You are on page 1of 10

Articles

https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-017-0001-0

Effectiveness of state climate and energy policies


in reducing power-sector CO2 emissions
Geoff Martin1,2 and Eri Saikawa *
1

States have historically been the primary drivers of climate change policy in the US, particularly with regard to emissions
from power plants. States have implemented policies designed either to directly curb greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions from
power plants, or to encourage energy efficiency and renewable energy growth. With the federal government withdrawing from
the global climate agreement, understanding which state-level policies have successfully mitigated power-plant emissions is
urgent. Past research has assessed policy effectiveness using data for periods before the adoption of many policies. We assess
17 policies using the latest data on state-level power-sector CO2 emissions. We find that policies with mandatory compliance
are reducing power-plant emissions, while voluntary policies are not. Electric decoupling, mandatory GHG registry/reporting
and public benefit funds are associated with the largest reduction in emissions. Mandatory GHG registry/reporting and public
benefit funds are also associated with a large reduction in emissions intensity.

T
he United States (US) plays an important role in the global from state-level policies that are confined to state borders, there are
effort to address climate change. The US has historically been also regional initiatives through which states collaborate to reduce
the world’s largest emitter of CO2, and is currently the second emissions. Of these subnational efforts, two in particular address
largest emitter1. Within the US, the electric power sector is responsi- power-sector emissions—the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
ble for the largest share of the country’s GHG emissions, contribut- (RGGI) and the Western Climate Initiative (WCI)—and are anal-
ing to 29% of total emissions in 20152, with a wide variation among ysed in this study.
the states (Fig. 1). Yet to date, the US federal government has not Much of the literature assessing the effectiveness of state-level
implemented any policies specifically addressing GHG emissions climate and energy policies has examined the impact of different
from the power sector. policy measures on investment in renewables or increasing renew-
States have historically been the primary drivers of climate able capacity. The focus has largely been on binding renewable
change policy in the US3, 4. As states aim to fill the federal void on portfolio standards (RPS), which typically require electric utilities
climate leadership, they have the opportunity to learn from past to provide a certain amount of electricity from renewable sources,
experience and create plans to address power-sector emissions and results have been mixed. Some found it to increase in-state
based on empirical evidence. Understanding which state-level renewable energy development8 and in-state renewable investment
policies are effective at reducing power-sector emissions therefore and deployment, although not increasing the percentage of renew-
becomes especially important. able energy generation9. Others found that RPS had a significant
State policymakers have implemented climate-related policies negative effect on investments in renewable capacity because the
that fall into two broad categories—climate policies and energy adoption was mostly symbolic10, 11. Some studies have gone beyond
policies with climate implications3, 5. Climate policies are those that RPS and found that RPS, combined with other policies, was asso-
explicitly target GHG emissions from power plants. Energy policies ciated with increased wind generation12 and non-hydro renewable
with climate implications (henceforth referred to as energy policies) energy penetration13.
do not explicitly target GHG emissions or climate change in their Ultimately what matters from a climate lens is not whether poli-
design, but rather are intended to change the energy landscape in cies increase renewable energy, but rather whether they are success-
ways that have implications for GHG emissions and climate change. ful in curbing GHG emissions. Increased investment in renewables,
While climate change may motivate the adoption of energy policies, greater renewable capacity or even higher renewable generation
reducing GHG emissions is not explicit in the policy design. Energy levels cannot serve as a suitable proxy for the decarbonization of
policies can thus be framed in terms of economic opportunities or the power sector, as simply increasing renewable capacity without
energy security, rather than as climate solutions, potentially making decreasing fossil fuel electricity generation is not a solution to cli-
it easier to garner bipartisan support3, 6. mate change. However, little empirical research has been conducted
There are two final distinctions with regard to policy types. demonstrating the strengths or weaknesses of various power-sector
First, states can design policies to be either mandatory or volun- climate-related policies with regard to their effectiveness at reduc-
tary. Mandatory policies establish legally binding targets, and non- ing CO2 and other GHG emissions.
compliance can result in penalties, whereas voluntary policies do The limited number of studies that have assessed the effect of
not have a legal mechanism for enforcement. Most policies, with the state-level policies on CO2 emissions are either outdated or are too
exception of climate action plans (CAPs), can be neatly assigned to narrow in focus. Drummond (2010)14 divided state climate actions
either the voluntary or mandatory category. There is a wide varia- into two broad categories—CAPs and the presence of policy entre-
tion, however, among and even within CAPs, as plans can often preneurs—and found that the presence of these factors, alone or
contain both voluntary and mandatory components7. Finally, aside in combination, led to moderate reduction of GHG emissions.

Department of Environmental Sciences, Emory University, Atlanta, GA 30322, USA. 2Planning and Development, Town of Hartford, Hartford 05001 VT,
1

USA. *e-mail: eri.saikawa@emory.edu

912 Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange

© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE Articles
250

200
MMTCO2 per year

150

100

50

0
VT
ID
ME
RI
AK
SD
NH
DE
HI
CT
OR
MA
WA
NV
NJ
MT
MD
MS
NE
NM
MN
VA
ND
KS
NY
SC
IA
UT
AR
TN
CO
LA
WI
OK
WY
CA
AZ
NC
GA
MI
AL
MO
WV
KY
IL
OH
PA
IN
FL
TX
State

Fig. 1 | Carbon dioxide emissions (in million metric tonnes (MMT) per year) from the power sector in each state in 2014, ranked from lowest to highest.
Data from ref. 26.

Drummond’s (2010) study14, while illustrative, neglects a wide sign, indicating that these policies are associated with decreasing
range of other climate and energy policies that states have used to emissions from the electricity sector. The increase in emissions
control their GHG emissions. Furthermore, Drummond’s (2010)14 associated with the voluntary GHG registry/reporting coefficient
time series data ends in 2007 and many states have implemented may be due to selection bias, as states that are either aware that
new policies or updated old ones over the past decade. Grant et al. their emissions are increasing or are less committed to controlling
(2014)5 analysed 2010 plant-level carbon emissions data to deter- their GHG emissions may choose to participate only in the volun-
mine the effectiveness of a broader range of state climate policy tary reporting programme. The policies that significantly reduce
on carbon emissions. However, 118 climate-related policies were emissions vary from approximately 1.12 million tonnes of CO2
passed by 41 different states from 2010 through 201415. (MMTCO2) per year (MGPO) to approximately 10.3 MMTCO2 per
Prasad and Munch (2012)16 conducted the first multivariate year (AB 32). In other words, the policies associated with a signifi-
analysis of the effect of renewable energy policy on carbon emis- cant reduction in emissions reduced emissions by about 2.7–25% of
sions from the electrical power sector. Their study provides a start- average state-level annual emissions from the power sector.
ing point for discussions on policy effectiveness, but analysed only California’s cap-and-trade programme (AB 32) has the largest
data from 1997 to 2008, representing a period prior to adoption of impact of any policy tested here by an order of magnitude. These
broader policies. Furthermore, they examined only the 39 states results should be taken with caution, however. This is not only
with significant wind energy potential because these were the only because California is the only state to have implemented AB 32, but
states they expected would have the potential to lower carbon emis- five other policies (CAP, mandatory GHG registry/reporting, bind-
sions. While this assumption may have held more weight in the early ing RPS, emissions performance standards and the WCI) were imple-
2000s, solar and other renewable technologies have become increas- mented in California either during or after 2006. Furthermore, CAP
ingly cost-competitive with wind, and assessing only states with sig- and mandatory GHG registry/reporting were also authorized as part
nificant wind potential limits the generalizability of the results. of AB 32. Thus, a more suitable interpretation of this result is that the
Our study, using the most recent state-level CO2 emissions data, suite of policies that California adopted around 2006, either under
broadens state-level CO2 emissions analysis to include a wider range AB 32 or otherwise, greatly reduced that state’s emissions. A sensitiv-
of climate-related policies. We examine the effect of 17 state-level ity analysis using 2012, the year that the cap-and-trade programme
policies (8 climate and 9 energy policies) on CO2 emissions in the authorized under AB 32 was adopted, as the start year yields a nega-
electricity sector, using data from 1990 to 2014. Table 1 provides tive effect on emissions that is large but insignificant at the 0.05 level.
a description of the policies, and the number of states that have The results also provide insight into the efficacy of voluntary and
adopted them as of 201415. This study assesses policy outcomes mandatory policies. All but one (MGPO) of the mandatory policies
across all 50 states from 1990 to 2014, all years for which power- assessed are associated with a significant emissions reduction, while
sector emissions data are available. Our study seeks to answer the none of the voluntary policies is (Fig. 2). Our result indicates that vol-
following questions. First, what is the effect of state-level climate- untary programmes do not provide enough incentive for utilities or
related policies on power-sector emissions? Second, which poli- energy providers to reduce their emissions. Lyon (2007)17 also found
cies can be labelled effective climate policies? By focusing on what voluntary programmes to be ineffective. Voluntary programmes might
policies lead to a significant reduction in CO2 emissions, we hope to have beneficial spillover effects, or may be the only politically feasible
provide vital, generalizable information for policymakers to intro- strategy for some states18, but given the urgent need for substantial cuts
duce smart strategies in addressing climate change. to GHG emissions, the case for voluntary policies appears weak.
The policy associated with the largest reduction in CO2 emissions
Results and discussion that has been implemented in six states is emissions performance
Figure 2 shows the results of regressions when each individual pol- standards, reducing emissions by approximately 3.9 MMTCO2 per
icy is tested separately. Detailed regression results, including results year. The finding agrees with the study by Grant et al. (2014)5, who
for the control variables, are shown in Supplementary Appendix 1. found that emissions standards significantly decreased emissions at
With the exception of voluntary GHG registry/reporting, all the power-plant level. Yet in terms of political feasibility, emissions
coefficients of the statistically significant policies had a negative standards might not be the most viable option as policymakers look

Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange 913


© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
Articles NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE

Table 1 | Description of the 17 policies used in this study and the number of states adopted in 2014.
Description Number of states
Climate policy
Mandatory
GHG targets Goals for emission reduction levels by a certain time period 20
Mandatory GHG registry/reporting Requirements for all power plants to register and record their emissions 18
Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) First US cap-and-trade programme to reduce GHG emissions from the power 9a
sector, comprised of nine northeastern states
Emissions performance standards Performance standards designed to reduce CO2 emissions 6
California Global Warming Solutions Act (AB 32) The act requires the state to return to 1990 GHG emission levels by 2020 1
Voluntary
Climate Action Plan (CAP) Detail steps that a state plans to take to address climate change 34
Voluntary GHG registry/reporting Voluntary or market-based registries 24
Western Climate Initiative (WCI) Collaboration of states working to identify, evaluate and implement emission- 7
trading programmes
Energy policy
Mandatory
Binding renewable portfolio standards (RPS) Requires electric utilities to generate a specified amount of electricity from 31
renewable sources
Public benefit fund (PBF) Provide money for renewable energy, energy efficiency and R&D 22
Mandatory energy-efficiency targets Encourage more efficient generation, transmission, and use of electricity 25
Electric decoupling Compensates utilities for selling less electricity 16
Deregulation Consumer choice of electricity generation suppliers 14
Mandatory green power option (MGPO) Requires utilities to offer customers electricity generated from renewable 12
sources
Voluntary
Voluntary RPS Same as RPS but the adherence to RPS is not enforceable 7
Quasi-PBF Allows utilities to collect fees from customers for renewable energy or energy 5
efficiency
Voluntary energy-efficiency targets Same as mandatory energy-efficiency target, but adherence is not enforceable 9
Climate and energy policies are shown separately. Data from refs 15,25. aNew Jersey was part of RGGI when it formed in 2009 but withdrew in 2011 and has not rejoined to date.

to adopt effective policies in their states or at the national level. signing of the agreement in 2007 did not send a strong enough mar-
Substantial literature indicates that market-based mechanisms, such ket signal to see a noticeable decrease in emissions.
as a tax or cap-and-trade programme, can achieve the same result as While the WCI is a weak alliance of states, RGGI is associated
regulation at lower costs19–22. with a significant reduction in CO2 emissions. It is important to
The implementation of a CAP, the most common policy with note, however, that emissions in the states participating in RGGI
adoption by 34 states, is not associated with a significant reduction were already declining before RGGI’s implementation24. It is pos-
in emissions from the power sector. This is in line with previous sible that regulators in the Northeast and Mid-Atlantic states imple-
research testing the effect of CAP on CO2 emissions from the power mented RGGI because emissions were already declining.
sector5, and in contrast to research examining the effect of CAP on Turning to the control variables (Supplementary Appendix 1),
non-industrial emissions14. These results make sense, as CAP typi- emissions significantly increase as population increases, and the
cally cover all sectors, not just the power sector. CAP policies also price of electricity has a strong effect on emissions, with almost
do not necessarily address mitigation, and may include a focus on 700,000 MTCO2 emissions decrease for every US$0.01 kWh−1
adaptation. This might explain the statistically insignificant result, increase, holding everything else constant. To our surprise, the
as using CO2 emissions from the power sector as the dependent ratio of electricity sold across borders to total within-state genera-
variable might not capture its purpose, thus underestimating the tion (exports) is not a significant determinant of emissions. One
impact of those for which mitigation is the intent. explanation for this might be that states that are exporting electric-
The analysis indicates that WCI is not associated with a sig- ity produce more renewable electricity than importing states, or
nificant reduction in emissions in participating states. This result that importing states are demanding clean energy from exporting
can be due to a number of factors. First, the start year for this states, perhaps to meet renewable energy requirements. Good data
policy—2007—is the year in which five WCI member states signed and further studies are essential to better understand the dynamics
an agreement establishing the programme. This initial agreement, related to interstate energy flows.
however, only established an economy-wide GHG emissions target In addition to individual policies, we also tested common policy
of 15% below 2005 levels by 202023, but did not create the market- combinations. Most states have adopted more than one of the poli-
based mechanism to achieve that goal. Second, California is the cies assessed in this study, and multiple policies are often adopted
only US state within the WCI that has actually implemented a contemporaneously (Supplementary Appendix 2). Models that
market-based mechanism for achieving the reduction targets estab- include only one policy at a time may mistakenly attribute a change
lished under the WCI. For the other six states within the WCI, the in emissions to the policy included in the model, when a policy

914 Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange

© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE Articles
a

GHG targets

Mandatory GHG registry/reporting

RGGI

Emissions performance standards

AB 32

CAP

Voluntary GHG registry/reporting

WCI

–15 –10 –5 0 5
Coefficient estimate (MMTCO2 per year)

Binding RPS

PBF

Mandatory energy-efficiency
targets

Electric decoupling

Deregulation

MGPO

Voluntary RPS

Quasi-PBF

Voluntary energy-efficiency targets

–15 –10 –5 0 5
Coefficient estimate (MMTCO2 per year)

Fig. 2 | Coefficient estimate in million tonnes of CO2 emissions (MMTCO2) per year for each of the state-level policies tested individually. a,b, Effects
of state-level climate (a) and energy (b) policies on CO2 emissions with 95% confidence interval are shown separately. Filled circles are for mandatory
policies and open circles are for voluntary policies.

absent from the model could have been responsible for the change implemented after GHG targets, it is most likely that the association
in emissions. We assessed up to five-policy combinations that were we found in the individual policy model for GHG targets was due
adopted by more than ten states in 2014. In Table 2, we show the to mandatory GHG registry/reporting instead. Similarly, binding
results of the four- and five-policy combinations on CO2 emissions. RPS no longer had a significant effect on emissions when combined
The results of the two- and three-policy combinations are provided with other policies, except voluntary GHG registry/reporting. This
in Supplementary Appendices 3 and 4, respectively. aligns with the past studies5,16, which found no impact of RPS on
In agreement with the individual policy models, mandatory GHG power-sector emissions. In the four- and five-policy models, electric
registry/reporting, electric decoupling and public benefit fund (PBF) decoupling, mandatory GHG registry/reporting and PBF were still
are always associated with large, significant decreases in emissions in associated with large, significant decreases in emissions.
the two- and three-policy models. However, we also found that GHG As an additional sensitivity test, we assessed the impact of
targets (mandatory energy-efficiency targets) were not associated four- and five-policy combinations on the electricity sector’s over-
with significant emissions decreases when the model also included all CO2 emissions per megawatt hour (MWh), or emissions inten-
electric decoupling or mandatory GHG registry/reporting (electric sity (Table 3). We chose to do this because many of the policies
decoupling). As mandatory GHG registry/reporting is almost always evaluated, by either encouraging renewable energy development or

Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange 915


© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
Articles NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE

Table 2 | Effect of the combination of four or five state-level policies on power sector CO2 emissions (tonnes). Each column shows
different model results and one standard error is shown in parentheses below coefficients.
Model 1a Model 2a Model 3a Model 4a Model 5a Model 6a Model 7a

Exports −​3,468,000 −​3,416,000 −​2,991,000 −​3,932,000 −​3,938,000 −​2,486,000 −​2,338,000

(2,906,000) (2,901,000) (2,928,000) (2,909,000) (2,931,000) (2,922,000) (2,927,000)

Population 2.752*** 2.724*** 2.777*** 2.829*** 2.841*** 2.761*** 2.750***

(0.216) (0.215) (0.218) (0.217) (0.218) (0.218) (0.218)


Price −​474,100*** −​443,200*** −​487,000*** −​585,700*** −​630,500*** −​549,200*** −​594,000***
(114,700) (115,600) (114,100) (113,800) (112,500) (114,300) (112,700)
CAP 506,000 492,300 368,400 1,141,000* 1,016,000 767,400 554,500
(533,500) (519,100) (515,800) (545,700) (544,900) (540,400) (538,100)

GHG targets −​888,700 −​763,600 −​846,500 −​1,462,000* −​1,605,000**


(635,000) (632,700) (650,800) (624,300) (621,000)
Mandatory GHG registry/ −2
​ ,603,000*** −​2,629,000***
reporting (677,800) (680,100)
PBF −​148,200* −​1,556,000** −​1,528,000*
(609,300) (581,200) (617,300)
Binding RPS −​440,500 −​183,000 −​378,900 −​687,200 −​365,400 −​594,100
(539,400) (551,700) (545,900) (536,600) (568,000) (549,000)
Deregulation −​1,096,000*
(531,300)
Mandatory energy- efficiency −​978,900
targets (621,100)
R2 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99
Model 8a Model 9a Model 10a Model 11a Model 12a Model 13a Model 14a
Exports −​1,729,000 −​3,937,000 −​3,244,000 −​2,408,000 −​1,582,000 −​3,779,000 −​3,797,000
(2,935,000) (2,923,000) (2,942,000) (2,930,000) (2,933,000) (2,930,000) (2,926,000)
Population 2.855*** 2.820*** 2.897*** 2.708*** 2.815*** 2.808*** 2.831***
(0.219) (0.217) (0.219) (0.217) (0.219) (0.217) (0.217)

Price −​568,800*** −​602,700*** −​628,300*** −​596,500*** −​551,100*** −​577,800*** −​582,600***


(113,000) (112,500) (110,900) (113,400) (113,500) (114,200) (114,000)
CAP 706,400 1,056,000 941,600 385,900 589,300 −​1,156,000*
(537,300) (538,700) (534,900) (528,100) (524,500) (546,900)
GHG targets −​1,524,000* −​454,500 −​692,500
(620,900) (643,900) (652,700)
Mandatory GHG registry/ −​2,810,000*** −​2,703,000*** −​2,319,000*** −​2,587,000***
reporting (645,700) (649,600) (668,000) (678,900)

PBF −​1,532,000* −​1,396,000* −​1,751,000** −​1,329,000* −​1,468,000*


(611,000) (665,500) (612,600) (611,400) (614,000)
Binding RPS −​267,000 −​399,000 −​408,900 −​685,300 −​76,610 −​180,100 −​252,400
(570,200) (548,500) (546,900) (548,600) (583,800) (565,400) (565,600)
Deregulation −​664,700
(575,700)
Mandatory energy- efficiency −​1,728,000** −​1,508,000* −​1,872,000**
targets
(599,100) (599,800) (597,700)

R2 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99


*
P < 0.05, **P <​ 0.01, ***P <​ 0.001.

916 Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange

© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE Articles
Table 3 | Effect of the combination of four or five state-level policies on power sector CO2 emissions intensity (million tonnes/MWh).
Each column shows different model results and one standard error is shown in parentheses below coefficients.
Model 1b Model 2b Model 3b Model 4b Model 5b Model 6b Model 7b

Exports −​0.191*** −​0.188*** −​0.167*** −​0.199*** −​0.204*** −​0.190*** −​0.189***


(0.0299) (0.0298) (0.0297) (0.0297) (0.0299) (0.0297) (0.0298)
Population 2.30 ×​ 10−10 4.24 ×​ 10−10 2.44 ×​ 10−9 7.95 ×​ 10−10 8.63 ×​ 10−10 1.03 ×​ 10−10 2.00 ×​ 10−11
(2.22 ×​ 10 )−9
(2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.22 ×​ 10 )−9
(2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.22 ×​ 10−9)
Price −​0.00211 −​0.00131 −​0.00176 −​0.00155 −​0.00228* −​0.00133 −​0.00194
(0.00118) (0.00119) (0.00116) (0.00116) (0.00115) (0.00116) (0.00115)
CAP −​0.00992 −​0.00562 −​0.00565 −​0.00413 −​0.00640 −​0.00802 −​0.0107
(0.00549) (0.00534) (0.00523) (0.00556) (0.00556) (0.00550) (0.00549)
Electric decoupling 0.00318 0.00677 0.0178*
(0.00694) (0.00673) (0.00694)
GHG targets 0.00855 0.0204** 0.0164* 0.0116 −​0.00959
(0.00654) (0.00645) (0.00664) (0.00635) (0.00633)

Mandatory GHG registry/reporting −​0.0229*** −​0.0239***


(0.00691) (0.00694)
PBF −​0.0194** −​0.0174** −​0.0203**

(0.00626) (0.00593) (0.00628)


Binding RPS −​0.000800 0.00739 0.0121* 0.000778 0.00560 0.00186
(0.00555) (0.00567) (0.00554) (0.00549) (0.00578) (0.00560)

Deregulation −​0.0111*
(0.00542)
Mandatory energy-efficiency targets −​0.0387***
(0.00630)
R 2
0.96 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.96
Model 8b Model 9b Model 10b Model 11b Model 12b Model 13b Model 14b
Exports −​0.174*** −​0.199*** −​0.182*** −​0.189*** −​0.172*** −​0.202*** −​0.202***
(0.0296) (0.0299) (0.0298) (0.0298) (0.0295) (0.0298) (0.0298)
Population 1.94 ×​ 10−9 1.06 ×​ 10−9 2.65 ×​ 10−9 3.50 ×​ 10−10 2.21 ×​ 10−9 8.33 ×​ 10−10 7.40 ×​ 10−10
(2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.22 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.22 ×​ 10 ) (2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9 −9
(2.20 ×​ 10 )−9
(2.21 ×​ 10 )
−9
(2.21 ×​ 10−9)
Price −​0.00139 −​0.00110 −​0.00111 −​0.00107 −​0.000308 −​0.00165 −​0.00163
(0.00114) (0.00115) (0.00112) (0.00115) (0.00114) (0.00116) (0.00116)
CAP −​0.00820 −​0.00184 −​0.00263 −​0.00611 −​0.00307 −​0.00452
(0.00542) (0.00551) (0.00542) (0.00537) (0.00528) (0.00557)
GHG targets 0.0115 0.0176** 0.0185**
(0.00627) (0.00655) (0.00665)
Mandatory GHG registry/reporting −​0.0173** −​0.0141* −​0.0243*** −​0.0233***
(0.00660) (0.00658) (0.00680) (0.00692)
PBF −​0.0180** −​0.0166* −​0.0201** −​0.0203** −​0.0197**
(0.00625) (0.00677) (0.00617) (0.00622) (0.00626)
Binding RPS 0.0107 0.0105 0.0151** 0.00886 0.0206 0.00633 0.00662
(0.00575) (0.00561) (0.00554) (0.00558) (0.00588) (0.00575) (0.00576)
Deregulation −​0.005421
(0.005855)
Mandatory energy-efficiency targets −​0.0347*** −​0.0324*** −​0.0346***
(0.00605) (0.00608) (0.00602)
R2 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97
*
P < 0.05, **P <​ 0.01, ***P <​ 0.001.

Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange 917


© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
Articles NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE

targeting power-plant efficiency, are designed implicitly or explicitly to fixed effects, it is still possible that policymakers decided to
reduce a state’s overall emissions intensity. Furthermore, the proposed enact a policy because their state’s emissions were declining, or
federal Clean Power Plan allowed states to use intensities as their per- as a result of the declining cost of renewables. Furthermore, this
formance standards. The results suggest that mandatory GHG registry/ study includes power-sector emissions through 2014. It is imper-
reporting, PBF and mandatory energy-efficiency targets are effective at ative that studies continue to monitor policy effectiveness as new
reducing the emissions intensity but not electric decoupling. In some data become available. This is particularly important, given that
cases, electric decoupling and GHG targets were even associated with many targets within policies become increasingly stringent as
a small increase in emissions intensity. One explanation for this result time progresses.
could be that electric decoupling incentivizes utilities to sell less elec- Despite these limitations, our study provides evidence that
tricity, but not necessarily increase renewable generation. Similarly, many policy innovations implemented at the state level are suc-
states may choose to meet GHG targets by reducing energy consump- cessfully reducing carbon emissions from the power sector. This
tion, rather than increasing renewables. Mandatory GHG registry/ is a heartening finding for those states that have implemented
reporting and PBF therefore appear best for reducing both emissions these successful policies. For those that have not yet implemented
and emissions intensity effectively. We also find that the exports vari- them, this study provides guidance as to which strategies to pur-
able is significant and negative across all emissions intensity models. sue. Finally, if and when the federal government takes leadership in
This finding supports our earlier hypothesis that states exporting elec- climate mitigation efforts, it can learn from the successes of state-
tricity are producing more renewable electricity, potentially helping level actions analysed here.
importing states meet RPS requirements.

Conclusion Methods
Much of the previous research on state-level climate and energy Methods, including statements of data availability and any asso-
policy has focused either on one policy in particular, such as bind- ciated accession codes and references, are available at https://doi.
ing RPS or CAP, or has analysed policy effectiveness on the basis org/10.1038/s41558-017-0001-0.
of a measure other than its ability to reduce carbon emissions. Our
study provides a thorough analysis of some of the most prominent Received: 23 April 2017; Accepted: 21 September 2017;
climate and energy policies used by states and their ability to reduce Published online: 6 November 2017
emissions from the power sector. The results of this study indicate
that many of these policies are effective. All of the effective policies
are mandatory or have binding targets, while none of the voluntary References
1. Friedrich, J. and T. Damassa. The History of Carbon Dioxide Emissions
policies is associated with emissions reduction. In particular, electric (World Resources Institute, last modified 21 May 2014, accessed
decoupling and mandatory GHG registry/reporting are associated 5 April 2017); http://www.wri.org/blog/2014/05/history-carbon-
with the largest reduction in emissions. Furthermore, our results dioxide-emissions
indicate that mandatory GHG registry/reporting and PBF are effec- 2. Sources of Greenhouse Gas Emissions (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
tive in reducing both emissions and emissions intensity from the 2015, accessed 8 September 2017); https://www.epa.gov/ghgemissions/
sources-greenhouse-gas-emissions
power sector. 3. Rabe, B. G. Statehouse and Greenhouse: The Emerging Politics of
There are several limitations to this study. One major limita- American Climate Change Policy (Brookings Institution Press, Washington,
tion is that it does not assess the differences within policies. For DC, 2004).
instance, there are many different forms of RPS, with varying 4. Goulder, L. & Stavins, R. Challenges from state-federal interactions in US
degrees of stringency, enforcement mechanisms or compliance climate change policy. Am. Econ. Rev. 101, 253–257 (2011); http://www.jstor.
org/stable/29783749 retrieved from.
periods. While we capture voluntary versus mandatory, we do not 5. Grant, D., Bergstrand, K. & Running, K. Effectiveness of US state policies
capture other differences that might matter in terms of their effect in reducing CO2 emissions from power plants. Nat. Clim. Change 4,
on emissions. 977–982 (2014).
Another limitation to this analysis is the chosen start year for 6. Climate Change 101: State Action. Climate Change101: Understanding and
Responding to Global Climate Change (Center for Climate and Energy
the policy variables. We have chosen the year that the policy was
Solutions, 2011).
signed into law, which may or may not be the same as the start 7. Wheeler, S. State and municipal climate action plans: The first generation.
of the compliance period. We used this start year because it can J. Am. Plann. Assoc. 74, 481–496 (2008).
be tracked clearly and consistently across all policies and because 8. Yin, H. & Powers, N. Do state renewable portfolio standards promote in-state
the law arguably sends a signal to the market and other actors to renewable generation? Energy Policy 38, 1140–1149 (2010).
9. Carley, S. State renewable energy electricity policies: An empirical evaluation
begin to take the steps necessary to comply. It is possible, however, of effectiveness. Energy Policy 37, 3071–3081 (2009).
that a policy’s effect on emissions is not recognized until years after 10. Michaels, R. J. National renewable portfolio standard: Smart policy or
it becomes law. It is likely, therefore, that the policy variables are misguided gesture? Energy Law J. 29, 79–119 (2008).
underestimated by the models, and future studies might assess 11. Delmas, M. A. & Montes-Sancho, M. J. U.S. state policies for
policies on the basis of the start of compliance periods or after a renewable energy: context and effectiveness. Energy Policy 39,
2273–2288 (2011).
specified lag period. 12. Menz, F. C. & Vachon, S. The effectiveness of different policy regimes for
Furthermore, our models might underestimate the effect of poli- promoting wind power: experiences from the states. Energy Policy 34,
cies because of the inclusion of the electricity price variable. Aside 1786–1796 (2006).
from the direct effect that policies have on emissions, they may also 13. Shrimali, G. & Kniefel, J. Are government policies effective in
indirectly affect emissions by increasing the price of electricity. For promoting deployment of renewable electricity resources? Energy Policy 39,
4726–4741 (2011).
example, if GHG emissions standards force utilities to employ more 14. Drummond, W. J. Statehouse versus greenhouse. J. Am. Plann. Assoc. 76,
expensive technologies, this would drive up the price of electricity, 413–433 (2010).
indirectly incentivizing consumers to conserve electricity and thus 15. Climate Policy Maps (C2ES, 2016, last modified September 2016; accessed
further reducing emissions. A portion of this indirect effect would 5 April 2017; https://www.c2es.org/us-states-regions/policy-maps/
be absorbed by the electricity price variable rather than being attrib- emissions-targets
16. Prasad, M. & Munch, S. State-level renewable electricity policies and
uted to the policy. reductions in carbon emissions. Energy Policy 45, 237–242 (2012).
The effects of policies may be overestimated due to the pos- 17. Lyon, J. W. M. Environmental public voluntary programs reconsidered.
sibility of reverse causation. While we control for state and year Policy Stud. J. 35, 723–750 (2007).

918 Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange

© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE Articles
18. Matisoff, D. Sources of specification errors in the assessment of voluntary 25. Morey, M. J. & Kirsch, L. D. Retail Choice in Electricity: What have we Learned
environmental programs: understanding program impacts. Policy Sci. 48, in 20 Years? (EMRF, 2016); https://sites.hks.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/2016/
109–126 (2014). Retail%20Choice%20in%20Electricity%20for%20EMRF%20Final.pdf
19. Pigou, A. C. The Economics of Welfare. (Macmillan and Co., London, 1920). 26. State Carbon Dioxide Emissions (U.S. Energy Information Administration,
20. Montgomery, W. D. Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control 2016, accessed 5 April 2017; https://www.eia.gov/environment/
programs. J. Econ. Theory 5, 395–418 (1972). emissions/state/
21. Stavins, R. N. What can we learn from the grand policy experiment? Lessons
from SO2 allowance trading. J. Econ. Perspect. 12, 69–88 (1998). Additional information
22. Goulder, L. H. & Parry, I. W. H. Instrument choice in environmental policy. Supplementary information is available for this paper at https://doi.org/10.1038/
Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2, 152–174 (2008). s41558-017-0001-0.
23. Multi-State Climate Initiatives (C2ES, 2017, accessed 5 April 2017; Reprints and permissions information is available at www.nature.com/reprints.
https://www.c2es.org/us-states-regions/regional-climate-initiatives
24. State CO2 Emissions from Fossil Fuel Combustion, 1990-2014 (U.S. EPA, 2016, Correspondence and requests for materials should be addressed to E.S.
accessed 5 April 2017; https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2017-07/ Publisher’s note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in
documents/co2ffc_2014.pdf published maps and institutional affiliations.

Nature Climate Change | VOL 7 | DECEMBER 2017 | 912–919 | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange 919


© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
Articles NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE
not a replicated policy intervention, the results from the AB 32 model
Methods run cannot be interpreted with authority. Finally, while Kim et al (2016)30
In this study, we examine the effect of 17 state-level climate and energy policies show that deregulation leads to higher levels of renewable energy policy, it
on CO2 emissions in the electricity sector using data from 1990 to 2014. The is unclear whether this leads to lower carbon emissions. It is also possible
independent policy dummy variables are set to 0 before adoption and 1 after that deregulation, by opening generation up to market competition from
adoption. The adoption year is defined as the year that the specific policy was competitors potentially looking to use cheap fossil fuels, is correlated with
signed into law. This may not correlate exactly with the year in which the policy higher emissions.
took effect for all policies, but it is a standard that can be easily determined, and The dependent variable is CO2 emissions (tons of CO2 per year) from the
the signing of a policy into law sends a signal to firms and sets expectations for electric power sector within a state. The data were derived from the EPA’s
their future requirements. There is also variance among policies of the same ‘State CO2 Emissions from Fossil Fuel Combustion, 1990–2014’ report, using
name—we did not code on the basis of the stringency of requirements or dates for data collected by the EPA and the US Energy Information Administration24.
compliance. We did, however, separate policies on the basis of whether or not they The emissions data cover all 50 states for each year between 1990 and 2014.
had mandatory or voluntary requirements. Thus, our unit of analysis is the state-year, and we have 1,250 state-years. In
CO2 emissions at state, national or international scales are the result of a sensitivity test, we also create a model with a dependent variable of CO2
many complex factors and mechanisms. Kaya (1990)27 proposed a framework emissions intensity (tons of CO2 MWh−1). We derived the state-level emissions
(Supplementary Appendix 5) that allows for decomposing the complexity intensity from the EIA’s ‘Net Generation by State by Type of Producer by Energy
into four key variables that drive carbon emissions. The interaction of human Source’31 and the EPA’s ‘State CO2 Emissions from Fossil Fuel Combustion,
population, gross domestic product (GDP) per capita, energy intensity and 1990–2014’ reports24. To determine a state’s emissions intensity, we divided
carbon intensity has been used by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate state-level electric-power-sector CO2 emissions (in million metric tons, MMT)
Change to develop future emissions scenarios28. The price of electricity by state-level electric power industry generation (MWh) for each year from
influences the energy production/GDP and CO2 emissions per unit of energy 1990 to 2014.
produced. Polices that attempt to control emissions can be grouped into Supplementary Appendix 6 defines the control variables and provides
categories that focus on controlling emissions (climate policies), and those that their sources. Descriptive statistics of all variables employed in this study
indirectly affect emissions by focusing on energy efficiency and non-fossil fuel are shown in Supplementary Appendix 7. We conducted variance inflation
modes of production (energy policies). factor analysis (Supplementary Appendix 8) for all individual models, and
This simplified framework illustrates not only what factors influence did not find evidence of multicollinearity. We also control for state and year
carbon emissions, and are therefore important to consider in developing fixed effects. State fixed effects account for the wide variation among state’s
explanatory models, but also the levers that policymakers can utilize power-sector emissions (Fig. 1) by subtracting the state CO2 emissions means,
to reduce carbon emissions. Energy intensity and carbon intensity so that the models can compare changes in emissions within states, rather
(Supplementary Appendix 5) are what policymakers try to affect when than comparing changes in emissions among states. The state fixed effects
designing climate and energy policies. Many policies are of a command-and- variable will capture unobserved heterogeneity among states, including the
control style, in that they proscribe certain mechanisms for achieving their renewable energy potential of states or infrastructural investments or other
aims. For example, renewable portfolio standards (RPS) require utilities to historical legacies that may be associated with a reliance on fossil fuels
increase electric production using non-fossil fuel energy sources. Others for power generation. Year fixed effects control for year-to-year national
are more flexible in their approach, or even employ market mechanisms, emissions trends that might be associated with factors such as technological
such as the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) and California’s improvements that have driven declines in the cost of renewables and natural
cap-and-trade programme authorized under the California Global Warming gas, or changing economic conditions. The models explain the variation
Solutions Act (AB 32). These types of policy set certain targets, but then allow in emissions from year to year almost perfectly. While state fixed effects
utilities to determine the best path to compliance. Regardless of the lever play a large role in these high R2 values, removing state fixed effects from
that a climate or energy policy targets in its design, policies must overcome the models still yields R2 values between 0.44 and 0.50, explaining much of
opposing forces, such as population or economic growth, in order to have an the variation. State-level policies that significantly reduce emissions must
effect on emissions levels. Alternatively, policies implemented in the context decrease emissions beyond expected emissions levels, given national trends.
of changing conditions that might independently reduce electricity emissions,
such as technological improvements, might erroneously appear effective.
Controlling for these independent factors can help reduce the chance of Population. The Kaya identity, discussed above, states that there is a direct
inaccurately attributing changes in emission levels to the implementation of association between population and CO2 emissions27,32,33. While there has been
policies. much debate about the impact of a growing population on the environment in
We employ the following fixed-effects regression model for each policy to general, there is less debate about the impact of population size on CO2 emissions.
control for unobserved state and year heterogeneity, as well as certain state-specific Larger populations typically generate higher emissions.
characteristics that may have an independent effect on annual power-sector
carbon emissions: Exports. Electricity markets are not bound by state borders; indeed, some states
are net importers of electricity while others are net exporters. A state that exports
CO2 = αi + γt + β1policyit + β2exportsit + β4populationit + β5priceit + ε electricity might have higher emissions simply because the state is generating for
consumers beyond its borders, and not because of the ineffectiveness of its climate-
where αi represents state fixed effects, γt represents year fixed effects, ‘policy’ related policies. For example, if a state increases its renewable energy generation in
is a dummy variable for the presence or absence of a specific climate or energy order to comply with its RPS, but sells the electricity across state lines, the effect on
policy for a given state-year, ‘exports’ is the percentage of a state’s total electricity emissions may be seen only in the importing state. Alternatively, a state could reduce
production that is exported to other states, ‘population’ represents the state’s its emissions by importing electricity (effectively ‘exporting’ emissions), regardless
population, ‘price’ is the price of electricity within a state and ε represents the of the effectiveness of the state’s climate policies. As Prasad and Munch (2012)16
error term. Our model illuminates changes in emissions trends as a result of policy note, however, with existing data it is impossible to know the exact fuel source of
between states that implement a policy and those that do not, as well as the trend all imports and exports of electricity. Therefore, the interpretation of controlling
within a state before and after policy implementation. We run separate models for for electricity imports would be impossible. Instead, we use the ratio of electricity
each of the 17 policies assessed. As a sensitivity test, we run models with up to five exported to the total in-state electricity production (setting this variable to 0 for
policies, the combinations of which, with results, are shown in Tables 2 and 3, and importing states) to control for the potential impact electricity exports might have
Supplementary Appendices 3 and 4. on emissions.
A few policies deserve further explanation. Quasi-PBFs, as defined by
C2ES (2014)29, allow utilities to add charges to customers’ utility bills to
fund renewable energy or develop energy-efficiency programmes. They are Electricity price. Lyon and Yin (2010)34 note the importance of controlling for
quasi-PBFs because the state does not formally maintain a PBF. The Western the average in-state electricity price. A higher electricity price may be correlated
Climate Initiative (WCI) started in 2007 as an agreement between five western with decreased emissions, as it might encourage end users such as households
states to develop a regional target for curbing GHG emissions and design and and businesses to either conserve electricity or to invest in more efficient
implement a market-based mechanism for doing so. We use 2007 as the start technologies. Alternatively, higher electricity prices could put pressure on
date for the WCI, but the programme has undergone significant changes since policymakers to rely on more generation from fossil fuels, having a positive effect
then. To date, only California has implemented a cap-and-trade system and on emissions.
is working with Canadian provinces to harmonize their emissions-trading
programmes under the direction of the non-profit corporation WCI, Inc. We Data availability. The data sets generated and analysed during the current study
thus test California’s cap-and-trade programme, mandated under AB 32, are available in the Pangea repository. Effectiveness of State Climate and Energy
separately to determine whether California’s programme is successful Policies in Reducing Power Sector CO2 Emissions Dataset (PANGAEA, 2017);
outside of the WCI. It is important to stress that because AB 32 is clearly https://doi.pangaea.de/10.1594/PANGAEA.880333.

Nature Climate Change | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange

© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.
NaTUrE CliMaTE CHanGE Articles
References 31 Net Generation by State by Type of Energy Producer by Energy Source.
27. Kaya, Y. Impact of Carbon Dioxide Emission Control on GNP Growth: (U.S. EIA, 2016, accessed 8 August 2017; https://www.eia.gov/electricity/
Interpretation of Proposed Scenarios (IPCC, 1990). data/state/
28. Nakicenovic, N. & Swart, R. (eds.) in Special Report on Emissions Scenarios 32 Kaya, K. Y. Environment, Energy, and Economy: Strategies for Sustainability
Ch. 3 (IPCC, 2000). (United Nations University Press, New York, 1997).
29. Public Benefit Funds (C2ES, 2014, last modified 2014, accessed 5 April 2017; 33 Rosa, E. A. & Dietz, T. Human drivers of national greenhouse-gas emissions.
https://www.c2es.org/us-states-regions/policy-maps/public-benefit-funds Nat. Clim. Change 2, 581–586 (2012).
30 Kim, S. E., Yang, J. & Urpelainen, J. Does power sector deregulation promote 34 Lyon, T. P. & Yin, H. Why do states adopt renewable portfolio
or discourage renewable energy policy? Evidence from the states, 1991–2012. standards? An empirical investigation. Energy J. 3,
Rev. Policy Res. 33, 22–50 (2016). 133–157 (2010).

Nature Climate Change | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange

© 2017 Macmillan Publishers Limited, part of Springer Nature. All rights reserved.

You might also like