prob(F-statistic) 0.001440 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000049

Null Hypothesis: D(DGDP,2) has a unit root


Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Null Hypothesis: D(DEMPLOYMENT,2) has a unit root
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=2) Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 2 (Automatic - based on SIC, maxlag=2)
t-Statistic Prob.*
t-Statistic Prob.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -6.264458 0.0034
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.328958 0.0388
Test critical values: 1% level -5.295384
Test critical values: 1% level -5.521860
5% level -4.008157
5% level -4.107833
10% level -3.460791
10% level -3.515047
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
Warning: Probabilities and critical values calculated for 20 observations
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 10
and may not be accurate for a sample size of 9

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation


Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation
Dependent Variable: D(DGDP,3) Dependent Variable: D(DEMPLOYMENT,3)
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/27/19 Time: 20:37 Date: 04/27/19 Time: 20:48
Sample (adjusted): 2008 2017 Sample (adjusted): 2009 2017
Included observations: 10 after adjustments Included observations: 9 after adjustments

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

D(DGDP(-1),2) -3.439947 0.549121 -6.264458 0.0008D(DEMPLOYMENT(-1),2) -5.603752 1.294480 -4.328958 0.0124


D(DGDP(-1),3) 0.761375 0.283237 2.688118 0.0361D(DEMPLOYMENT(-1),3) 2.663391 0.914130 2.913581 0.0435
C -1.279077 1.083990 -1.179971 0.2827D(DEMPLOYMENT(-2),3) 0.719643 0.410671 1.752356 0.1546
@TREND("2002") 0.108196 0.099339 1.089157 0.3179 C 0.826864 1.022360 0.808780 0.4640
@TREND("2002") -0.083109 0.091591 -0.907393 0.4155
R-squared 0.988026 Mean dependent var 0.700000
Adjusted R-squared 0.982040 S.D. dependent var 6.650814R-squared 0.994300 Mean dependent var -0.555556
S.E. of regression 0.891317 Akaike info criterion 2.896940Adjusted R-squared 0.988600 S.D. dependent var 6.166667
Sum squared resid 4.766672 Schwarz criterion 3.017974S.E. of regression 0.658428 Akaike info criterion 2.302259
Log likelihood -10.48470 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.764166Sum squared resid 1.734112 Schwarz criterion 2.411828
F-statistic 165.0348 Durbin-Watson stat 1.354275Log likelihood -5.360166 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.065809
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000004 F-statistic 174.4340 Durbin-Watson stat 2.394247
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000097
Appendix Figure 4. Regression Result of all Dependent Variables
Dependent Variable: DGDP Dependent Variable: DGDP
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/27/19 Time: 23:48 Date: 04/27/19 Time: 21:35
Sample (adjusted): 2004 2017 Sample (adjusted): 2004 2017
Included observations: 14 after adjustments Included observations: 14 after adjustments

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -0.358504 0.137391 -2.609368 0.0228 C -0.347480 0.127285 -2.729946 0.0183


DACTUALMAX 0.012700 0.030800 0.412324 0.6874 DACTUALMIN -0.067638 0.045517 -1.486004 0.1631

R-squared 0.013970 Mean dependent var -0.357143 R-squared 0.155418 Mean dependent var -0.357143
Adjusted R-squared -0.068200 S.D. dependent var 0.497245 Adjusted R-squared 0.085036 S.D. dependent var 0.497245
S.E. of regression 0.513921 Akaike info criterion 1.638071 S.E. of regression 0.475634 Akaike info criterion 1.483226
Sum squared resid 3.169383 Schwarz criterion 1.729365 Sum squared resid 2.714729 Schwarz criterion 1.574520
Log likelihood -9.466497 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.629620 Log likelihood -8.382582 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.474775
F-statistic 0.170011 Durbin-Watson stat 3.154337 F-statistic 2.208208 Durbin-Watson stat 2.802642
Prob(F-statistic) 0.687373 Prob(F-statistic) 0.163071

Dependent Variable: DEMPLOYMENT Dependent Variable: DEMPLOYMENT


Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/27/19 Time: 21:00 Date: 04/27/19 Time: 21:34
Sample (adjusted): 2004 2017 Sample (adjusted): 2004 2017
Included observations: 14 after adjustments Included observations: 14 after adjustments

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -0.153022 0.234185 -0.653426 0.5258 C -0.165864 0.230235 -0.720414 0.4851


DACTUALMAX 0.094876 0.052499 1.807174 0.0959 DACTUALMIN 0.161050 0.082332 1.956107 0.0741

R-squared 0.213933 Mean dependent var -0.142857 R-squared 0.241771 Mean dependent var -0.142857
Adjusted R-squared 0.148428 S.D. dependent var 0.949262 Adjusted R-squared 0.178585 S.D. dependent var 0.949262
S.E. of regression 0.875986 Akaike info criterion 2.704630 S.E. of regression 0.860335 Akaike info criterion 2.668573
Sum squared resid 9.208211 Schwarz criterion 2.795924 Sum squared resid 8.882111 Schwarz criterion 2.759867
Log likelihood -16.93241 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.696179 Log likelihood -16.68001 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.660122
F-statistic 3.265878 Durbin-Watson stat 2.647975 F-statistic 3.826354 Durbin-Watson stat 2.710399
Prob(F-statistic) 0.095854 Prob(F-statistic) 0.074134
Appendix Figure 5. Durbin Watson Result of all Independent and Dependent Variables
Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test: Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test:
Null hypothesis: No serial correlation at up to 1 lag Null hypothesis: No serial correlation at up to 1 lag

F-statistic 7.009532 Prob. F(1,11) 0.0227 F-statistic 3.578423 Prob. F(1,11) 0.0851
Obs*R-squared 5.448972 Prob. Chi-Square(1) 0.0196 Obs*R-squared 3.436443 Prob. Chi-Square(1) 0.0638

Test Equation: Test Equation:


Dependent Variable: RESID Dependent Variable: RESID
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:03 Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:02
Sample: 2004 2017 Sample: 2004 2017
Included observations: 14 Included observations: 14
Presample missing value lagged residuals set to zero. Presample missing value lagged residuals set to zero.

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -0.015511 0.112302 -0.138119 0.8926 C -0.018097 0.115877 -0.156175 0.8787


DACTUALMAX -0.003366 0.025174 -0.133702 0.8961 DACTUALMIN 0.013000 0.041864 0.310541 0.7620
RESID(-1) -0.637886 0.240934 -2.647552 0.0227 RESID(-1) -0.522168 0.276035 -1.891672 0.0851

R-squared 0.389212 Mean dependent var -2.38E-17 R-squared 0.245460 Mean dependent var 7.93E-18
Adjusted R-squared 0.278160 S.D. dependent var 0.493760 Adjusted R-squared 0.108271 S.D. dependent var 0.456974
S.E. of regression 0.419504 Akaike info criterion 1.287922 S.E. of regression 0.431527 Akaike info criterion 1.344436
Sum squared resid 1.935820 Schwarz criterion 1.424863 Sum squared resid 2.048371 Schwarz criterion 1.481377
Log likelihood -6.015456 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.275246 Log likelihood -6.411051 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.331759
F-statistic 3.504766 Durbin-Watson stat 1.477964 F-statistic 1.789212 Durbin-Watson stat 1.740598
Prob(F-statistic) 0.066435 Prob(F-statistic) 0.212448

Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test: Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test:


Null hypothesis: No serial correlation at up to 1 lag Null hypothesis: No serial correlation at up to 1 lag

F-statistic 2.585516 Prob. F(1,11) 0.1361 F-statistic 5.734788 Prob. F(1,11) 0.0356
Obs*R-squared 2.664398 Prob. Chi-Square(1) 0.1026 Obs*R-squared 4.797613 Prob. Chi-Square(1) 0.0285

Test Equation: Test Equation:


Dependent Variable: RESID Dependent Variable: RESID
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:06 Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:07
Sample: 2004 2017 Sample: 2004 2017
Included observations: 14 Included observations: 14
Presample missing value lagged residuals set to zero. Presample missing value lagged residuals set to zero.

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C 3.67E-05 0.220095 0.000167 0.9999 C 0.026322 0.195272 0.134798 0.8952


DACTUALMAX -0.023765 0.051507 -0.461395 0.6535 DACTUALMIN -0.166284 0.098398 -1.689910 0.1192
RESID(-1) -0.455559 0.283316 -1.607954 0.1361 RESID(-1) -0.826298 0.345047 -2.394742 0.0356

R-squared 0.190314 Mean dependent var 3.17E-17 R-squared 0.342687 Mean dependent var 3.12E-17
Adjusted R-squared 0.043099 S.D. dependent var 0.841620 Adjusted R-squared 0.223175 S.D. dependent var 0.826583
S.E. of regression 0.823284 Akaike info criterion 2.636378 S.E. of regression 0.728531 Akaike info criterion 2.391836
Sum squared resid 7.455758 Schwarz criterion 2.773319 Sum squared resid 5.838330 Schwarz criterion 2.528777
Log likelihood -15.45464 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.623701 Log likelihood -13.74285 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.379160
F-statistic 1.292758 Durbin-Watson stat 2.260382 F-statistic 2.867394 Durbin-Watson stat 2.068578
Prob(F-statistic) 0.313142 Prob(F-statistic) 0.099483
Appendix Figure 6. Ramsey Reset Result of all Independent and Dependent Variables
Ramsey RESET Test Ramsey RESET Test
Equation: UNTITLED Equation: UNTITLED
Specification: DGDP C DACTUALMAX Specification: DGDP C DACTUALMIN
Omitted Variables: Squares of fitted values Omitted Variables: Squares of fitted values

Value df Probability Value df Probability


t-statistic 1.203472 11 0.2541 t-statistic 0.417783 11 0.6841
F-statistic 1.448344 (1, 11) 0.2541 F-statistic 0.174542 (1, 11) 0.6841
Likelihood ratio 1.731693 1 0.1882 Likelihood ratio 0.220401 1 0.6387

F-test summary: F-test summary:


Sum of Sq. df Mean Squares Sum of Sq. df Mean Squares
Test SSR 0.368752 1 0.368752 Test SSR 0.042403 1 0.042403
Restricted SSR 3.169383 12 0.264115 Restricted SSR 2.714729 12 0.226227
Unrestricted SSR 2.800631 11 0.254603 Unrestricted SSR 2.672326 11 0.242939

LR test summary: LR test summary:


Value Value
Restricted LogL -9.466497 Restricted LogL -8.382582
Unrestricted LogL -8.600651 Unrestricted LogL -8.272382

Unrestricted Test Equation: Unrestricted Test Equation:


Dependent Variable: DGDP Dependent Variable: DGDP
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:04 Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:03
Sample: 2004 2017 Sample: 2004 2017
Included observations: 14 Included observations: 14

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -4.559413 3.493265 -1.305201 0.2185 C -0.102364 0.601352 -0.170223 0.8679


DACTUALMAX 0.304652 0.244469 1.246177 0.2386 DACTUALMIN -0.001875 0.164324 -0.011413 0.9911
FITTED^2 31.88806 26.49672 1.203472 0.2541 FITTED^2 -1.559182 3.732042 -0.417783 0.6841

R-squared 0.128693 Mean dependent var -0.357143 R-squared 0.168610 Mean dependent var -0.357143
Adjusted R-squared -0.029727 S.D. dependent var 0.497245 Adjusted R-squared 0.017448 S.D. dependent var 0.497245
S.E. of regression 0.504582 Akaike info criterion 1.657236 S.E. of regression 0.492888 Akaike info criterion 1.610340
Sum squared resid 2.800631 Schwarz criterion 1.794177 Sum squared resid 2.672326 Schwarz criterion 1.747281
Log likelihood -8.600651 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.644559 Log likelihood -8.272382 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.597664
F-statistic 0.812354 Durbin-Watson stat 3.278009 F-statistic 1.115426 Durbin-Watson stat 2.705439
Prob(F-statistic) 0.468751 Prob(F-statistic) 0.362182
Ramsey RESET Test Ramsey RESET Test
Equation: UNTITLED Equation: UNTITLED
Specification: DEMPLOYMENT C DACTUALMIN Specification: DEMPLOYMENT C DACTUALMAX
Omitted Variables: Squares of fitted values Omitted Variables: Squares of fitted values

Value df Probability Value df Probability


t-statistic 0.191101 11 0.8519 t-statistic 0.175615 11 0.8638
F-statistic 0.036520 (1, 11) 0.8519 F-statistic 0.030841 (1, 11) 0.8638
Likelihood ratio 0.046403 1 0.8294 Likelihood ratio 0.039197 1 0.8431

F-test summary: F-test summary:


Sum of Sq. df Mean Squares Sum of Sq. df Mean Squares
Test SSR 0.029391 1 0.029391 Test SSR 0.025745 1 0.025745
Restricted SSR 8.882111 12 0.740176 Restricted SSR 9.208211 12 0.767351
Unrestricted SSR 8.852720 11 0.804793 Unrestricted SSR 9.182466 11 0.834770

LR test summary: LR test summary:


Value Value
Restricted LogL -16.68001 Restricted LogL -16.93241
Unrestricted LogL -16.65681 Unrestricted LogL -16.91281

Unrestricted Test Equation: Unrestricted Test Equation:


Dependent Variable: DEMPLOYMENT Dependent Variable: DEMPLOYMENT
Method: Least Squares Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:07 Date: 04/28/19 Time: 00:06
Sample: 2004 2017 Sample: 2004 2017
Included observations: 14 Included observations: 14

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -0.219499 0.369332 -0.594313 0.5643 C -0.183642 0.300101 -0.611933 0.5530


DACTUALMIN 0.179550 0.129390 1.387665 0.1927 DACTUALMAX 0.099679 0.061207 1.628551 0.1317
FITTED^2 0.228965 1.198133 0.191101 0.8519 FITTED^2 0.150967 0.859648 0.175615 0.8638

R-squared 0.244280 Mean dependent var -0.142857 R-squared 0.216131 Mean dependent var -0.142857
Adjusted R-squared 0.106876 S.D. dependent var 0.949262 Adjusted R-squared 0.073609 S.D. dependent var 0.949262
S.E. of regression 0.897102 Akaike info criterion 2.808116 S.E. of regression 0.913657 Akaike info criterion 2.844687
Sum squared resid 8.852720 Schwarz criterion 2.945057 Sum squared resid 9.182466 Schwarz criterion 2.981628
Log likelihood -16.65681 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.795440 Log likelihood -16.91281 Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.832011
F-statistic 1.777828 Durbin-Watson stat 2.716652 F-statistic 1.516478 Durbin-Watson stat 2.639359
Prob(F-statistic) 0.214282 Prob(F-statistic) 0.262023

You might also like