You are on page 1of 57

The Economic Analysis of Terrorism

In the aftermath of 9/11 The Economic Analysis of Terrorism examines two


crucial questions. First, how does the new global terrorism affect the economy?
And second, what contribution can economics make to the analysis of terrorism?
The answers to both questions are comprehensive and intriguing.
Economic analysis is used throughout the volume to explain the deadly but
rational calculus of terrorists and to outline the choices available to national and
global policy makers in the fight against terrorism. The emphasis is on combing
the main economic theories on terrorism research with cutting edge empirical
evidence.
The Economic Analysis of Terrorism contains 17 thought-provoking articles
and essays by leading economists from Europe and North America. The authors
are experts in all areas of economic analysis, ranging from financial and insur-
ance economics, industrial organisation and business economics, microeconomics,
international macroeconomics and trade, public choice and public finance to
development economics.
This book represents the most thorough and systematic study of the economics
of terrorism published since 9/11. It will be of interest to students, researchers and
policy makers with an interest in the most challenging global policy issue facing
the world today.

Tilman Brück is the Head of the Department of International Economics at the


German Institute for Economic Research (DIW Berlin), Germany.
Routledge studies in defence and peace economics
Series Editors: Keith Hartley
University of York, UK and
Jurgen Brauer,
Augusta State University, USA.

1 European Armaments Collaboration


Policy, problems and prospects
R. Matthews

2 Military Production and Innovation in Spain


J. Molas-Gallart

3 Defence Science & Technology


Adjusting to change
R. Coopey, M. Uttley and G. Spiniardi

4 The Economics of Offsets


Defence procurement and countertrade
S. Martin

5 The Arms Trade, Security and Conflict


Edited by P. Levine and R. Smith

6 Economic Theories of Peace and War


F. Coulomb

7 From Defense to Development?


International perspectives on realizing the peace dividend
A. Markusen, S. DiGiovanna and M. Leary

8 Arms Trade and Economic Development


Theory, policy, and cases in arms trade offsets
Edited by Jurgen Brauer and J. Paul Dunne

9 The Economic Analysis of Terrorism


Edited by Tilman Brück
The Economic Analysis
of Terrorism

Edited by Tilman Brück


First published 2007
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada
by Routledge
270 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2007 Selection and editorial matter, Tilman Brück; individual chapters,
the contributors
This edition published in the Taylor & Francis e-Library, 2007.
“To purchase your own copy of this or any of Taylor & Francis or Routledge’s
collection of thousands of eBooks please go to www.eBookstore.tandf.co.uk.”
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or
utilised in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now
known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in
any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing
from the publishers.
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book has been requested

ISBN 0–203–01663–7 Master e-book ISBN

ISBN10: 0-415-36523-6 (hbk)


ISBN10: 0-203-01663-7 (ebk)

ISBN13: 978-0-415-36523-9 (hbk)


ISBN13: 978-0-203-01663-3 (ebk)
To Marta, with all my love
Contents

Figures x
Tables xii
Contributors xiv
Acknowledgements xvi

PART I
Introduction 1

1 A brief survey of the economic analysis of terrorism 3


TILMAN BRÜCK

PART II
Features of terrorism 11

2 An economic perspective on transnational terrorism 13


TODD SANDLER AND WALTER ENDERS

3 Economic conditions and terrorism 29


S. BROCK BLOMBERG, GREGORY D. HESS AND AKILA WEERAPANA

4 The economics of high-visibility terrorism 47


SANJAY JAIN AND SHARUN W. MUKAND

5 Decomposing violence: political murder in Colombia, 1946–99 64


JURGEN BRAUER, ALEJANDRO GÓMEZ-SORZANO AND SANKAR SETHURAMAN
viii Contents
PART III
Economic effects of terrorism 81

6 The effects of terrorism on global capital markets 83


ANDREW H. CHEN AND THOMAS F. SIEMS

7 Terrorism-induced structural shifts in financial risk: the


case of airline stocks in the aftermath of 11 September
terror attacks 107
KONSTANTINOS DRAKOS

8 Financial markets and terrorism 121


RAFI ELDOR AND RAFI MELNICK

9 Global terrorism and the insurance industry: new challenges


and policy responses 146
MICHAEL WOLGAST

10 Terrorism and international trade: an empirical investigation 173


VOLKER NITSCH AND DIETER SCHUMACHER

11 Fiscal consequences of armed conflict and terrorism


in low- and middle-income countries 185
SANJEEV GUPTA, BENEDICT CLEMENTS, RINA BHATTACHARYA AND
SHAMIT CHAKRAVARTI

PART IV
Anti-terrorist policies 207

12 Rights and citizenship in a world of global terrorism 209


DENNIS C. MUELLER

13 Decentralization as a response to terror 224


BRUNO S. FREY AND SIMON LUECHINGER
Contents ix
14 Global threats and the domestic struggle for power 231
MICHELLE R. GARFINKEL

15 Global financial information, compliance incentives and


terrorist funding 246
VALPY FITZGERALD

16 An economic analysis of security policies 262


TILMAN BRÜCK

PART V
Epilogue 283

17 Terror: the ‘ISM’ versus the ‘ISTS’ 285


GEOFFREY BRENNAN
Figures

2.1 All incidents and bombings. 17


2.2 Ordinal game matrix for retaliation. 22
4.1 Utility from a successful attack. 51
4.2 Expected utility of N and S attacks. 53
5.1 Total homicides, Colombia, 1946–1999. 65
5.2 Original data (total homicides per 100,000 people) and
permanent component according to HP and BN methods. 67
5.3 Cyclical component according to HP and BN methods. 68
6.1 Dow Jones industrial average 1915–2002. 90
6.2 US capital markets’ 11-day cumulative abnormal returns
(Dow Jones Industrial Average Index). 92
6.3 Global capital markets’ event-day abnormal returns following
the 11 September terrorist attacks. 96
6.4 Global capital markets’ 11-day cumulative average abnormal
returns following the 11 September terrorist attacks. 97
6.5 Global capital markets’ 11-day cumulative average abnormal
returns following Iraq’s invasion of Kuwait. 100
6.6 Global capital markets’ and banking/financial sector 11-day
cumulative average abnormal returns following the
11 September terrorist attacks. 103
6.7 Ten-year US treasury note rates 1982–2002. 104
8.1 Terror attacks, victims injured, victims killed and suicide
attacks. 123
8.2 The Tel Aviv 100 stock market index
[January 1990–June 2003 (log)]. 126
8.3 The Tel Aviv 100 and the S&P500 indices
[January 1990–June 2003 (log)]. 126
8.4 The basket of currencies exchange rate and the exchange rate
band [January 1990–July 2003]. 127
8.5 The Dollar and basket of currencies exchange rate
[January 1990–June 2003 (log)]. 128
Figures xi
8.6 The Tel Aviv 100 index – actual and simulated with the
pre-September 27, 2000 fundamental equation,
September 2000–June 2003. 131
11.1 Real GDP growth in conflict countries (average annual per cent
changes). 190
11.2 Consumer price inflation in conflict countries (average annual
per cent change). 191
11.3 Capital formation in conflict countries in per cent of GDP. 192
11.4 Fiscal aggregates in conflict countries in per cent of GDP. 193
11.5 Composition of government spending in conflict countries
in per cent of GDP. 194
12.1 Possible optimal majorities. 211
Tables

2.1 Transnational terrorism: events 1968–2001 15


2.2 Trend and other statistical properties of transnational terrorist
incidents 18
3.1 Terrorist incidence around the world average annual
incidence 1968–91 34
3.2 Estimates of 2 × 2 Markov processes for the economy and
terrorism 38
3.3 Estimates of 4 × 4 Markov processes for the economy and
terrorism 42
4.1 Payoff matrices with only passengers and hijackers 56
4.2 Payoff matrices with the possibility of sky marshals 57
6.1 Average abnormal returns on the Dow Jones Industrial Average
Stock Index following terrorist attacks 88
6.2 Average abnormal returns on global capital markets following
the 11 September terrorist attacks 94
6.3 Average abnormal returns on global capital markets following
Iraq’s invasion into Kuwait 99
6.4 Average abnormal returns on global capital markets’
banking/financial sectors following the 11 September terrorist
attacks 102
7.1 IATA members’ average (international scheduled services) 108
7.2 Quarterly financial review for US passenger airlines
(majors); 2001 109
7.3 The impact of 9/11 attacks on market value 111
7.4 Market model for individual airline stocks: estimation results 116
7.5 Tests of equality of volatility 117
7.6 Decomposition of total risk for individual airline stocks 118
8.1 Summary of terror attacks by categories
(January 1990–June 2003) 124
8.2 The damage rate of attacks by categories
(January 1990–June 2003) 125
8.3 Proportion of people killed, injured and days of a terror attack
by categories (January 1990–June 2003) 125
Tables xiii
8.4 Testing for unit roots (January 1990–June 2003) 129
8.5 Granger causality tests (6 lags) (January 1990–June 2003) 129
8.6 The fundamental regressions [January 1990–June 2003
(3515 daily observations)] 130
8.7 Interpreting the news of a terror attack 133
8.8 Testing the impact of terror on the stock exchange
(January 1990–June 2003) 134
8.8a Testing the impact of terror on the stock exchange
(January 1990–June 2003) 136
8.9 Testing the impact of terror on the dollar exchange rate
(February 1996–June 2003) 139
8.10 Testing the impact of terror on the basket exchange rate
(February 1996–June 2003) 141
8App Dependent variable Dlog (TA100) (included observations:
3515 after adjusting endpoints) 144
9.1 The worst terrorist acts in terms of casualties and insured
property losses 148
9.2 The most costly insurance losses 1970–2001 149
9.3 Development of major indexes on the stock market in 2001 150
9.4 Global insurance markets/inflow of new capital
(USD million) (as of 12 April 2002) 151
9.5 Synopsis of international model solutions for the insurance
of terror risks 160
10.1 Description of data on terrorist activity. Five countries that
suffered most strongly from terrorism; period: 1968–79 177
10.2 The impact of terrorism on trade 178
10.3 The impact of internal instability on trade 180
10.4 The impact of military personnel and defence expenditures
on trade 181
10.5 The impact of war on trade 182
11.1 Selected social indicators in countries experiencing
armed conflicts (average annual rates of change, per cent) 195
11.2 Regression results 196
11.3 Regression results: robustness test 199
Contributors

Rina Bhattacharya, OECD, Paris, France


S. Brock Blomberg, Department of Economics, Claremont McKenna
College, USA
Jurgen Brauer, James M. Hull College of Business, Augusta State
University, USA
Geoffrey Brennan, Social and Political Theory, RSSS, ANU, Political Science
Department, Duke University Philosophy Department, UNC-Chapel Hill
Tilman Brück, Department of International Economics, Economic Research
(DIW Berlin), Berlin, Germany
Shamit Chakravarti, Asian Development Bank, New Delhi, India
Andrew H. Chen, Distinguished Professor of Finance, Cox School of Business,
Southern Methodist University, USA
Benedict Clements, International Monetary Fund, Washington, USA
Konstantinos Drakos, Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University
of Patras, Greece
Rafi Eldor, Arison Business School, The Interdisciplinary Center, Israel
Walter Enders, Department of Economics, Finance, and Legal Studies,
University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa, USA
Valpy FitzGerald, Finance and Trade Policy Research Centre, University of
Oxford, UK
Bruno S. Frey, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of
Zurich, Switzerland
Michelle R. Garfinkel, Professor of Economics, Department of Economics,
University of California-Irvine, USA
Contributors xv
Alejandro Gómez-Sorzano, Consultant, Philadelphia, USA
Sanjeev Gupta, International Monetary Fund, Washington, USA
Gregory D. Hess, Claremont McKenna College, USA
Sanjay Jain, Department of Economics, University of Virginia, USA
Simon Luechinger, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of
Zurich, Switzerland
Rafi Melnick, Arison Business School, The Interdisciplinary Center, Israel
Dennis C. Mueller, Department of Economics, University of Vienna, Vienna
Sharun W. Mukand, Department of Economics, Tufts University, USA
Volker Nitsch, Department of Economics, Free University, Berlin, Germany
Todd Sandler, University of Texas at Dallas, School of Economics, Political and
Policy Sciences, USA
Dieter Schumacher, DIW Berlin, International Economics, Germany
Sankar Sethuraman, Department of Mathematics and Computer Science,
Augusta State University, USA
Thomas F. Siems, Senior Economist and Policy Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas, USA
Akila Weerapana, Department of Economics, Wellesley College, USA
Michael Wolgast, Chief Economist and Head of Economics Department, German
Insurance Association (GDV), Germany
Acknowledgements

This book emerged from the international conference on ‘The Economic Conse-
quences of the New Global Terrorism’ held at the German Institute for Economic
Research (DIW Berlin) in 2002. The workshop was made possible by the very
generous financial support from the German Insurance Association (GDV) and
the German Foreign Office. Some of the papers presented at the conference were
published in a special issue of the European Journal of Political Economy on
‘The Economic Consequences of Terror’ (Vol. 20, No. 2, June 2004), which was
edited by Tilman Brück and Bengt-Arne Wickström. I am grateful to Elsevier for
permission to reproduce some of the articles from that special issue in this volume.
I am also indebted to Stefanie Erdrich, Wolfgang Härle and Gisela Tietke for their
excellent research assistance, to the many authors of this volume for their support
in preparing this text, and to the extremely helpful staff at Taylor & Francis.

Tilman Brück
Part I
Introduction
1 A brief survey of the economic
analysis of terrorism
Tilman Brück

This introduction notes the importance of the economic analysis of the causes,
workings and consequences of global terrorism and discusses the costs of anti-
terrorist policy. It does so by summarizing the main contributions of this
volume.

1. Introduction
9/11 has focused attention on global terrorism in a way that no previous attacks had
ever done. Within the field of economics, it seemed initially as if there was a lack
of understanding about how to analyse terrorism. This early incomprehension
of the attacks had two dimensions. First, most academic economists felt they
had little to contribute to the debate about the nature and the workings of global
terrorism. Second, most economic analysts could not predict the likely economic
consequences of the attacks. Both dimensions are important as an understanding
of the nature of terrorism and the magnitudes of its effects is a prerequisite for
designing successful policies to prevent terror, to alleviate the costs of terrorism,
and to reduce an economy’s vulnerability to attacks.
Within a few months of the attacks, economists in many different sub-disciplines
realised that their toolkits had, after all, prepared them to tackle the analysis of
terrorism. For example, the study of shocks has long been a subject of international
economics, the effects of violent conflict have been analysed in development
economics for at least ten years and the economics of insurance naturally addresses
issues of risk.
To bring this young and diverse community of economic terror experts together,
the German Institute for Economic Research (DIW Berlin) organised an inter-
national conference in Berlin in June 2002. Most of the chapters of this book are
derived from the presentations at that conference. They hence provide one of the
first and most systematic analyses of terrorism from an economic point of view
to date.
The topics of this volume include on the one hand the economic analysis of the
functions and mechanisms of terrorism and on the other hand the economic effects
of the attacks in the short- and the long-term. Furthermore, the book offers some
4 Tilman Brück
insights from economics on the analysis of anti-terror policies. Methodologically,
the chapters in this book include analytical approaches, empirical studies and
policy analyses, thus providing a uniquely broad overview of the newly emerging
field of the economic analysis of terrorism.
In the remainder of this chapter, the key findings of this volume will be
summarized and discussed.

2. Features of terrorism
The first part of the book surveys some key economic features of terrorism. First,
Todd Sandler and Walter Enders provide an overview of data sources on terrorism.
Data that they present describe patterns of terror before the 9/11 attack and show
that prior terror attacks took place in cycles.
Sandler and Enders also emphasize that terrorists respond to changed incen-
tives and that anti-terrorist policies may induce substitution effects, with terrorists
moving from hard to soft targets or shifting their activities over time. Anti-terrorist
policy is therefore more successful if conducted across the entire spectrum of
potential terrorist activities so as to reduce terrorists’ substitution possibilities.
Otherwise a domestic anti-terrorist policy directed at stopping terror against the
national population would shift the focus of terrorist activities to other countries.
Sandler and Enders point out that, for example, guarding American embassies
more heavily abroad after the dual attacks on US embassies in Kenya and Tanzania
in the 1990s reduced embassy bombings but led to an increase in shootings and
abductions of embassy personnel away from the embassies themselves.
S. Brock Blomberg, Gregory Hess and Akila Weerapana study the relationship
between growth cycles and terrorism or civil war. They find that in richer demo-
cratic countries terrorism is more likely during economic downturns. Their chapter
emphasizes the need for further work about the relationship between conflict and
growth in poorer countries, the role of transnational terrorism versus domestic ter-
rorism, and the joint determination of both conflict and growth by omitted variables
such as weak governance.
With hindsight, it appears that the immediate or shorter-run economic effects
of the 9/11 attacks were contained by insightful policy making by the monetary
authorities in the US and Europe and by the robustness of the world economy
itself. It is thus ironic that an event that some interpret as an anti-globalization
attack failed to induce an international worst-case economic scenario due to the
stabilizing forces of globalization. Incidentally, this result is confirmed by Eldor
and Melnick in their chapter on the response of financial markets in Israel to
Palestinian terror (see below), suggesting that market liberalization enhanced the
capability of the Israeli economy to cope with terror.
Sanjay Jain and Sharun Mukand demonstrate in a theoretical model how terrorist
attacks change expectations, including the expectations of terrorists themselves.
Terror leads to anti-terror policies that affect the nature of future terror. By making
anti-terror policy less predictable, policy makers can increase the uncertainty
facing the terrorists, which is beneficial for society. Jain and Mukand show the
A brief survey of the economic analysis of terrorism 5
importance of policy makers responding to terror both verbally and through action,
and that anti-terrorist policy can also contain policy elements beyond standard
security or economic policies.
The importance of detailed data for the analysis of terrorism is also demon-
strated in the chapter by Jurgen Brauer, Alejandro Gómez-Sorzano and Sankara
Sethuraman on Colombia. They demonstrate the role of cyclical political variables
and permanent non-political variables using a novel source of data on politically
motivated and other types of murders.

3. Economic effects of terrorism


This section surveys contributions in this volume and elsewhere on the costs of
terror, the economic effects of terror on financial markets and international trade,
and the post-terror fiscal and growth effects in developing and developed countries.
Estimates of the costs of terrorism or violent conflict more generally confront
methodological problems of different types, including the definition of damage,
the measurement of losses, aggregation issues, avoidance of double counting
of damages in different sectors or statistics, and the causality of second round
and indirect effects. Against the background of such measurement problems, the
OECD estimated costs resulting from the terror attacks of 9/11 of 14 billion USD
for the private sector, 1.5 billion USD for state and local government enterprises,
0.7 billion USD for the US federal government, and 11 billion USD for the rescue
and clean-up operations, where the latter is shared between the private and the
public sectors (Lenain et al. 2002).
The direct economic costs of terrorism are most pronounced in the aftermath
of attacks. It appears that consumer confidence in the United States had started
to recover before 9/11 but then was held back by the psychological impact of the
attacks. In the medium term, the loss of confidence had an adverse self-reinforcing
effect on growth in the United States and Europe. The heightened uncertainty
reduced spending, slowed down firm investment, led to layoffs and increased
unemployment (Baily, 2001).
The intertemporal distribution of the indirect consequences depends on the
nature of the attacks, the multiplier effects of the direct effects, and the type of
policies adopted in response to the attacks. The US economy, for instance, recov-
ered quickly from the 9/11 attacks because the shocks were transitory and caused
proportionately little damage to the American capital stock, left oil prices unaf-
fected, and did not affect the economy’s ability to generate income and wealth.
This reflects a key difference between the economic legacies of terrorism and
war, with ongoing civil war in particular damaging a country’s capacity to grow
(see for example Abadie and Gardeazabal, 2003, Addison, 2003, and Stewart and
FitzGerald, 2001).
The indirect costs of terrorist attacks vary in their distribution across activities,
sectors, countries and time. Some activities and sectors are more vulnerable to
attacks than others and consequently suffer a higher burden. Service sectors, for
example, experienced a sharper drop in production if they were more closely
6 Tilman Brück
related to firms affected by the twin tower attacks of 9/11 or by border clo-
sures, as inventories of service output cannot be accumulated in times of slack
demand (Strauß, 2001). Highly networked and synchronized just-in-time indus-
trial production can be expected to have been affected by supply disruptions due
to 9/11.
Terror attacks can also change patterns of demand in the long-term. House-
holds, firms and governments may exhibit different preferences after exposure to
terror or may re-assess their vulnerability to attacks. Reductions in demand have
in particular been exhibited by the transport and tourism sectors. With regard to
tourism, Fleischer and Buccola (2002) find that foreign demand for accommo-
dation in Israel is price elastic and sensitive to regional terrorism. Local demand
for accommodation, on the other hand, is price inelastic and does not react nega-
tively to terrorism. Such effects through costs and changed demand are reflected in
financial markets where asset values respond to changes in expected profitability.
Increases in transaction costs are one of the main indirect effects of terror.
Strictly speaking, it is not the attacks themselves but the policy responses to the
attacks that cause these increases. These policies can include measures to prevent
and to detect terrorism. Given the nature of the attacks of 9/11, these measures are
especially enacted on borders and include closer inspections of people, vehicles
and goods as well as more restrictive immigration regulations. The estimates for
the scale of the increase in these international transaction costs vary between
0.5 per cent and 3 per cent ad valorem (Walkenhorst and Dihel, 2002). In addition,
domestic trade may also suffer from higher transaction costs if new regulations
prove costly for business – though the scale of such increases has not been estimated
to date.
Andrew Chen and Thomas Siems investigate the magnitudes of the effects of
9/11 on global and US share prices and compare the outcome to the consequences
of other political, economic or natural shocks. The magnitude of the effects of
9/11 on global and US financial markets was significant but not unique when
placed in historical perspective. While some sectors were particularly strongly
affected by 9/11, Chen and Siems show that the impact of the attacks on financial
markets varied greatly across countries. Furthermore, the reactions of financial
markets to 9/11 in the United States were less severe than the reactions to previous
negative shocks. They conclude from this that financial markets have become more
resilient to political shocks in recent years and that regulatory authorities reacted
wisely to the attacks by adding sufficient liquidity to the global financial system to
prevent a banking crisis. Their analysis demonstrates that consumers, firms, and
governments that are not directly physically harmed by terrorists thus still lose from
terror attacks. The question remains why market resilience varied so extensively
internationally, given that globalization has integrated national financial markets,
which should have resulted in more uniform responses to shocks.
Konstantinos Drakos finds that the already embattled airline industry was
strongly and aversely affected by 9/11. Changed risk perceptions by consumers
reduced demand for air travel and for complementary aircraft and hotel accom-
modation. Airlines also faced higher insurance rates when insurance companies
A brief survey of the economic analysis of terrorism 7
reassessed the likelihood of large-scale terror attack using airplanes. Airline shares
reflected these changes in lower stock market valuations. Airline shares thus exhib-
ited higher systematic and individual risks post–9/11, with the systematic risk of
selected US and European airlines shares more than doubling. This led fund man-
agers to reduce their exposure to these shares in their portfolios and hence put
further pressure on the value of the airline shares. The impact of the attacks may
have varied by airline (Carter and Simkins, 2002) but the pressure on the sector
as a whole increased significantly due to the attacks. A policy implication from
Drakos’ analysis is that state aid as a response to terror is not useful when terror
induces significant and permanent changes in demand patterns.
Rafi Eldor and Rafi Melnick use daily data to enable a close matching between
terror attacks and financial-market responses. Their study indicates that the stock
and foreign exchange markets in Israel functioned efficiently in the face of
Palestinian terror. Whereas the effects of the attack of 9/11 on financial markets
was a one-off event, the attacks directed at the population of Israel were ongoing,
with 639 terror attacks in the period 1990 to 2003. The empirical results indicate
that the terror did not affect the foreign exchange market but that the stock market
was affected, with stock prices internalizing expectations of reduced future profits.
The stock market (and also the foreign exchange market) never became desensi-
tized to terror attacks. Eldor and Melnick propose that the evidence regarding the
functioning of financial markets under continuous conditions of terror in Israel
has broader implications for the western world because of Israel’s well-developed
financial markets.
Michael Wolgast discusses in his contribution whether the insurance sector
should receive blanket subsidies in the wake of the attacks. Public-private partner-
ships aimed at providing some degree of insurance for large-scale terror attacks
have been instituted in several countries, for example the UK and Germany. These
are effectively re-re-insurers that aim to encourage insurance firms to cover terror
risks that otherwise would remain uninsurable within the private sector. From a
policy perspective, the main challenge in designing such schemes is to avoid dimin-
ishing incentives for private agents to reduce their or their customers’ exposure to
terror risks.
Volker Nitsch and Dieter Schumacher study the empirical effects of terrorism
and other forms of insecurity on international trade. They demonstrate that con-
flict, broadly defined, has significant dampening effects on bilateral trade flows.
A doubling of terror incidents reduces bilateral trade by four per cent. The study
by Nitsch and Schumacher raises the question whether policies can counteract the
negative effects of terrorism on transaction costs, for example through enhanced
international technical cooperation between customs officials and police forces.
Sanjeev Gupta, Benedict Clements, Rina Bhattacharya and Shamit Chakravarti
provide empirical evidence on the fiscal effects of terrorism in low- and middle-
income countries. Their focus is on the effects of terrorism on government spending
and revenue, and thereby on growth. The empirical results confirm that terrorism
has significant fiscal effects and both direct and indirect effects on growth in a
range of countries. Gupta et al. make an important contribution in identifying and
8 Tilman Brück
quantifying the fiscal transmission mechanism for terrorism. An important role
for aid conditionality is also identified, to avoid situations where governments in
poorer countries permit terrorism to exist in order to reap financial gains from the
fight of terrorism.

4. Anti-terrorist policies
The next section of the volume assesses some key policy issues in the fight against
terrorism from an economic point of view. Dennis Mueller, for instance, addresses
the policy implications of 9/11 by asking whether global terrorism should lead to
a re-evaluation of how to design constitutions, how to award citizenship, and how
to protect property rights. Mueller addresses the social dilemmas (or the trade-
off between the costs and benefits of constitutional rights) that western liberal
societies face in seeking to adhere to liberal values while at the same time protecting
citizens, residents, and future citizens from terror. The policy fields affected by
these dilemmas are broad, and include domestic civil rights, immigration and
education policies, the regulation of religions, and the granting of citizenship.
Mueller concludes that terror significantly influences the balance of rights defined
in a constitution. Mueller’s premise is that global terrorism seriously challenges
the democratic constitutional state. Yet 9/11 might not represent a failure of the
western system from within. That might have been more appropriate in the case
of the left-wing terrorism of 1970s Europe.
While death, injury and capital destruction are the most visible effects of a
terrorist attack, fear and the indirect effects of terror can be more harmful to the
economy in the longer term. Bruno Frey and Simon Luechinger argue that terrorists
are intent on causing such fear. This is particularly true for the consequences
of terror attacks in a centralized economy. Their chapter hence asks whether a
concerted anti-terrorist policy by a centralized government creates more fear than a
less intense anti-terror policy would. The former case would yield the paradoxical
result that anti-terror measures raise fear of terrorism further. Such a scenario
places governments in a dilemma where both responding and not responding to
terrorism plays into the terrorists’ hands. An implication of the argument made by
Frey and Luechinger is, for example, that centralizing political decision-making
in the European Union could attract terror attacks.
Michelle Garfinkel proposes a model in which a terror threat has two effects
on the domestic economy. On the one hand, a lower sense of domestic security
reduces the value of the gross domestic product, which in turn reduces the intensity
of the fight for the control of the state. On the other hand, if government policy
succeeds in reducing the scale or the effects of terrorism, the value of capturing
the state rises and the domestic struggle for power intensifies. In practice, both
effects were observed sequentially in domestic US politics after 9/11. Politicians
first rallied around the flag before eventually resuming and even intensifying the
domestic political struggle.
Garfinkel’s analysis raises some important questions. First, does the scale of
the two effects differ according to the type of conflict and the type of democracy?
A brief survey of the economic analysis of terrorism 9
One or the other of the effects dominating might explain why some democracies
appear to be in a high-conflict equilibrium (as Colombia, described by Brauer,
Gómez-Sorzano and Sethuraman in this volume), while other democracies enjoy
a low level of conflict (such as Switzerland, perhaps for reasons described by
Frey and Lüchinger in this volume). Second, are terrorists aware of their impact
on the domestic struggle for power and could this awareness be manipulated by
policy makers to reduce the intensity of conflict? The second option would then
open a strategic interaction between the domestic policy makers and the terrorists,
affecting income in the domestic economy and hence the intensity of the domestic
power struggle, and thus the probability of political survival of the domestic policy
maker.
Valpy FitzGerald investigates the international financial transactions supporting
global terrorism and how policy can detect and undermine terror-related financial
flows. He identifies obstacles to unilateral and multilateral policy initiatives in
this field. In particular, current regulatory systems do not succeed in excluding
suspected groups or individuals from undertaking transactions or the transactions
are reported too late for effective intervention to take place. Rather than adapt-
ing anti-money-laundering institutions to the task of combating terrorist finance,
FitzGerald suggests policies of disincentives for undertaking terrorist financial
transactions and improving systems for channelling migrant remittances.
In the last chapter of this section, Tilman Brück analyses security policy from
an economic perspective. He discusses the role of public goods for national and
global security and identifies the importance of the first- and second-order indi-
rect effects of insecurity on economic activity, which include the behavioural
responses of agents and the government to security measures, akin to such effects
in insurance economics. Furthermore, key public policy trade-offs are outlined, in
particular between security and efficiency, globalisation, equity and freedom. The
chapter identifies suitable policy options for raising security in the national and
international contexts and in view of these trade-offs. Brück calls for a suitable
balance between market and non-market instruments in achieving security to min-
imize the adverse effects of aiming for higher security. In addition, he emphasises
the importance of the public good nature of global security, which implies that the
international coordination of security policies is important, despite that process
being fraught with enforcement problems.

5. Epilogue
Together the chapters in this volume provide an introduction to and an overview of
the state of the art in the economic analysis of terrorism. The chapters indicate how
terrorism functions economically, how economies are affected by terror and how
policies can minimize the economic costs of terrorism and maximize the defence
against terror attacks.
In a critical and thought-provoking epilogue to this volume, Geoffrey Brennan
cautions to give too much attention to the phenomenon of terrorism. In particu-
lar, he recommends to shift the attention away from the motivations, incentives
10 Tilman Brück
and likely behaviour of terrorists and towards the mechanisms of response that
effectively mobilize the terror. He also draws attention to the limited ability of most
economic agents to assess correctly the expected costs of rare but extreme events,
which provokes the unanswered counter-question of how terrorists are able to
assess their impact in such a limited rationality framework. In his chapter, Brennan
warns that the combination of imperfectly perceived terror and volatile electoral
politics may yield sub-optimal or even counter-intuitive policy responses. In doing
so, Brennan identifies implicitly an important field for further research – the eco-
nomic analysis of the interaction of terrorism, politics and group mobilization in
both Western and Muslim societies.

References
Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003) ‘The economic costs of conflict: a case study of the
Basque Country’, American Economic Review, 93: 113–32.
Addison, T. (ed.) (2003) From Conflict to Recovery in Africa, Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Baily, M. N. (2001) Economic policy following the terrorist attacks, Washington, DC:
Institute for International Economics.
Carter, D. A. and Simkins, B. J. (2002) ‘Do markets react rationally?: The effect of the
11 September tragedy on airline stock returns’, Working Paper 26, Department of
Finance, College of Business Administration, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater.
Fleischer, A. and Buccola, S. (2002) ‘War, terror, and the tourism market in Israel’,
Applied Economics, 34: 1335–43.
Lenain, P., Bonturi, M. and Koen, V. (2002) ‘The economic consequences of terror-
ism’, OECD Working Paper: 334, Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development.
Stewart, F. and FitzGerald, E. V. K. (eds) (2001) War and Underdevelopment, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Strauß, H. (2001) ‘Assessing the effects of the terrorist attacks on the U.S. economy’,
Working Paper 17, Kiel: Institute of World Economics.
Walkenhorst, P. and Dihel, N. (2002) ‘Trade impacts of the terrorist attacks of 11 September
2001: a quantitative assessment’, International Conference on the Economic Conse-
quences of the New Global Terrorism, 14 and 15 June, Berlin: German Institute for
Economic Research (DIW Berlin).
References

1 A brief survey of the economic analysis


of terrorism

Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003) ‘The economic costs


of conflict: a case study of the Basque Country’, American
Economic Review, 93: 113–32.

Addison, T. (ed.) (2003) From Conflict to Recovery in


Africa, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Baily, M. N. (2001) Economic policy following the terrorist


attacks, Washington, DC: Institute for International
Economics.

Carter, D. A. and Simkins, B. J. (2002) ‘Do markets react


rationally?: The effect of the 11 September tragedy on
airline stock returns’, Working Paper 26, Department of
Finance, College of Business Administration, Oklahoma State
University, Stillwater.

Fleischer, A. and Buccola, S. (2002) ‘War, terror, and the


tourism market in Israel’, Applied Economics, 34: 1335–43.

Lenain, P., Bonturi, M. and Koen, V. (2002) ‘The economic


consequences of terrorism’, OECD Working Paper: 334, Paris:
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

Stewart, F. and FitzGerald, E. V. K. (eds) (2001) War and


Underdevelopment, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Strauß, H. (2001) ‘Assessing the effects of the terrorist


attacks on the U.S. economy’, Working Paper 17, Kiel:
Institute of World Economics.

Walkenhorst, P. andDihel, N. (2002) ‘Trade impacts of the


terrorist attacks of 11 September 2001: a quantitative
assessment’, International Conference on the Economic
Consequences of the New Global Terrorism, 14 and 15 June,
Berlin: German Institute for Economic Research (DIW
Berlin).
2 An economic perspective on
transnational terrorism

Alexander, Y. and Pluchinsky,D. (1992)Europe’s Red


Terrorists: TheFightingCommunist Organizations, London:
Frank Cass.

Atkinson, S.E., Sandler, T. and Tschirhart, J.T. (1987)


‘Terrorism in a bargaining framework’, Journal of Law and
Economics, 30: 1–21.

Brophy-Baermann, B. and Conybeare, J.A.C. (1994)


‘Retaliating against terrorism: rational expectations and
the optimality of rules versus discretion’, American
Journal of Political Science, 38: 196–210.

Drakos,K. andKutan,A.M. (2001) ‘Regional effects of


terrorismon tourism: evidence from three Mediterranean
countries’, paper presented at DIW conference on The
Economic Consequences of Global Terrorism, Berlin: German
Institute for Economic Research (DIW Berlin).

Enders, W., Parise, G.F. and Sandler, T. (1992) ‘A


time-series analysis of transnational terrorism: trends and
cycles’, Defence Economics, 3: 305–20.

Enders, W. and Sandler, T. (1991) ‘Causality between


transnational terrorism and tourism: the case of Spain’,
Terrorism, 14: 49–58.

—— (1993) ‘The effectiveness of anti-terrorism policies:


vector-autoregressionintervention analysis’, American
Political Science Review, 87: 829–44.

—— (1996) ‘Terrorism and foreign direct investment in Spain


and Greece’, Kyklos, 49: 331–52.

—— (1999) ‘Transnational terrorism in the post-cold war


era’, International Studies Quarterly, 43: 145–67.

—— (2000) ‘Is transnational terrorism becoming more


threatening?’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44: 307–32.

——(2002) ‘Patterns of transnational terrorism, 1970–99:


alternative time series estimates’, International Studies
Quarterly, 46: 145–65.

Enders,W., Sandler, T. andCauley, J. (1990) ‘UNconventions,


technology and retaliation in the fight against terrorism:
an econometric evaluation’, Terrorism and Political
Violence, 2: 83–105.

Enders, W., Sandler, T. and Parise, G.F. (1992) ‘An


econometric analysis of the impact of terrorism on
tourism’, Kyklos, 45: 531–54.

Hirshleifer, J. (1991) ‘The paradox of power’, Economics


and Politics, 3: 177–200.

Hoffman, B. (1997) ‘The confluence of international and


domestic trends in terrorism’, Terrorism and Political
Violence, 9: 1–15.

—— (1998) Inside Terrorism, New York: Columbia University


Press.

Im, E.I., Cauley, J. and Sandler, T. (1987) ‘Cycles and


substitutions in terrorist activities: a spectral
approach’, Kyklos, 40: 238–55.

Islam,M.Q. and Shahin,W.N. (1989) ‘Economic methodology


applied to political hostagetaking in light of the
Iran-Contra affair’, Southern Economic Journal, 55:
1019–24. Kupperman, R.N. (1987) ‘Vulnerable America’, in
Wilkinson, P. and Stewart, A.M. (eds), Contemporary
Research on Terrorism, pp. 570–80, Aberdeen, UK: University
of Aberdeen Press. Landes, W.M. (1978) ‘An economic study
of US aircraft hijackings, 1961–76’, Journal of Law and
Economics, 21: 1–31. Lapan, H.E. and Sandler, T. (1988) ‘To
bargain or not to bargain: that is the question’, American
Economic Review, 78: 16–20. —— (1993) ‘Terrorism and
signalling’, European Journal of Political Economy, 9:
383–97. Lee, D.R. (1988) ‘Free riding and paid riding in
the fight against terrorism’, American Economic Review, 78:
22–6. Mickolus, E.F. (1982) International Terrorism:
Attributes of Terrorist Events 1968–77. (ITERATE 2), Ann
Arbor, MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and
Social Research. Mickolus, E.F. and Fleming, P. (2003)
International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist Events
1992–2002, Dunn Loring, VA: Vinyard Software. Mickolus,
E.F., Sandler, T., Murdock, J.M. and Fleming, P. (1989)
International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist Events,
1978–87. (ITERATE 3), Dunn Loring, VA: Vinyard Software.
Mickolus, E.F., Sandler, T., Murdock, J.M. and Fleming, P.
(1993) International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist
Events, 1988–91. (ITERATE 4), Dunn Loring, VA: Vinyard
Software. Overgaard, P.B. (1994) ‘Terrorist attacks as a
signal of resources’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38:
452–78. Sandler, T. and Lapan, H.E. (1988) ‘The calculus of
dissent: an analysis of terrorists’ choice of targets’,
Synthèse, 76: 245–61. Sandler, T. and Scott, J.L. (1987)
‘Terrorist success in hostage-taking incidents’, Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 31: 35–53. Sandler, T., Tschirhart,
J.T. and Cauley, J. (1983) ‘A theoretical analysis of
transnational terrorism’, American Political Science
Review, 77: 36–54. Scott, J.L. (1991) ‘Reputation building
in hostage incidents’, Defence Economics, 2: 209–218.
Selten, R. (1988) ‘A simple game model of kidnappings’, in
R. Selten (ed.) Models of Strategic Rationality, pp. 77–93,
Boston: Kluwer Academic. United States Department of State
(various years) Patterns of Global Terrorism. Washington,
DC: US Department of State. Wilkinson, P. (1986)Terrorism
and the Liberal State, Revised edition, London: Macmillan.
3 Economic conditions and terrorism

Atkinson, S., Sandler, T. and Tschirhart, J. (1987)


‘Terrorism in a bargaining framework’, Journal of Law and
Economics, 30: 1–21.

Bernholz, P. (2003) Supreme values as the basis for terror,


unpublished paper, University of Basel, Switzerland.

Blomberg, S.B. and Hess, G.D. (2002) ‘The temporal links


between conflict and economic activity’, Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 46: 74–90.

Blomberg, S.B., Hess, G.D. and Thacker, S. (2002) ‘Is there


a conflict-poverty trap?’, Wellesley College Working Paper
2000–06, Wellesley, MA.

Brueck, T. (2002) ‘The macroeconomic effects of the war


onMozambique’, QEHWorking Paper #11, Oxford, UK.

Burns, A. and Mitchell, W. (1944) Measuring business


cycles, New York: NBER.

Enders, W. and Sandler, T. (1993) The effectiveness of


anti-terrorism policies: vector autoregression intervention
analysis’, American Political Science Review, 87: 839–44.

Gelpi, C. (1997) ‘Democratic diversions: governmental


structure and the externalization of domestic conflict’,
Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41: 255–82.

Grossman, H.I. (1991) ‘A general equilibriummodel of


insurrections’, American Economic Review, 81: 912–21.

Hess, G.D. and Orphanides, A. (1995) ‘War politics: an


economic, rational-voter framework’, American Economic
Review, 85: 828–46.

—— (2001) ‘Economic conditions, elections and the magnitude


of foreign conflicts’, Journal of Public Economics, 80:
121–40.

Lapan, H. and Sandler, T. (1988) ‘To bargain or not to


bargain: that is the question’, American Economic Review
Papers and Proceedings, 78: 16–21.

Lian, B. and O’Neal, J. (1993) ‘Presidents, the use of


military force, and public opinion’, Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 37: 277–300.
—— (1993) ‘Terrorism and signaling’, European Journal of
Political Economy, 9: 383–97.

Mickolus, E., Sandler, T., Murdock, J. and Fleming, P.


(1993) International terrorism: attributes of terrorist
events (ITERATE), Dunn Loring, VA: Vinyard Software.

O’Brien, S.P. (1996) ‘Foreign policy crises and the resort


to terrorism: A time series analysis of conflict linkages’,
Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41: 320–35.

Ostrom, C.W. and Job, B.L. (1986) ‘The president and the
political use of force’, American Political Science Review,
80: 541–66.

Russett, B. (1990) ‘Economic decline, electoral pressure,


and the initiation of international conflict’, in Gochman,
C.S. and Sobrosky, A.S. (eds), Prisoners of war, Lexington,
MA: Lexington Books.

Sandler, T. (2000) ‘Economic analysis of conflict’, Journal


of Conflict Resolution, 44: 723–9.

Stoll, R. (1984) ‘The guns of November: presidential


reelections and the use of force, 1947–82’, Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 28: 231–46.

Tornell, A. (1998) ‘Reform from within’, Working Paper


6497, Cambridge, MA: NBER.
4 The economics of high-visibility
terrorism

Atkinson, S., Sandler, T. and Tschirhart, J. (1987)


‘Terrorism in a bargaining framework’, Journal of Law and
Economics 30(1): 1–21.

Becker, G. (1968) ‘Crime and punishment: an economic


approach’, Journal of Political Economy 76(2): 169–217.

Krueger, A. andMaleckova, J. (2002) ‘Education, poverty,


political violence and terrorism: Is there a causal
connection’, NBER Working Paper 9074, Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research.

Kunreuther, H. and Heal, G. (2002) ‘Interdependent


security: the case of identical agents’, NBER Working Paper
8871, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Landes, W. (1978) ‘An economic study of US aircraft


hijackings, 1961–76’, Journal of Law and Economics 21(1):
1–31.

Lapan, H. E. and Sandler, T. (1988) ‘To bargain or not to


bargain: That is the question’, American Economic Review
Papers and Proceedings, 78: 16–20.

Lee, D. R. (1988) ‘Free riding and paid riding in the fight


against terrorism’, American Economic Review Papers and
Proceedings, 78: 22–6.

Morris, S. and Shin, H.-S. (1997) ‘Approximate common


knowledge and coordination’, Journal of Logic, Language and
Information 6: 171–90.

Morris, S. and Shin, H.-S. (1998) ‘Unique equilibrium in a


model of self-fulfilling currency attacks’, American
Economic Review 88(3): 587–97.

Osborne, M. and Rubinstein, A. (1994) A Course in Game


Theory, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Rubinstein, A. (1989) ‘The electronicmail game: strategic


behaviour under almost common knowledge’, American Economic
Review 79(3): 385–91.

Sandler, T. and Enders, W. (2004) ‘An economic perspective


on transnational terrorism’, European Journal of Political
Economy 20(2): 301–16.
Sandler, T., Tschirhart, J. and Cauley, J. (1983) ‘A
theoretical analysis of transnational terrorism’, American
Political Science Review 77(1): 36–54.

Sprinzak, E. (2000) ‘Rational fanatics’, Foreign Policy


120, Sept/Oct 2000: 66–73.

Selten, R. (1988) ‘A simple game model of kidnappings’, in


R. Selten (ed.) Models of Strategic Rationality, pp. 77–93,
Boston: Kluwer Press.

Townsend, R. (1979) ‘Optimal contracts and competitive


markets with costly state verification’, Journal of Economic
Theory 21(2): 265–93.
5 Decomposing violence: political murder
in Colombia, 1946–99

Bejarano, J.A. (1997) ‘Inseguridad, violencia y actividad


económica’, Lecturas de Economía [Medellín, Colombia],
July–December: 7–24.

Beveridge, S. andNelson, C.R. (1981) ‘A new approach to


decomposition of economic time series into permanent and
transitory componentswith particular attention
tomeasurement of the “business cycle”’, Journal of Monetary
Economics, 7(2): 151–74. Brito, D.L. and Intriligator, M.D.
(1992) ‘Nacro-traffic and guerrilla warfare: a new
symbiosis’, Defence Economics, 3: 263–74. Bushnell, D.
(1993) The Making of Modern Colombia: A Nation In Spite of
Itself. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Cárdenas, M. (1991) ‘Coffee Exports, Endogenous State
Policy and the Business Cycle’, PhD thesis, Economics.
University of California, Berkeley, CA. Collier, P. (1999)
‘On the economic consequences of civil war’, Oxford
Economic Papers 51(1): 168–83. —— (2000) ‘Doing well out of
war: an economic perspective’, in M. Berdal and D.M. Malone
(eds) Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil War,
pp. 91–111, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Cuddington, J. and
Winters, L.A. (1987) ‘The Beveridge-Nelson decomposition of
economic time series’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 19:
125–7. Dinar, A. and Keck, A. (1997) ‘Private irrigation
investment in Colombia: effects of violence, macroeconomic
policy, and environmental conditions’, Agricultural
Economics, 16(1): 1–15. Giraldo, J. (1996) ‘Colombia: The
Genocidal Democracy’, Common Courage Press, Monroe, ME.
Guerrero, R. (1998) ‘Epidemiology of violence in the
Americas: the case of Colombia’, in: Burki, S.J, Aiyer,
S.R. and Hommes, R. (eds) Annual World Bank Conference on
Development in Latin America and the Caribbean: Poverty and
Inequality, pp. 95–100 (Bogotá, Colombia) The World Bank,
Washington, DC. Harvey, A.C. and Jaeger, A. (1993)
‘Detrending, stylized facts and the business cycle’,
Journal of Applied Econometrics 8: 231–47. Hodrick, R.J.
and Prescott, E.C. (1997) ‘Postwar US business cycles: an
empirical investigation’, Journal of Money, Banking, and
Credit, 29: 1–16. Kirk, R. (2003) More Terrible than Death:
Massacres, Drugs, and America’s War in Colombia, New York:
Public Affairs. London˜o, J.L. (1998) ‘Violence, psyche,
and social capital’ in: Burki, S.J, Aiyer, S.R. and Hommes,
R. (eds) Annual World Bank Conference on Development in
Latin America and the Caribbean: Poverty and Inequality,
pp. 71–82, (Bogotá, Colombia) The World Bank, Washington,
DC. Maravall, A. and del Río, A. (2001) ‘Time aggregation
and the Hodrick-Prescott filter’, Working Paper No. 108,
Madrid: Bank of Spain. Miller, S.M. (1988)
‘TheBeveridge-Nelson decomposition of economic time series:
another economic computation method’, Journal of Monetary
Economics, 21: 141–2. Newbold, P. (1990) ‘Precise and
efficient computation of the Beveridge-Nelson decomposition
of economic time series’, Journal of Monetary Economics,
26: 453–57. Ravn,M.O. and Uhlig, H. (2002) ‘On adjusting
the Hodrick-Prescott filter for the frequency of
observations’, The Review of Economics and Statistics,
84(2): 371–80. Richani, N. (1997) ‘The political economy of
violence: the war-system in Colombia’, Journal of
Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, 39(2): 37–81.
Rubio, M. (1997) ‘Perverse social capital – some evidence
from Colombia’, Journal of Economic Issues, 31(3): 805–16.
—— (1998a) ‘Violence, organized crimes, and the criminal
justice system in Colombia’, Journal of Economic Issues,
32(2): 605–10. —— (1998b) Comment, in: Burki, S.J., Aiyer,
S.R. and Hommes, R. (eds), Annual World Bank Conference on
Development in Latin America and the Caribbean: Poverty and
Inequality, pp. 90–2, (Bogotá, Colombia) The World Bank,
Washington, DC.

Sambanis, N. (2002) ‘A review of recent advances and future


directions in the quantitative literature on civil war’,
Defence and Peace Economics, 13: 215–43.

Wold, H. (1938) A Study in the Analysis of Stationary Time


Series, Stockholm: Almquist and Wiksell.
6 The effects of terrorism on global
capital markets

Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003) ‘The Economic Costs


of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country’, American
Economic Review, 93: 113–32.

Arshanapalli, B. and Doukas, J. (1993) ‘International Stock


Market Linkages: Evidence from the Preand Post-October 1987
Period’, Journal of Banking and Finance, 17: 193–208.

Brown, S.J. and Warner, J.B. (1985) ‘Using Daily Stock


Returns: The Case of Event Studies’, Journal of Financial
Economics, 14: 3–31.

Constitutional Rights Foundation (2001), Significant


Terrorist Attacks. Available HTTP:
<http://www.crf-usa.org/terror/significant%20attacks>

Fama, E.F., Fisher, L., Jensen, M.C. and Roll, R. (1969)


‘The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information’,
International Economic Review, 10: 1–21.

Hamao, Y., Masulis, R.W. and Ng, V. (1990) ‘Correlations in


Price Changes and Volatility across International Stock
Markets’, Review of Financial Studies, 3: 281–307.

Schwert, G.W. (1981) ‘Using Financial Data to Measure


Effects of Regulation’, Journal of Law and Economics, 24:
121–58.

USDepartment of State (2001) ‘Significant Terrorist


Incidents, 1961–2001: AChronology’. Office of the Historian,
Bureau of Public Affairs, October 31. Available HTTP:
<http://usinfo.state.gov/topical/pol/terror/01103131.htm>
7 Terrorism-induced structural shifts in
financial risk: the case of airline
stocks in the aftermath of 11 September
terror attacks

Bhattacharya, U., Daouk, H., Jorgenson, B. and Kehr, C.


(2000) ‘When an event is not an event: the curious case of
an emerging market’, Journal of Financial Economics, 55:
69–101.

Brown, R., Durbin, J. and Evans, J. (1975) ‘Techniques for


testing the constancy of regression relations over time’,
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 37: 149–92.

Brown, S. and Warner, J. (1985) ‘Using daily stock returns:


the case of event studies’, Journal of Financial Economics,
14: 3–31.

Campbell, J., Lo, A. and MacKinlay, C. (1997) The


Econometrics of Financial Markets, Princeton, New Jersey:
Princeton University Press.

Carter, D. and Simkins, B. (2002) ‘Do markets react


rationally? the effects of the September 11 th tragedy on
airline stock returns’, unpublished manuscript, Oklahoma:
State University.

Chen, A. and Siems, T. (2002) ‘An empirical analysis of the


capital markets’ response to cataclysmic events’,
unpublished manuscript presented at the DIW Conference on
the Economic Consequences of September 11 th .

Chow, C. (1960) ‘Test of equality between sets of


coefficients in two linear regressions’, Econometrica, 28:
591–605.

Conover, W. and Johnson, M. (1981) ‘A comparative study of


tests for homogeneity of variance with applications to the
outer continental shelf bidding data’, Technometrics, 23:
351–61. Corrado, C. (1989) ‘A nonparametric test for
abnormal security-price performance in event studies’,
Journal of Financial Economics, 23: 385–95. Department of
Transportation (USA), ‘Airline quarterly financial review’,
Office for Aviation Analysis, various issues from 1995:
Q1–2001:Q3. Fama, E., Fisher, L., Jensen, M. and Roll, R.
(1969) ‘The adjustment of stock prices to new information’,
International Economic Review, 10(1): 1–21. IATA (2001)
‘Monthly international statistics’, March 2000–December
2001. IATA (2001) ‘Corporate air travel survey and post
September 11 th supplementary survey’. Lintner, J. (1965)
‘The valuation of risky assets and the selection of risky
investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets’,
Review of Economics and Statistics, pp. 394–419. Malatesta,
P. and Thompson, R. (1985) ‘Partially anticipated events: a
model of stock price reactions with an application to
corporate acquisitions’, Journal of Financial Economics,
14: 237–50. Sharpe, W. (1964) ‘Capital asset prices: a
theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk’,
Journal of Finance, 19: 425–42. White, H. (1980) ‘A
heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator
and a direct test for heteroskedasticity’, Econometrica
48(4): 817–38. Wilson, B., Saunders, A. and Caprio, G.
(2000) ‘Financial fragility andMexico’s 1994 peso crisis:
an event-window analysis of market-valuation effects’,
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32(3): 450–68.
8 Financial markets and terrorism

Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003) ‘The Economic Costs


of Conflict: A Case-Control Study for the Basque Country’,
American Economic Review, 94: 113–132.

Bernholz, P. (2004) ‘Supreme values as the basis for


terror’, European Journal of Political Economy, 20.

Brenner, M., Eldor, R. and Hauser, S. (2001) ‘The price of


options Illiquidity’, The Journal of Finance, 56: 789–805.

Chen, A.H. and Siems, T.F. (2004) ‘The effects of terrorism


on global capital markets’, European Journal of Political
Economy, 20.

Eckstein, Z. andTsiddon,D. (2004) ‘Macroeconomic


consequences of terror: theory and the case of Israel’,
Discussion Paper No. 3–2004, The Pinhas Sapir Center for
Development, Tel-Aviv University.

Fleischer, A. and Buccola, S. (2002) ‘War, terror, and the


tourismmarket in Israel’, Applied Economics, 34: 1335–43.

Melnick, R. (2002) ‘Business Cycles in Israel’, The


Economic Quarterly, 49: 219–44 (Hebrew).

Orgler, Y.E. (2002) ‘The Tel-Aviv Stock Exchange (TASE):


Functioning in a turbulent Period’, Journal of Global
Financial Markets, (winter), pp. 44–56.

Trajtenberg, M. (2003) ‘Defense R&D Policy in the


anti-terrorist era’, NBER Working Paper 9725, Cambridge MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
9 Global terrorism and the insurance
industry: new challenges and policy
responses

Guinn, P. (2002), Why Are Insurance Prices Going up?, in:


Leaders Magazine, vol. 25, number 2 (April 2002), p. 150,
also available under www.leadersmag.com

Heck, Warren W. (2002), Lack of Terrorism Reinsurance


Threatens Economic Recovery, Washington Legal Foundation,
Legal Backgrounder vol. 17, No. 10, Washington DC, 22
February 2002.

Hillman, R. J. (2002), Terrorism Insurance, Rising


Uninsured Exposure to Attacks Heightens Potential Economic
Vulnerabilities, Testimony before the Subcommittee on
Oversight and Investigations, Committee on Financial
Services, House of Representatives, General Accounting
Office, Washington DC, 27 February 2002.

Jaffee, D. and Russell, Th. (2002), Extreme Events and the


Market for Terrorist Insurance, mimeo, 11 January 2002.

Karten, W. (1972), Zum Problem der Versicherbarkeit und zur


Risikopolitik des Versicherungsunternehmens –
betriebswirtschaftliche Aspekte, in: Zeitschrift für die
gesamte Versicherungswissenschaft, vol. 61, pp. 279–299.

—— (1988), Existenzrisiken der Gesellschaft –


Herausforderung für die Assekuranz, in: Zeitschrift für die
gesamte Versicherungswissenschaft, vol. 77, pp. 343–362.

—— (1997), How to Expand the Limits of Insurability, Geneva


Papers on Risk and Insurance, No. 85, pp. 515–522.

—— (2000), Versicherungsbetriebslehre: Kernfragen aus


entscheidungstheoretischer Sicht, Karlsruhe.

Kessler, D. and Lamère, J.-M. (2002a), The Financial Impact


of September 11 on the French Insurance Market, in: Études
et Dossiers, Working Paper Series of the Geneva
Association, No. 251, Special Issue on the Economic
Consequences of the September 11 Attacks on National
Insurance Markets, Geneva, pp. 59–76.

—— (2002b), The Financial Impact of September 11 on the


French Insurance Market, in: Liedtke, P., and Courbage, C.
(eds.), Insurance and September 11 – One Year After,
Impact, Lessons and Unresolved Issues, International
Association for the Study of Insurance Economics, Geneva,
pp. 56–69.

Kollar, John J. (2002), Terrorism Insurance Coverage in the


Aftermath of September 11 th , A Public Statement by the
Extreme Events Committee of the American Academy of
Actuaries, mimeo, 17 April 2002, available under
www.actuary.org

Kunreuther,H. (2002), TheRole of Insurance


inManagingExtremeEvents: Implications for Terrorism
Coverage, December 2001, Wharton Financial Institutions
Center Working Paper No. 02-07, Wharton School, University
of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.

Lakdawalla, D. and Zanjani, G. (2002), ‘Insurance,


Self-Protection, and the Economics of Terrorism’, NBER
Working Paper 9215, Cambridge MA, also available under
www.nber.org/papers/w9215

McCall, John J. (1987), Insurance, in: Eatwell, J.,


Milgate, M., Newman, P. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary
of Economics, vol. 2, E-J, Basingstoke, New York, pp.
868–870.

—— (1992), Insurance, in: Newman, P., Milgate, M., Eatwell,


J. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and
Finance, vol. 2, F-M, London, New York, pp. 424–427.

Munich Re (2001), Press Release of 29 th November 2001,


www.munichre.com

Nell, M. (2001), Staatshaftung für Terrorrisiken?, in: Zur


Diskussion gestellt: Risikoübernahme – sollte der Staat
bestimmte Versicherungsgarantien übernehmen?, ifo
Schnelldienst, vol. 54, No. 24, pp. 6–9.

OECD (2002), Economic Consequences of Terrorism, in:


Economic Outlook 71, Spring 2002, pp. 117–140. Rees, R.
(2001), Kein Grund für staatliche Interventionen, in: Zur
Dikussion gestellt: Risikoübernahme – sollte der Staat
bestimmte Versicherungsgarantien übernehmen?, ifo
Schnelldienst, vol. 54, No. 24, pp. 5–6. Rogoff, K. (2002),
‘Opening Remarks on the World Economic Outlook Press
Conference’, available under www.imf.org Schaad, W. (2002),
Terrorism – dealing with the new spectre, Swiss Re Focus
Report, Zurich. Sinn, H.-W. (1986), Risiko als
Produktionsfaktor (Risk as a Factor of Production), in:
Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik (Journal of
Economics and Statistics), vol. 201/6, pp. 557–571. ——
(1988), Gedanken zur volkswirtschaftlichen Bedeutung des
Versicherungswesens, in: Zeitschrift für die gesamte
Versicherungswissenschaft, vol. 77, pp. 1–27. Straubhaar,
Th. (2003), Die Weltwirtschaft nach dem 11. September: Mehr
Regulierung oder mehr Markt?, in: Zeitschrift für
Politikwissenschaft, vol. 13, forthcoming, available under
www.hwwa.de/hwwa.html Swiss Re (2002), Natural catastrophes
and man-made disasters in 2001: man-made losses take on a
new dimension, sigma No. 1/2002, Zurich. Tillinghast-Towers
Perrin (2001), Pool Re and Terrorism Insurance in Great
Britain, Update, October 2001. Wolgast,M. (2001),
Zweckgerichtete Arbeitsteilung zwischen
Versicherungswirtschaft und Staat ist erforderlich, in: Zur
Diskussion gestellt: Risikoübernahme – sollte der Staat
bestimmte Versicherungsgarantien übernehmen?, ifo
Schnelldienst, vol. 54, No. 24, pp. 12–14. —— (2002a), The
implications of 11 September for the German insurance
industry, in: Études et Dossiers, Working Paper Series of
the Geneva Association, No. 251, Special Issue on the
Economic Consequences of the September 11 Attacks on
National Insurance Markets, Geneva, pp. 77–97. —— (2002b),
The implications of 11 September for the German Insurance
Industry, in: Liedtke, P. and Courbage, C. (eds.),
Insurance and September 11 – One Year After, Impact,
Lessons and Unresolved Issues, International Association
for the Study of Insurance Economics, Geneva, pp. 70–86. ——
(2002c), Global terrorism and the insurance industry: The
case for public-sectorintervention, in: Insurance
Economics, No. 46, International Association for the Study
of Insurance Economics, Geneva, July 2002, pp. 7–10. ——
(2002d), Global Terrorism and the Insurance Industry: New
Challenges and Policy Responses, in Liedtke, P. and
Courbage, C. (eds.), Insurance and September 11 – One Year
After, Impact, Lessons and Unresolved Issues, International
Association for the Study of Insurance Economics, Geneva,
pp. 243–257. —— (2002e), ‘Insurability of the Risks of
Terrorism and the Role of the State’, in: Asia Insurance
Review, December, pp. 33–35.
10 Terrorism and international trade: an
empirical investigation

Banks, A. S. (1979) Cross National Time-Series Data


Archive, updated, Center for Social Analysis, State
University of New York at Binghampton.

Barbieri, K. and Schneider, G. (1999) ‘Globalization and


peace: assessing new directions in the study of trade and
conflict’, Journal of Peace Research, 36: 387–404.

Barro, R. J. and Lee, J.-W. (1994) Data Set for a Panel of


138 Countries, Department of Economics, Harvard University.

Buckelew, A. H. (1984) Terrorism and the American Response,


San Rafael, CA: Mira Academic Press.

Easterly, W. and Sewadeh, M. (2002) Global Development


Network Growth Database, Washington, DC: World Bank.

Frankel, J. A. (1997) Regional Trading Blocs, Washington,


DC: Institute for International Economics.

Glick, R. and Rose, A. K. (2002) ‘Does a currency union


affect trade?: The time series evidence’, European Economic
Review, 46: 1125–51.

Grossman, H. (2001) ‘Creation of effective property


rights’, American Economic Review, 91: 347–52.

Gupta, S., deMello, L. and Sharan, R. (2001) ‘Corruption


andmilitary spending’, European Journal of Political
Economy, 17: 749–77.

McCallum, J. (1995) ‘National borders matter: Canada-US


regional trade patterns’, American Economic Review, 85:
615–23.

Mickolus, E. F. (1980) Transnational Terrorism, Westport,


CT: Greenwood Press. Mickolus, E. F. and Simmons, S. L.
(1997) Terrorism, 1992–1995, Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.
Morrow, J. D., Siverson, R. M. and Tabares, T. E. (1998)
‘The political determinants of international trade: the
major powers, 1907–90’, American Political Science Review,
92: 649–61. Polachek, S. W. (1980) ‘Conflict and trade’,
Journal of Conflict Resolution, 24: 55–78. Pollins, B.M.
(1989) ‘Does trade still follow the flag?’, American
Political Science Review, 83: 465–80. Reuveny, R.
(1999–2000) ‘The trade conflict debate: a survey of theory,
evidence and future research’, Peace Economics, Peace
Science and Public Policy, 6: 23–49. Rose, A. K. (2000)
‘One money, one market: the effect of common currencies on
trade’, Economic Policy, 30: 7–45. Skaperdas, S. and
Syropoulos, C. (2001) ‘Guns, butter, and openness: on the
relationship between security and trade’, American Economic
Review, 91: 353–57. US Department of State (2002) Patterns
of Global Terrorism 2001. Available at
www.state.gov/s/ct/rls/pgtrpt/2001/pdf. Walkenhorst, P. and
Dihel, N. (2002) Trade impacts of the terrorist attacks of
11 September 2001: a quantitative assessment. Paris: OECD.
11 Fiscal consequences of armed conflict
and terrorism in low- and middle-income
countries

Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2001) ‘The economic costs


of conflict: a case study of the Basque country’, American
Economic Review, 93: 113–32.

Addison, T. and Murshed, S.M. (2001) ‘The fiscal dimensions


of conflict and reconstruction’, WIDER Discussion Paper No.
2001/49, World Institute for Development Economics
Research, Helsinki: United Nations University.

Addison, T., Chowdhury, A.R. and Murshed, S.M. (2002) ‘By


how much does conflict reduce financial development?’, WIDER
Discussion Paper No. 2002/48. World Institute for
Development Economic Research, Helsinki: United Nations
University. Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1993) ‘Income
distribution, political instability, and investment’, NBER
Working Paper No. 4486, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. —— (1996) ‘Income distribution,
political instability, and investment’, European Economic
Review, 40: 1203–28. Alesina, A., Ozler, S., Roubini, N.
and Swagel, P. (1996) ‘Political instability and economic
growth’, Journal of Economic Growth, 1: 189–212. Arora, V.
and Bayoumi, T. (1993) Economic benefits of reducing
military expenditure, Annex II in World Economic Outlook,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Arunatilake,
N., Jayasuriya, S. and Kelegama, S. (2001) ‘The economic
cost of the war in Sri Lanka’, Research Studies:
Macroeconomic Policy and Planning, Series No. 13, Colombo:
Institute of Policy Studies of Sri Lanka. Bahl, R.W. (1971)
‘A regression approach to tax effort and tax ratio
analysis’, IMF Staff Papers, 18: 570–612. Barro, R.J.
(1991) ‘Economic growth in a cross section of countries’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 407–43. Bayoumi, T.,
Hewitt, D. and Schiff, J. (1993) ‘Economic consequences of
lower military spending: some simulation results’, IMF
Working Paper No. 93/17, Washington, D.C: International
Monetary Fund. Benoit, E. (1978) ‘Growth and defense in
developing countries’, Economic Development and Cultural
Change, 26: 271–80. Brunetti, A. and Weder, B. (1998)
‘Investment and institutional uncertainty: a comparative
study of different uncertainty measures’,
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv/Review of World Economics, 134:
513–33. Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2002a) ‘Aid, policy
and growth in post-conflict economies’, paper presented at a
Joint World Bank-IMF Seminar, Washington, DC Collier, P.
and Hoeffler, A. (2002b) ‘Military expenditures: threats,
aid, and arms races’, paper presented at a Joint World
Bank-IMF Seminar, Washington, DC Davoodi, H., Clements, B.,
Debaere, P. and Schiff, J. (2001) ‘Military spending, the
peace dividend, and fiscal adjustment’, IMF Staff Papers 48
(2), 290–316. Available at
www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/staffp/2001/01/index.htm.
Drakos, K. and Kutan, A.M. (2001) ‘Regional effects of
terrorism on tourism: Evidence from three Mediterranean
countries’, Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI),
Working Paper No. 26, Bonn: Rheinische
Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universität. Easterly,W. and Levine, R.
(1997) ‘Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic
divisions’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112: 1203–50.
Ebrill, L., Keen, M., Bodin, J.P. and Summers, V. (2001)
The Modern VAT, Washington, DC: International Monetary
Fund. Enders, W., Sandler, T. and Parise, G.F. (1992) ‘An
econometric analysis of the impact of terrorism on
tourism’, Kyklos, 45: 531–54. Enders, W. and Sandler, T.
(1991) ‘Causality between transnational terrorism and
tourism: the case of Spain’, Terrorism, 14: 49–58.
Gleditsch, N.P., Strand, H., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M.
and Wallensteen, P. (2001) ‘Armed conflict 1946–99: a new
dataset’, paper presented at the Euroconference on:
Identifying Wars: Systematic Conflict Research and Its
Utility in Conflict Resolution and Prevention. Uppsala
University, Uppsala, Sweden. Gupta, S., deMello, L. and
Sharan, R. (2001) ‘Corruption andmilitary spending’,
European Journal of Political Economy, 17: 748–77.

Gupta, S., Plant, M., Dorsey, T. and Clements, B. (2002)


‘Is the PRGF living up to expectations?’, Finance and
Development, 39: 17–20.

Hess, G.D. (2003) ‘The economic welfare cost of conflict: an


empirical assessment’, Working Paper, Department of
Economics, Claremont McKenna College, CA.

Knight, M., Loayza, N. and Villanueva, D. (1996) ‘The peace


dividend: military spending cuts and economic growth’, IMF
Staff Papers, 43: 1–37.

Lucas Jr., R.E. (1987) Models of Business Cycles, Oxford:


Blackwell.

Ndikumana, L. (2001) ‘Fiscal policy, conflict, and


reconstruction in Burundi and Rwanda’, WIDER Discussion
Paper No. 2001/62, World Institute for Development
Economics Research, Helsinki: United Nations University.

Nitsch, V. and Schumacher, D. (2002) ‘Terrorism and trade’,


paper presented at the German Institute for Economic
Research (DIW) workshop, The Economic Consequences of
Global Terrorism. Available at www.diw.de/deutsch/service/
veranstaltungen/ws_consequences.

Richardson Jr., J.M. and Samarasinghe, de A.S.W.R. (1991)


‘Measuring the economic dimensions of Sri Lanka’s ethnic
conflict’, in Samarasinghe, de A. and Coughlan, R. (eds)
Economic Dimensions of Ethnic Conflict, New York : St.
Martin’s Press.

Rodrik, D. (1999) ‘Where did all the growth go? external


shocks, social conflict, and growth collapses’, Journal of
Economic Growth, 4: 385–412.

Shieh, J.-Y., Ching-Chong, L. and Wen-Ya, C. (2002)


‘Endogenous growth and defense expenditures: a new
explanation of the Benoit hypothesis’, Defense and Peace
Economics, 13: 179–86.

Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, SIPRI


Yearbook, 2001, Armaments, Disarmament and International
Security, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Tanzi, V. (1992) ‘Structural factors and tax revenue in


developing countries: a decade of evidence’, in Goldin, I.
and Winters, L.A. (eds) Open Economies: Structural
Adjustment and Agriculture, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.

US Department of State (2002) ‘Patterns of global


terrorism–2001’ (Washington, D.C.). Available at
www.state.gov/s/ct/rls/pgtrpt/2001/html.

Venieris, Y.P. and Gupta, D.K. (1986) ‘Income distribution


and sociopolitical instability as determinants of savings:
a cross-sectional model’, Journal of Political Economy, 94:
873–83.

Walkenhorst, P. andDihel, N. (2002) ‘Trade impacts of the


terrorist attacks of 11 September 2001: a quantitative
assessment’, paper presented at the German Institute for
Economic Research (DIW)workshop, TheEconomicConsequences
ofGlobal Terrorism. Available at
www.diw.de/deutsch/service/veranstaltungen/ws_consequences.

World Bank (2000) ‘Economic causes of civil conflict and


their implications for policy’, press briefing, June 15,
Washington, DC Available at www.worldbank.
org/html/extdr/extme/pr061500.htm.
12 Rights and citizenship in a world of
global terrorism

Breton, A. (1996) Competitive Governments, Cambridge:


Cambridge University Press.

Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1962) The Calculus of


Consent, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Condorcet, M. de (1785) ‘Essai sur l’application de


l’analyse á la probabilité des décisions rendues á la
probabilité des voix. De l’imprimerie royale’, Paris;
English translation: ‘Essay on the Application of
Mathematics to the Theory of Decision Making’, in: Baker,
K. (ed.) (1976) Condorcet, Selected Writings, Indianapolis:
Boobs-Merrill.

Eaton, R.M. (ed.) (1927) Descartes Selections, New York:


Charles Scribner’s Sons.

Friedman, M. (1962) Capitalism and Freedom, Chicago:


University of Chicago Press.

Mueller, D.C. (1991) ‘Constitutional rights’, Journal of


Law, Economics, andOrganization, 7: 313–33.

—— (1996) Constitutional Democracy, Oxford/New York: Oxford


University Press.

—— (2000) ‘Capitalism, democracy and rational individual


behavior’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10: 67–82.

—— (2001) ‘The importance of uncertainty in a two-stage


theory of constitutions’, Public Choice, 108: 223–58.

—— (2002) ‘Defining citizenship’, Theoretical Inquiries in


Law, 3: 151–66.

Wittman, D. (1995) The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why


Political Institutions are Efficient, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.

Young, H.P. (1997) ‘Group choice and individual judgments’,


in Mueller, D.C. (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice, pp.
181–200, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
13 Decentralization as a response to
terror

Badey, T.J. (1998) ‘Defining international terrorism: a


pragmatic approach’, Terrorism and Political Violence, 10:
90–107.

Enders, W. and Sandler, T. (1995) ‘Terrorism: theory and


applications’, in Hartley, K. and Sandler, T. (eds)
Handbook of Defense Economics, Vol. 1. Handbooks in
Economics, Vol. 12, Amsterdam, New York and Oxford:
Elsevier, 213–49.

Freedom House (2000) Freedom in the World. The Annual


Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties, 1999–2000,
New York: Freedom House.

Frey, B.S. (1988) ‘Fighting political terrorism by refusing


recognition’, Journal of Public Policy, 7: 179–88.

——(1997) Not Just for The Money. An Economic Theory of


Personal Motivation, Cheltenham, UK, and Brookfield, USA:
Edward Elgar.

——(2004) Dealing With Terrorism: Sticks or Carrots?,


Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Frey, B.S. and Eichenberger, R. (1999) The New Democratic


Federalism for Europe: Functional Overlapping and Competing
Jurisdictions, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Frey, B.S. and Luechinger, S. (2003) ‘How to fight


terrorism: alternatives to deterrence’, Defence and Peace
Economics, 14: 237–49.

Frey, B.S., Luechinger, S. and Stutzer, A. (2006)


‘Calculating tradegy: Assessing the costs of terrorism:
Journal of Economic Surveys, forthcomming.

Hoffman, B. (1998) Inside Terrorism, New York: Colombia


University Press.

Kirk, R.M. (1983) ‘Political terrorism and the size of


government: a positive institutional analysis of violent
political activity’, Public Choice, 4: 41–52.

Lake, D.A. (2002) ‘Rational extremism: understanding


terrorism in the twenty-first century’, Dialog-IO (Spring),
15–29.
Landes, W.A. (1978) ‘An economic study of US aircraft
hijackings, 1961–1976’, Journal of Law and Economics, 21:
1–31.

Lapan, H.E. and Sandler, T. (1988) ‘To bargain or not to


bargain: that is the question’, American Economic Review,
78: 16–21.

Laqueur, W. (1977) Terrorism, Boston: Little Brown.

Lichbach, M.I. (1987) ‘Deterrence or escalation? The puzzle


of aggregate studies of repression and dissent’, Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 31: 266–97.

Sandler, T. and Enders, W. (2002) ‘An economic perspective


on transnational terrorism’, Mimeo, Los Angeles: University
of South California. Sandler, T. and Lapan, H.E. (1988)
‘The calculus of dissent: an analysis of terrorists’ choice
of targets’, Synthese, 76: 245–61. Sandler, T., Tschirhart,
J. and Cauley, J. (1983) ‘A theoretical analysis of
transnational terrorism’, American Political Science
Review, 77: 36–54. Schelling, T.C. (1991) ‘What purposes
can “international terrorism” serve?’, in Frey, R.G. and
Morris, C.W. (eds) Violence, Terrorism, and Justice, pp.
18–32, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wilkinson, P.
(2002) Terrorism Versus Democracy: The Liberal State
Response, London: Frank Cass.
14 Global threats and the domestic
struggle for power

Robinson, James A. (2001) ‘Social identity, inequality, and


conflict’, Economics of Governance, 2: 85–99.

Sandler, Todd and Enders, Walter (2004) ‘An economic


perspective on transnational terrorism’, European Journal
of Political Economy, 20: 301–16.

Skaperdas, Stergios (1992) ‘Cooperation, conflict and power


in the absence of property rights’, American Economic
Review, 82: 720–39.

Skocpol, Theda (2002) ‘Will 9/11 and the war on terror


revitalize American civic democracy?’, Political Science
and Politics, 35: 537–40.

Tullock, Gordon (1980) ‘Efficient rent seeking’, in


Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert D., Tullock, Gordon
(eds), Toward a Theory of the Rent Seeking Society. Texas
A&M University Press, College Station, pp. 3–15.
15 Global financial information,
compliance incentives and terrorist
funding

Nawaz, S., McKinnon, R. andWebb, R. (2002) ‘The war on


South Asia’s hawala networks: fighting financial crime or
undermining financial services for the poor?’ Institute for
Development Policy Management, Manchester University,
Manchester:

OECD (1998) Harmful Tax Competition: an Emerging Global


Issue, Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development, Paris.

OECD (2000) Towards Global Tax Cooperation: Progress in


Identifying and Eliminating Harmful TaxPractices.
Organization forEconomicCooperation andDevelopment, Paris.

Philippsohn, S. (2001) ‘The dangers of new technology –


laundering on the internet’, Journal of Money Laundering
Control, 5: 87–85.

Sandler, T., Tschirhart, J.T. and Cauley, J. (1983) ‘A


theoretical analysis of transnational terrorism’, American
Political Science Review, 77: 36–54.

Santomero, A. (1984) ‘Modelling the banking firm: a survey’,


Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 16: 576–602.

Stiglitz, J. (2002) ‘Information and the change in the


paradigm in economics’, American Economic Review, 92:
460–501.

Tanzi, V. (1996) ‘Globalization, tax competition and the


future of tax systems’, IMF Working Paper 96/141,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

UN (1998) Financial Havens, Banking Secrecy and Money


Laundering, UN Office for Drug Control and Crime Prevention,
Vienna.

UNCTAD (1995) Incentives and Foreign Direct Investment,


United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva.

Zee, H.H. (1998) ‘Taxation of financial capital in a


globalised environment: the role of withholding taxes’,
National Tax Journal, 51: 587–99.
16 An economic analysis of security
policies

Kunreuther, H. and Heal, G. (2003) ‘Interdependent


Security’, The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 26(2/3):
231–49.

Kunreuther, H., Kerjan, E. M. and Porter, B. (2003)


‘Assessing, Managing and Financing Extreme Events: Dealing
with Terrorism’, NBER Working Paper Series, 10179.

Leibfritz, W. (2003) ‘Auswirkungen des Terrorismus auf die


Volkswirtschaften und Implikationen für die
Wirtschaftspolitik’, Ifo Schnelldienst 56(1): 14–20.

Lenain, P., Bonturi, M. and Koen, V. (2002) ‘The Economic


Consequences of Terrorism’, OECD Economics Department
Working Papers, 334.

Leonard, J. S. (2001) ‘Impact of the September 11, 2001


Terrorist Attacks on North American Trade Flows’,
Manufacturers Alliance E-Alert, Arlington Virginia.

Limao,N. andVenables,A. J. (2001) ‘Infrastructure,


GeographicalDisadvantage, Transport Costs and Trade’, World
Bank Economic Review, 15: 451–79.

Lyon,D. (2003) ‘MidtoLong-term Implications for Society of


theGrowingUse of Security Technologies’, Paper presented at
the OECD Forum for the Future on ‘The Security Economy:
What Trade-Offs in an Open and Mobile Society?’, Paris.

Nordhaus, W. D. (2002) ‘The Economic Consequences of War


with Iraq’, The New York Review of Books, 49(19).

Paldam, M. and Würtz, A. (2003) ‘The Big Bend – Economic


Freedom and Growth’, paper presented at the European Public
Choice Society annual meeting in Aarhus.

Phillips, L. T. (2001) ‘A Crisis of Security and


Economics’, Regulation, 24(4): 53–6.

Raby, G. (2003) ‘The Cost of Terrorism and the Benefits of


Cooperating to Combat Terrorism’, paper presented at the
SecureTrade in theAPECRegion (STAR)Conference.

Ram,R. (1995) ‘DefenseExpenditure andEconomicGrowth’,


inHartley,K. andSandler, T. (eds) Handbook of Defense
Economics, pp. 251–73, Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Sandler, T. (2003) ‘Collective Action and Transnational
Terrorism’, The World Economy, 26(6): 779–802.

______ (2005) ‘Collective versus Unilateral Responses to


Terrorism’, Public Choice, forthcoming.

Sheffi, Y. (2001) ‘Supply Chain Management under the Threat


of International Terrorism’, The International Journal of
Logistics Management, 12(2): 1–11.

Stevens, B. (2003) ‘Factors Shaping the Demand for Security


Goods and Services’, paper presented at theOECDForumfor
theFuture on ‘TheSecurityEconomy:WhatTrade-Offs in an Open
and Mobile Society?’, Paris.

Sunstein, C. R. (2003) ‘Terrorism and Probability Neglect’,


The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 26(2/3): 121–36.

Walkenhorst, P. and Dihel, N. (2002) ‘Trade Impacts of the


Terrorist Attacks of 11 September 2001: A Quantitative
Assessment’, paper presented at the workshop on ‘The
Economic Consequences of Global Terrorism’, DIW Berlin.

WorldBank (2003) ‘Reducing TradingCosts in aNewEra of


Security’, inGlobal Economic Prospects 2004: Realizing the
Development Promise of the Doha Agenda World Bank: 179–203.
17 Terror: the ‘ISM’ versus the ‘ISTS’

Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. andWelch, I. (1992) ‘A


Theory of Fads Fashions, Custom and Cultural Change as
Informational Cascades’, Journal of Political Economy, 100:
992–1026.

Brennan, G. and Hamlin, A. (2004) ‘The European


Constitution and Peace: Taking the Heat out of Politics’,
in Blankart, C. and Mueller, D. (eds) A Constitution for
the European Union MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass. 1–24.
Brennan, G. and Pettit, P. (2004) The Economy of Esteem,
Oxford: Oxford University Press pp. 339 + xii. Fedderson,
T. and Pesedorfer, W. (1998) ‘Convicting the Innocent’,
American Political Science Review, 92: 23–35. Frey, B.
(2004) Dealing with Terrorism: Stick or Carrot?,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar pp. 182 + xvi. McLuhan, M. and
Powers, B. (1988) The Global Village, Oxford: Oxford
University Press. Prentice, D. and Miller, D. (1993)
‘Pluralistic Ignorance and Alcohol Use on Campus’, Journal
of Personality and Social Psychology, 64: 243–56.

You might also like