You are on page 1of 67

The Japanese Economy 4th Edition

David Flath
Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://ebookmass.com/product/the-japanese-economy-4th-edition-david-flath/
The Japanese Economy
THE
JAPANESE
ECONOMY
FOURTH EDITION

David Flath
Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP,
United Kingdom
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.
It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of
Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries
© David Flath 2022
The moral rights of the author have been asserted
Impression: 1
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in
a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, without the
prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted
by law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics
rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of the
above should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the
address above
You must not circulate this work in any other form
and you must impose this same condition on any acquirer
Published in the United States of America by Oxford University Press
198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016, United States of America
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Control Number: 2021950958
ISBN 978–0–19–286534–2
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780192865342.001.0001
Printed and bound by
CPI Group (UK) Ltd, Croydon, CR0 4YY
Links to third party websites are provided by Oxford in good faith and
for information only. Oxford disclaims any responsibility for the materials
contained in any third party website referenced in this work.
This book is dedicated to curious and inquisitive free thinkers
everywhere.
Preface to the Fourth Edition

This edition updates and expands much of the content of the previous edition.
In 2000, when the first edition of this book was published, readers may have
been seeking an explanation for Japan’s prosperity, an informed analysis of its
trade friction with the US and Europe, or an appraisal of its unique business
practices and institutions. These topics are all still addressed in these pages; my
own curiosity about such things is what first motivated me to write the book.
But in the last few years, much has transpired that a book on Japan’s econ-
omy should also aim to explain—negative interest rates, Japan’s ballooning
government debt, commercial banks’ persistent dominance of Japanese finan-
cial intermediation, the ongoing attempts to include women more fully in
the Japanese system of educating, training, and hiring employees, and much
more. Much of the new content of this edition is devoted to these topics.
I first began contemplating Japan in 1980 when as a young academic in
Raleigh, North Carolina I was presented with an opportunity to study the
Japanese language, visit Japan, and develop a course on the Japanese economy.
Thus, began an eventful journey in which I have learned from many, taught
others, and enjoyed the many pleasures of exploring a wider world. I invite
all readers of this book to join me.
Kyoto, March 2021
Preface to the Third Edition

The Japanese economy continues to fascinate and reward those who consider
it from the perspective of the principles of economics. I invite all who open
these pages to join me in this. This edition includes a new chapter on the
tax system of Japan. I have also updated many of the tables and figures and
revised many of the other chapters to reflect new learning, current events,
and the latest data. Finally, let me acknowledge the splendid hospitality of my
colleagues at the Osaka University, Institute of Social and Economic Research,
where I completed this work while employed as an adjunct professor.
Kyoto, March 2013
Preface to the Second Edition

It has been gratifying to learn of the many successful courses based on the first
edition of The Japanese Economy. And I hope that with this revision of the book,
it will continue to serve as a useful text and reference for students, scholars,
journalists, and the intellectually curious. In the five years since publication
of the first edition, much has transpired. Japan has emerged from a prolonged
recession and a banking crisis, both of which receive a more extended treat-
ment in this edition. I have also updated many tables and figures to bring the
data closer to the present. The basic format and most of the content remains
intact.
Raleigh, November 2004
Preface to the First Edition

Very few universities outside of Japan offer courses on the Japanese economy;
I wrote this book out of the conviction that many more of them would offer
such courses, if only a suitable text were available. If courses on Japan are
to become a regular part of the economics curriculum in English-speaking
colleges and universities, as I believe they should, then the subject has to be
made accessible to students and faculty who presently have little familiarity
with Japanese history or institutions.
This is less of a leap to make than one might suppose. Anyone who un-
derstands the principles of economics already knows a lot about the Japanese
economy without necessarily even realizing it. Many specific topics on the
Japanese economy invite uncomplicated explanations based on standard bits
of economic logic, such as the axiom of revealed preference, the Ricardian the-
ory of comparative advantage, the Solow growth model, the life-cycle model
of saving, the quantity theory of money, the purchasing power parity theory
of exchange rates, public goods, Coase’s law, the welfare losses resulting from
monopoly, analysis of company specific skills, the Modigliani–Miller theorem,
and so on. Anyone now teaching economics courses at university level should
find enough in this book that is familiar, along with guideposts toward the un-
familiar, to teach a solid course based on the book. The book itself supplies the
relevant facts about Japan that economic arguments can illuminate, and also
explains the logic of the arguments.
For those not already versed in economics, this book will afford a broad
and, I hope, enticing introduction to the economic way of reasoning. This is
a book not only for specialists in economics, but also for political scientists,
historians, and others interested in Japan. For undergraduate students taking
a course based on this book, a prior course on the principles of economics may
be helpful, but is possibly not essential.
There may be more here than one should attempt to include in a one-
semester course. The chapters proceed from macroeconomic topics toward
microeconomic ones, but this is somewhat arbitrary and the chapters can be
taken in just about any order, and any of them can be skipped without ren-
dering the remaining chapters incomprehensible. The first chapter assesses
Preface
Japan’s current status as a developed nation with a high standard of living,
and the next three chapters describe the sequence of events that produced this
result. The remaining chapters are divided by subject area rather than chrono-
logically, Many of these “subject area” chapters refer to historical events,
but their main focus is on contemporary topics. A course emphasizing eco-
nomic history and development should include the first four chapters and the
chapter on industrial policy. A course emphasizing Japanese business should
include the last five chapters. A course emphasizing government policy should
include Chapters 8–13 and 16. A course emphasizing macroeconomics should
include the first chapter and Chapter 3–7.
People have helped me very much in this project in myriad ways, with com-
ments on earlier drafts, copies of their own articles, conversations, mentoring,
editing, and other forms of support. I am grateful to all of them and especially
the following. Colleagues at NCSU: Steve Allen, Bob Clark, Lee Craig, Bob Fearn,
Douglas Fisher, Tom Grennes, Tony Moyer, Doug Pearce, John Seater, Walt
Wessels. Colleagues at Osaka University: Hayashi Toshio, Charles Yuji Horioka,
Colin McKenzie, Royama Shoichi, Takagi Shinji. Friends and colleagues at other
universities: Jeff Bernstein, Hanai Satoshi, Hayashi Fumio, Iida Takao, James
Nakamura, Nakata Yoshihiro, Nariu Tatsuhiko, Hugh Patrick, Tish Robin-
son, Gary Saxonhouse, Paul Sheard, Richard Sylla, Takeuchi Nobuhito, Yishai
Yafeh, Yumoto Yuji, and David Weinstein.
I would also like to thank John Sylvester (former director of the NC Japan
Center), A. Scott Voorhees (of US EPA), Fujiwara Masahiko (of MITI), and my
editor at Oxford, Andrew Schuller, who faithfully conveyed the comments
of anonymous reviewers. I would like to acknowledge my mentors at UCLA,
Harold Demsetz and Armen Alchain—whatever economics I know I learned
from them. Thanks also to my first Japanese teacher, Kataoka Hiroko, who
introduced me to Japan. I also acknowledge the contributions of the many
students in the classes in which I tested the materials that became this book:
students at North Carolina State University, Osaka University, Sapporo Uni-
versity, and those from all over the world who took my classes at the Harvard
Summer School.
Many institutions have assisted me while writing the book and I thank them
also: North Carolina Japan Center, North Carolina State University, Osaka
University and Osaka Gas Company, and Nanzan University.
D.F.
Raleigh, April 1999

xiv
Contents

List of Figures xvi


List of Tables xix

Introduction 1
1 Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today 11
2 Economic History, Part 1: The Tokugawa Period (1603–1868)
and the Meiji Era (1868–1912) 28
3 Economic History, Part 2: The Twentieth Century
(1912–1945) 61
4 Economic History, Part 3: Postwar Recovery (1945–1964) 93
5 Saving 119
6 Macroeconomy 133
7 International Finance 187
8 International Trade 209
9 Industrial Policy 251
10 Public Economy, Part 1: Government Spending 282
11 Public Economy, Part 2: Taxes 298
12 Environmental Policy 321
13 Industrial Organization 331
14 Finance 356
15 Marketing 398
16 Labor 423
17 Technology 454

Glossary 466
Index 484
List of Figures

1.1. Gross domestic product (GDP) and gross national product


(GNP = GNI), Japan, 1994–2018 13
2.1. Japan population (total and urban), and per-capita real GDP,
730 CE to 1874 37
2.2. Increasing population with no change in income per person in
the first part of the Tokugawa period, 1600–1721 42
2.3. Rising per-capita income with unchanging population in the
latter part of the Tokugawa period, 1721–1868 43
2.4. Effects of the Meiji land tax reform 47
2.5. Price of silver in terms of Japanese currency and in terms of gold
on the London exchange, 1868–1897 50
2.6. Net value added in manufacturing and mining versus that
in agriculture, forestry, and fisheries, all in 1934–6 prices,
1885–1940 52
3.1. Japanese terms of trade, 1885–1940 (1934–6 = 100) 64
3.2. Real and nominal GNP, 1910–1940 76
3.3. Annual rates of growth in high-powered money (HPM) and real
GNP, 1910–1940 79
3.4. Changes in real government spending as a percentage of
previous year’s real GNP, 1910–1940 80
3.5. Movements along the boundary of Japan’s production
possibilities, 1885–1942 84
4.1. Real gross national product of Japan, 1885–2000 94
4.2. Annual percentage increases in money stock (M2), prices (GNP
deflator), and real GNP, fiscal years 1947–1955 108
4.3. Japanese government subsidies, US aid, and US procurement
spending in Japan, 1946–1955 109
4.4. The aggregate production function under constant returns to
scale 111
4.5. GNP per unit of labor, NNP per unit of labor, and annual net
investment per unit of labor at each alternative capital-to-labor
ratio, under constant returns to scale, constant saving rate s,
balanced trade, and constant rate of depreciation δ 111
4.6. The steady state 113
List of Figures
4.7. Labor’s share in Japan, 1906–1940 and 1955–1998 115
4.8. Growth path of Japan’s real GNP, 1935–1995 117
4.9. Imputed growth path of Japan’s capital stock, 1935–1995
(1940 = 1) 117
5.1. Net national saving relative to net national income at market
prices; Japan, 1885–2018 122
5.2. Net national saving and net government saving relative to net
national income at market prices, Japan, 1955–2018 124
6.1. Real GDP potential growth rate and shortfall, 1956–2020 140
6.2. An aggregate demand curve 141
6.3. Money stock, nominal GNP, and real GNP, 1900–2018 142
6.4. A contraction of the money supply or expansion of money
demand 143
6.5. Bank of Japan loans and discounts (discount window lending)
and increase in base, 1956–2011 146
6.6. Supply and demand for excess reserves 150
6.7. Call rate and long-term prime lending rate, 1980–2020 152
6.8. Monetary base and money stock, 1980–2020 155
6.9. An aggregate supply curve 159
6.10. Flows into and out of the pool of unemployed workers 160
6.11. Unemployment rate during recessions, Japan, 1956–2020 166
6.12. Annual rates of change in employment and hours during
recessions, Japan, 1956–2020 166
6.13. Annual growth in real wage rate and in real GDP, Japan,
1956–2020 167
6.14. Growth rates in money, real GDP, and nominal GDP, 1956–2020 171
6.15. Fiscal policy in Japan, 1980–2019 175
6.16. CPI, all items less fresh food, y/y % change each month
(adjusted to remove effects of consumption tax increases),
January 2005–March 2020 179
6.17. Bank of Japan policies to expand the monetary base, 1990–2020 180
6.18. Bank of Japan purchases of commercial paper, corporate bonds,
ETFs and J-REITs, 2008–2020 181
6.19. Japanese government bond yields, 2005–2020 182
7.1. Japan’s current account as a percentage of GNP, 1885–2018 193
7.2. Japanese terms of trade and real exchange rates, 1980–2018 196
7.3. Deviations of the Japan–US forward exchange rate from covered
interest parity, 1972–1984 197
7.4. Nominal and real yen-per-dollar exchange rates, and reciprocal
of Japan’s terms of trade, 1950–2018 202
7.5. Movements in the Producer Price Index (PPI) and Consumer
Price Index (CPI), Japan and the USA, 1955–2019 203
7.6. The J-curve 206
8.1. Equilibrium under autarky 211
8.2. Equilibrium under free trade 212
8.3. International trade in relation to GNP, Japan, 1885–2018 213
8.4. Foreign direct investment (FDI) stocks, Japan, USA, and Europe,
2018 (US $Bn) 222

xvii
List of Figures
8.5a. Annual average tariff rates (customs duties divided by dutiable
imports) of Japan and the USA, 1868–2018 230
8.5b. Annual average tariff rates (customs duties divided by c.i.f.
imports) of Japan and the USA, 1868–2018 230
8.6. Effects of tariff or import quota and output-based producer
subsidy 247
9.1. Directing resources toward an industry with high value-added
per worker 253
9.2. The Fiscal Investment and Loan Program 267
10.1. Marginal valuations of defense by allies “Big” and “Little,” and
implied reaction curves of each in choosing its contribution to
the common defense 292
11.1. Tax wedge 304
11.2. Excess burden 308
11.3. General government debt of Japan, percent GDP, 1980–2017 312
11.4. Average interest rate on outstanding Japanese government
bonds and annual growth rate of nominal GDP, fy 1976–2018 316
11A.1. A tax fully shifted onto labor 319
11A.2. Output response to a tax fully shifted onto labor, showing
excess burden Bj 319
13.1. Herfindahl indices (summations of squared shares of industry
sales) of matched industries in Japan and the USA, 2010–2012 343
13.2. Welfare losses resulting from oligopoly 347
14.1. Financial intermediation in Japan 357
14.2. Financial surplus or deficit of each sector, Japan, 1980–2020 358
14.3. Implementation of the Interest Control Law of 1948 376
14.4. External fund-raising by private nonfinancial corporations in
Japan, 1980–2020 388
15.1. Retail and wholesale employment as a percent of the labor
force, Japan, 1952–2016 399
15.2. Retail stores per thousand persons, Japan and the US,
1952–2017 401
15.3. Number of retail stores in Japan, incorporated and
unincorporated, 1952–2016 402
15.4. Employees per retail store in Japan, incorporated and
unincorporated, 1952–2016 402
15.5a. Economic order quantity model 407
15.5b. Economic order quantity model, continued 407
15.6. Successive monopolies 413
16.1. Wages over workers’ careers 430
16.2. A wage scheme that deters shirking 432
16.3. Japanese women’s labor force participation rates at selected
ages, 1920–2019 448
16.4. Japanese women’s labor force participation over the life cycles
of selected birth cohorts 448
16.5. Japanese women’s share in managerial positions by the job
title (companies with 100 employees or more), 1985–2019 452

xviii
List of Tables

1.1. GDP per capita and its composition; Japan and selected other
nations, 2018 16
1.2. Revealed preferences, 2005 17
1.3. Estimated value of nonmarket goods as a percentage of GNP,
Japan and the USA 21
1.4. Hours per week devoted to various activities by men and women
in Japan and other countries, 1999–2006 22
1.5. International comparisons of income distribution, after taxes,
2013 24
2.1. Japan population (total and urban), and per-capita real GDP, 730
CE to 1874 37
2.2. Conditions at the start of modern economic growth, Japan and
selected other nations 56
2A.1. Periods of Japanese history 58
3.1. Japan’s international debt and investment position, end-1913
and end-1919 62
3.2. Scale of the major zaibatsu, 1928 67
3.3. Employment in Japan, by sector 69
3A.1. Formation of the four major zaibatsu: principal affiliated
enterprises and their dates of entry into the zaibatsu orbits 86
3A.2. Japanese prime ministers 90
4.1. Average annual growth rates in real GNP and population, Japan
1885–2005 114
5.1. Net national saving rates of Japan and selected other nations,
1970–2018 125
6.1. Business cycle turning points in Japan, 1888–2020 136
6.2. Components of the Cabinet office diffusion index used for dating
turning points of the business cycle 137
6.3. Real GDP during Japan’s recent recessions 139
6.4. Real and nominal variables during Japan’s recent recessions 158
6.5. Unemployment rates (percentages of labor forces), selected
countries, 1965–2019 159
List of Tables
6.6. Monthly flows into and out of the unemployment pool and
natural rates of unemployment, selected countries and years 161
6.7. Gross flows into and out of the unemployment pool of Japan,
1985–2000 161
6.8. Unemployment insurance in Japan and selected other countries,
1985, 2004, and 2014 163
6.9. Output, employment, and unemployment during Japan’s recent
recessions 164
7.1. Double-entry accounting 188
7.2. Accounts of the balance of payments of Japan, 2019 191
7.3. Libor-based yen-dollar covered interest parity deviations 198
7.4. International variation in retail prices, July 2020 200
7.5. Estimates of the short-run and long-run price elasticities of
demand for Japanese imports and exports 206
8.1. Exports and imports of Japan in the early Meiji era (1870s) 217
8.2. Intra-industry manufacturing trade indices, Japan and selected
other countries, 1980 to 2008 219
8.3. Inward and outward stocks of foreign direct investment, Japan
and selected other countries, 2019 221
8.4. Japanese companies among the world’s 100 largest multinational
enterprises ranked by estimated dollar value of foreign assets,
1999 and 2011 223
8.5. Voluntary export restraints of Japan 235
8.6. Japan Economic Partnership Agreements and Free-Trade
Agreements, as of September 2020 242
8.7. Protection of agricultural commodities in Japan, 2018 246
9.1. Domestic price subsidies (“price”) and Reconstruction Finance
Bank loans (“RFB”), 1946–1950 (1934–6¥mn) 262
9.2. Sources of industrial funds, 1946–1975 (% of external funds) 268
9.3a. Composition of JDB loans, 1951–1974 (¥bn and %) 270
9.3b. Equipment purchases of private firms financed by government
intermediaries and by the Japan Development Bank, 1954–1967 270
9.4. Composition of ExIm Bank loans, 1950–1975 (¥bn and %) 271
9.5. Rationalization plans and related measures, 1951–1974 273
9.6. Reductions in interest burden arising from public loans and
reductions in taxes resulting from special depreciation allowances,
by industry, 1961–1980 275
10.1. Government employees as a percentage of all employment, Japan
and selected other nations, 1988–2017 283
10.2. Government expenditures, by purpose, percent GDP, Japan and
selected other nations, 2000–2018 286
10.3. Government-provided local public goods, Japan, USA, France,
and the UK, 1980s and 2010s 290
11.1. Taxes in Japan, 1886–1945 299
11.2. Taxes in Japan, 1950–2015 301
11.3. Taxes in Japan and selected other countries, fy 2017 302
11.4. Debt-related financial assets and liabilities of the general
government of Japan, end of March 2019 313

xx
List of Tables
13.1. Descendants of the Presidents’ club members of the six financial
keiretsu 333
13.2. Scale of keiretsu Presidents’ club companies, excluding banks and
insurance companies, in relation to the Japanese economy, 1994 337
13.3. Companies that head the 40 most significant enterprise groups
(Presidents’ club memberships are stated in parentheses) 338
13.4. Market shares of leading Japanese companies, 2018 342
14.1. Reorganization of major Japanese banks, 1990–2005 361
14.2. Financial Intermediaries of Japan, end-March 2019 367
14.3. Private nonfinancial corporations of Japan, annual financial
transactions, 1980–2019 387
15.1. Stores per thousand persons, selected countries, 1980s, 1990s,
and 2017 400
15.2. Store formats recognized by the Census of Commerce of Japan in
1997 and backdated to 1991 403
15.3. Employees per store, by format, 1991–2014 403
15.4. Floorspace per store in m2 , by format, 1991–2014 403
15.5. Numbers of stores, by format, 1991–2014 404
15.6. Composition of sales across store formats, 1991–2014 404
16.1. Average ultimate expected tenure of employment in selected
countries, 1979–2017 425
16.2. Job switching in Japan and the USA 427
16.3. Expected ultimate tenure of employment of employees of
different sized firms, Japan and the USA, 1979 428
16.4. Composition of union membership in Japan by type of union,
1930–2017 439
16.5. Union membership in Japan and other nations, 1970–2018 439
16.6. Unionization in Japan by firm size and industry, 2009 and 2018 440
16.7. Strikes in Japan and selected other nations, 1990 and 2018 444
16.8. Labor force participation rates of persons aged 15–64, Japan and
selected other countries, 1956–2016 445
16.9. Composition of Japan’s labor force aged 15 and over, by type of
employment and by sex, 1920–2019 446
16.10. Women’s share of managerial employment in selected countries,
2010 and 2018 451
17.1. Research and development spending in Japan, 2017 455
17.2. Research and development spending, sources of funds in Japan,
fiscal year 2017 457
17.3. International comparison of R&D spending, 1985, 1995, 2008,
and 2017 458
17.4. Estimates of the rate of return from R&D spending in Japan and
the USA 460

xxi
Introduction

Why study the Japanese economy? Well, the best wholesale and retail distributors of their products,
reason is the joy and satisfaction that accompanies and much else. The Japanese economy is a kind of
a deeper understanding of the world and our place test case that validates modern economic thought.
in it. Learning about Japan’s economy and how it More specifically, Solow’s model of a grow-
came to be should instill an appreciation of the ing economy correctly accounts for Japan’s rapid
pervasive role of trade and the power of economic recovery from the devastations of the Pacific
incentives in organizing and shaping societies ev- war (Chapter 4). Modigliani’s life-cycle model of
erywhere. This book is for anyone curious about saving correctly predicted that postwar Japan’s
economics, for it is impossible to appreciate eco- youthful demographic profile and rapid economic
nomics without vivid examples of its application. growth would cause an enlarged national sav-
This book is also for anyone broadly interested in ing rate and that population aging would reverse
Japan, for it is impossible to fully understand Japan this (Chapter 5). The Ricardian model correctly
without learning what basic economics has to say anticipates that resource-poor, skilled-labor-rich
about it, which is much. Japan will import oil and export manufactures
(Chapter 8). Becker’s theory of investment in
company-specific skills and Lazear’s theory of
The principles of economics apply in mandatory retirement together form a coherent
Japan as they do elsewhere explanation of Japanese employment practices
(Chapter 16). Nor is this all. Samuelson’s the-
In the following pages we shall encounter some ory of revealed preference clarifies the logical
of the most famous contributions to modern eco- difficulties we encounter in comparing the eco-
nomics. Without them, convincing explanations nomic well-being of citizens of Japan with those
for many of Japan’s economic peculiarities would of other nations (Chapter 1). Coase’s exposition of
be impossible. The peculiarities include the famous the problem of social cost affords the indispens-
Japanese employment practices (lifetime employ- able framework for evaluating the achievements
ment, seniority-based wages), Japan’s “miracu- and limitations of Japan’s environmental policies
lous” postwar rapid economic growth, Japan’s (Chapter 12). The modern theory of industrial or-
once high national saving rate, Japan’s evolving ganization offers convincing interpretations of the
patterns of international trade, the allocation of many contractual arrangements linking Japanese
public resources in Japan, the patterns of regu- firms and their suppliers or customers (Chapter 13)
lation of Japanese industries, special contractual and linking marketing channel members to one
arrangements between Japanese firms and the another (Chapter 15). All of these explanations fit

The Japanese Economy. Fourth Edition. David Flath, Oxford University Press.
© David Flath (2022). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780192865342.003.0001
Introduction
squarely in the mainstream of modern economics. suzerainty of military rulers whose political status
Despite the country’s fascinating strangeness, the was determined by the taxable yield of the lands
principles of economics apply in Japan as they do under their control. The overlord in this scheme
elsewhere. was the shōgun, the mantle assumed by Tokugawa
Ieyasu and passed to his descendants. The shogu-
nal domains, known as the tenryō, encompassed
Major themes the most fertile lands and the largest cities, Edo
(now Tokyo), Osaka, and Kyoto the imperial capi-
The book follows a progression of topics, begin- tal. Directly under the shōgun stood the daimyō, the
ning with those that focus on Japan’s economy military rulers of the next largest domains, known
as a whole and proceeding to those that focus as han, and below them still others of the samurai
on particular institutions or sectors of the econ- class, warriors with no wars to fight—in effect, an
omy, or aspects of Japanese business. The order is hereditary and hierarchical civil bureaucracy. The
arbitrary in that each chapter can stand alone, in- Tokugawa capital, Edo, grew from a small fishing
dependently of the others. Thus, the reader may village of no consequence in 1600 to a city of 1 mil-
alter the order or skip from one chapter to another lion in 1700, a direct result of the shogunal decrees
and not lose the thread of discourse. Even so, four obliging all of the two to three hundred daimyō
threads do run through all the chapters: Japan’s to reside there in alternating years and their fam-
economic growth and development, Japan’s in- ilies to remain there year-round as quasi-hostages.
tegration with the world economy, government With daimyō under the watchful eye of the shogu-
policies and their effects, and peculiar economic nate, they were effectively prevented from forming
institutions and practices. Here are some previews dissenting coalitions.
of each of these major themes. The policy that most epitomized the Tokugawa
political outlook was the closure of the coun-
try. The point was to forestall change altogether
Japan’s economic growth and and perpetuate the status quo indefinitely. Con-
development tact with foreigners was an unwanted disruption
and a potential source of instability. Under de-
Japan today enjoys one of the highest standards cree of the third shogun of the Tokugawa dynasty,
of living of any nation, a state of economic well- in 1642, foreigners were expelled,and Japan was
being comparable to that of the USA. The Japanese closed to the outside world, with the minor excep-
people live long, healthy lives, eat well, are well ed- tion of limited official trade with the Dutch and
ucated, and have accumulated a substantial stock Chinese, conducted through the southern port of
of durable goods. Japan’s phenomenal economic Nagasaki.
growth since the end of World War II is only a Almost the entire productive effort of Japan in
part of a much longer account of how the na- the Tokugawa era was devoted to feeding the na-
tion achieved its current high standard of living. tion, which meant that most of the population,
The story of Japan’s economic development begins around 80%, were of the agrarian caste, and mainly
long before the twentieth century. engaged in the cultivation of rice. Most of the re-
When Europeans reached Japan in the sixteenth mainder of the population, other than the 7% or
century, they beheld a country engulfed in civil so who were of the samurai caste, were merchants
wars. Soon after the end of that eventful cen- and artisans, both of which were held in lower
tury, the wars ended and the victors, led by esteem than farmers under the Confucian ideol-
Tokugawa Ieyasu, imposed on Japan a highly reg- ogy embraced by official doctrines of the country’s
imented, caste-based, political–economic regime rulers. The farmers were obliged to pay rice taxes
that retained its essential features for the next 250 to the samurai under a scheme that made land in-
years. The political system of the Tokugawa era alienable, but ceded responsibility for managing
(1603–1868) has been described as feudalistic. The the local affairs of agricultural communities to the
country and its population were under the divided inhabitants themselves.

2
Introduction
With the civil wars ended and the daimyō se- and Europeans on more equal terms. The Meiji oli-
cure in their right to impose taxes on the lands garchs quickly dismantled the far-reaching Toku-
under their official control, land reclamation and gawa era controls on economic activity, freeing
irrigation proceeded apace in the seventeenth cen- powerful market forces that soon provided a dra-
tury, and the population of Japan grew commen- matic stimulus to Japan’s economic development.
surately, expanding from about 17 million in 1600 Japan’s seclusion had already ended with the estab-
to 30 million in 1700. Then, for the next 150 lishment of foreign treaty ports in 1858. Now the
years, the population grew hardly at all. This fits Meiji oligarchs abolished the caste system, abol-
the Malthusian model of an agrarian economy ished the system of feudal domains, dispossessed
in which equilibrium income per person is de- the samurai, and replaced the system of rice taxes
termined by the birth rate and death rate, and payable in kind with a monetary land tax that for
labor productivity only affects the equilibrium size the first time in Japan rendered agricultural land
of the population. The increase in labor produc- alienable. Soon after the implementation of the
tivity caused by expansion of arable land caused land tax, the Meiji government was able to forgo
population to expand without much affecting in- inflation, and under the capable direction of the fi-
come per person. By 1700, land reclamation had nance ministry by Matsukata M(asayoshi), secured
approached the limits of Japan’s mountainous ge- the convertibility of its currency into silver after
ography. Families of all castes began deliberately 1886 and into gold after 1897. Commercial banks
to limit their offspring, including resorting to in- facilitated the private financing of new industrial
fanticide, in calculated attempts to raise their own enterprises, and in 1882 a central bank, the Bank
living standards, and did achieve some success; in- of Japan, was founded. Much has been made of the
come per person did improve slightly. Moderate Meiji government’s official promotion of industry
technological advance and increased commercial under the political slogan shokusan kōgyō (increase
activity in the late Tokugawa period substantially production, encourage industry), but, actually, the
offset what would have been the declining effect government pilot plants established under this set
on population size of the lowering of the birth rate, of policies were small elements of the national
but without much affecting income per person. economy. The spirit of the age was one of laissez-
The Tokugawa economy was Malthusian. faire, not government planning and direction. The
By the beginning of the nineteenth century, first mechanized industry to develop on a large
the world outside Japan had undergone dra- scale in Japan was cotton spinning, and it pros-
matic changes. The industrial revolution in Eu- pered in the final decade of the nineteenth century
rope rendered Japan technologically backward. with little direct government support.
Nevertheless, Japan had indigenously developed Another Meiji era (1868–1912) political slogan,
sophisticated economic and political institutions, fukoku kyōhei (rich country, strong army), identifies
including futures markets, wholesaling and retail- the central preoccupation of Japanese government
ing networks, double entry accounting, and the leaders near the dawn of the twentieth century: im-
mechanisms of local self-government. In these perialist expansion and warfare. The Sino-Japanese
ways, Japan carried the seeds of its later rapid War of 1895 was concluded swiftly with a Japanese
economic development. victory and gained Japan colonial possessions (Tai-
The dispatch of American warships to Japan in wan and the Pescadores) and a sizable indemnity.
1853 ended Japan’s two centuries of near seclu- Japan’s victory in its 1905 war with Russia cost it
sion from the outside world. Commodore Perry’s 100,000 war dead and required an expenditure of
demand that Japan should open its ports to for- about half of its national income in that year. The
eigners set in motion a chain of events that cul- Portsmouth treaty ending the conflict conferred
minated in the 1868 Meiji Restoration, a political no financial indemnity upon Japan but expanded
revolution that ended shogunal rule and estab- the Japanese empire to include a colony on the
lished in its place an oligarchy of energetic young southern part of the island of Sakhalin and interna-
reformers intent on transforming Japan into a mil- tionally recognized spheres of Japanese influence
itary power capable of dealing with the Americans in the Korean peninsula and in China’s Kwantung

3
Introduction
peninsula. Japan annexed Korea in 1910. The fol- seriously weakened by deflationary monetary poli-
lowing year, the 1858 commercial treaties that had cies, ultimately leading to a severe banking cri-
established extra-territorial settlements of foreign sis in 1927. An unwise and unfortunately timed
traders in Japanese ports and limited Japanese tar- deflationary drive restored Japan’s prewar gold
iff rights were fully retired, bringing to fruition a parity in January 1930 just as the worldwide
cherished goal of the Meiji political leaders. Great Depression began. Then, in September 1931,
Japan entered World War I as an ally of Britain the Japanese army, without the authorization of
but managed largely to avoid actual hostilities. Japan’s elected government, undertook the oc-
Japan took advantage of the worldwide rise in in- cupation of Manchuria, a province of China in
terest rates attending the war by switching from which Japan had maintained a sphere of influ-
net international borrower to net lender and ex- ence since 1905. A Japanese puppet state was
panding aggregate output. The resulting real de- quickly established there, and the Japanese army
preciation of the yen stimulated foreign demand set about experimenting with central planning in
for Japanese goods and switched domestic demand the province, deriving few lessons from its abject
from imports to domestic goods. The business failure.
groups known as the zaibatsu expanded from their Under the able counsel of the brilliant Takahashi
initial strongholds in mining, banking, and bro- K(orekiyo) as finance minister, Japan abruptly
kerage of foreign trade into shipbuilding, iron abandoned the gold standard in December 1931
and steel, and insurance. Nevertheless, the za- and then instituted the expansionary monetary
ibatsu form of organization, in which a few fami- and fiscal policy that effectively insulated Japan
lies maintained concentrated ownership in diverse from the worldwide Great Depression—but too
holdings through the pyramiding of shares, was at late. After the assassination of the prime minis-
no time the only viable way of financing and ad- ter in May 1932, the Japanese military insinuated
ministering businesses in Japan. Cotton-spinning itself into the choosing of prime ministers and
companies were among the largest corporations in cabinets and in conducting Japan’s foreign af-
Japan in the first decades of the twentieth century fairs. Democracy and cooperation with Britain and
and were, for the most part, diversely held joint- America were effectively ended from that time.
stock enterprises. Also, about half the labor force Takahashi, too, the “Keynes of Japan,” fell before
of Japan continued to work as self-employed farm- assassins in the failed coup of February 26, 1936.
ers, and another quarter of the labor force worked In July 1937, Japan initiated war with China, and
in small enterprises. the government of Japan began to switch the econ-
The 1920s was a time of economic malaise in omy to a war footing, increasing arms purchases
Japan, partly owing to mistaken macroeconomic dramatically. A series of diplomatic blunders led
policies, but also exacerbated by the 1923 Tokyo Japan in 1941 into the disastrous war with the Al-
earthquake. Japan took important strides toward lies which it could not win, and which left the
establishing parliamentary democracy in those Japanese economy in ruins.
years, enjoying alternating rule by two political For six years and eight months after the war,
parties, the conservative Seiyūkai and more lib- from August 1945 to April 1952, the government
eral Kenseikai–Minseitō. Japan joined Britain and of Japan was completely subordinate to that of
the USA in arms limitation agreements, diplomatic the USA. This was the period of the American
treaties, and the establishment of an open world Occupation. The Americans drafted a new consti-
trading regime anchored by the gold standard. In tution that permanently established democracy,
pursuit of these aims, Japan sought to rejoin the dissolved the zaibatsu, redistributed agricultural
gold standard at the same parity it had maintained land, and enacted laws legitimizing labor unions.
from 1897 to 1917. To accomplish this, the gov- Additionally, the Americans allowed or di-
ernment authorities had to reverse the substantial rected the continuation of wartime price controls
inflation that had occurred in Japan in the in- and rationing, embargoes on foreign trade, and
tervening years. The Tokyo earthquake dealt a inflation-financed subsidies of industrial firms.
devastating blow to a Japanese economy already Japan’s postwar recovery did not begin until these

4
Introduction
disastrous policies were suspended as part of Amer- the goods for which it has relatively low incremen-
ica’s “reverse course” from a punitive toward a re- tal costs of producing and imports the goods it
constructive Japan policy, beginning in 1949. The has high incremental costs of producing, then how
rapid economic growth of the Japanese economy, can it both export and import like-goods? Newer
from this time until the mid-1970s, is a triumph of theories point to the pursuit of oligopoly profit as a
unfettered capitalism. The ongoing process of sav- motivation for intra-industry trade. Even if nations
ing and investment eventually restored the stock have the same incremental costs of producing a
of wealth that Japan had dissipated in the war. good so that none has a comparative advantage,
The elevation of the growth path of Japan’s aggre- they may still each supply goods in all of the na-
gate output above the trajectory extrapolated from tions’ respective markets, simply to capture a share
the prewar years reflects the dramatic enlargement of the profit that accompanies competition among
of Japan’s national saving rate compared with the the few.
prewar era. In fact, Japan’s national saving rate was Much intra-industry trade arises as the intra-
until the 1990s among the world’s largest, which company shipments of multinational enterprises,
accounted for its persistent trade surpluses. companies that produce goods in more than one
nation. Possibly this reflects the fact that multi-
national enterprises include many of the world’s
Japan’s integration with the world largest companies and are characteristic of the
economy oligopolistic industries most apt to invite intra-
industry trade. One reason for the small extent of
After its opening to trade in 1858, Japan immedi- Japan’s intra-industry trade is that foreign multi-
ately began to export the goods that, before then, national enterprises control relatively few assets in
had lower prices at home than elsewhere, includ- Japan. The Japanese government once restricted
ing silk and tea, and to import the goods that foreign control of domestic assets, but that pol-
previously had higher prices at home, including icy ended with enactment of the Foreign Exchange
cotton and wool, just as Ricardo’s theory of com- and Investment Control Law of 1980. The limited
parative advantage would have predicted. Japan’s presence of foreign multinationals in Japan now,
integration into the world economy contributed decades after de jure restrictions on inward foreign
to the international division of labor and thereby direct investment were lifted, is perhaps because
expanded the consumption possibilities of both peculiarities of the Japanese language and culture
Japan and other countries. make it a difficult place for foreigners to live and
This continues to be true today. Japan’s major work. Government protectionism has little to do
imports include the oil and other natural resources with Japan’s low stock of inward foreign direct in-
that it lacks, and that would surely command high vestment or the small extent of its intra-industry
prices in Japan were it to forgo international trade. trade.
Similarly, Japan exports manufactures that inten- Protectionist interferences with trade generally
sively employ the capital and skilled labor it has in constrict a nation’s consumption possibilities,
abundance and, through foreign direct investment even though they enrich the protected industries.
in lesser developed nations, exports the services Protectionism is, on net, harmful to the nation
of the entrepreneurs and managers it also has in that imposes it, and thus represents the triumph
abundance. Japan is the supreme example today of a narrow special interest over the broader na-
validating the Ricardian theory of comparative tional interest. Special interests seeking protection
advantage. are more likely to prevail in industry-by-industry
But this very fact has been viewed by some referenda than in economy-wide referenda. This
as anomalous; for the other developed nations, is why international treaties were necessary to
but not Japan, engage in substantial intra-industry prompt Japan and the other developed nations
trade, the import and export of like products. Intra- to reduce their tariff rates; the treaties broadened
industry trade does not comport easily with no- the political question of free trade versus protec-
tions of comparative advantage. If a nation exports tion in a way that undercut the special interests

5
Introduction
within each nation. As a full participant in the in identifying the underlying bases for long-term
rounds of multilateral agreements to reduce tariff trends in exchange rates. For instance, the gradual
rates, Japan has joined the developed nations in real appreciation of the yen relative to the US dol-
liberalizing its trade policies. The continuing in- lar which was evident throughout the 1950s and
stances of protectionism by Japan have analogues 1960s exemplifies a phenomenon known as the
in other nations. For instance, Japan’s restrictions Balassa–Samuelson effect. Short-term movements
on rice imports can be compared to America’s re- in exchange rates are a less well understood. Prob-
strictions on sugar imports. The sad saga of 1980s ably they exhibit the influence of macroeconomic
Japan–USA trade friction was not about Japan’s policies, but in a complicated way. Exchange rate
“closed” markets or “unfair” practices: it was about movements caused by macroeconomic policies do
how best to deal with or deflect the political pres- bring about consistent changes in trade balances
sure inside the USA for protection from expanded but with a lag of up to two years.
Japanese imports. Partly, the expanded imports
from Japan reflected the rapid growth of Japan’s
economy. But the most vituperative trade disputes Government policies and their effects
between Japan and the USA surfaced in 1985, af-
ter several years in which extreme real appreciation Monetary and fiscal policy, trade policy, public
of the US dollar relative to the yen had added fur- spending, environmental policy, government reg-
ther stimulus to American purchases of Japanese ulation, and other government policies are sig-
goods. nificant elements of any nation’s economy, and
Nations gain not only from their exchange of Japan is no exception. That said, the government
one another’s commodities and services, but also of Japan has a smaller presence in its economy
from their exchange of claims on one another’s than is often recognized. In 2017, government em-
future incomes, sometimes referred to as intertem- ployees comprise less than 10% of Japan’s labor
poral trade. A nation’s extent of intertemporal force (in the USA it is 18%). With the privati-
trade equals its imbalance of trade in commodi- zation of telecommunications and the national
ties and services. If a nation exports more than railway, there no longer exist large public enter-
it imports, then it necessarily accumulates claims prises in Japan. Government spending, including
on the future incomes of foreigners, for the ex- transfers, amounts to about one-third of the na-
ports had to have been exchanged for something. tion’s aggregate output, which is comparable to
The converse is also true. One expects a nation the USA and less than many of the European na-
with a high national saving rate to accumulate tions. The national government in Japan controls
foreign assets, that is, to lend to other nations almost all public expenditures either directly or in-
or accumulate IOUs issued by trading partners, directly. Centralization of control economizes on
and so to export more than it imports, achiev- administrative costs but limits the range of choices
ing a trade surplus, as indeed Japan has done. available to citizens willing to move from one local
In the past, Japan, like other countries, has also jurisdiction to another. The objects of public ex-
resorted to foreign borrowing, and has incurred penditure are largely the same in Japan as in other
temporary trade deficits to maintain consump- nations. They include defense, education, health
tion when confronted with the windfall losses of insurance, and social security pensions.
a natural disaster such as the 1923 Tokyo earth- The scale of the public sector is a measure of
quake or an event such as the first oil shock. only one dimension of government’s role in the
Some adjustments of trade balances reflect not au- economy. Another dimension is regulation, the
tonomous shifts such as these in nations’ propen- setting of rules that private firms must obey. There
sities to save, but prior movements in exchange is little that is extraordinary about the govern-
rates. Economists have not succeeded very well ment regulation of industry in Japan. The national
in explaining short-term movements in exchange government has asserted explicit control over the
rates, but they have had a little more success pricing and entry of firms in the public utilities,

6
Introduction
transport, telecommunications, and financial ser- Ministry of International Trade and Industry MITI
vices industries, as have almost all other nations of (renamed METI—the ministry of economy, trade,
the world. Antimonopoly law pertains to firms in and industry—in January 2001), the same ministry
all industries. Japan’s antimonopoly law is a legacy that directed the policies of the key government
of the American Occupation and has survived to financial intermediaries.
the present day but without the vigorous support This is what the much-vaunted industrial pol-
of the elected governments. Resources devoted to icy of Japan really amounted to, which is to say,
the enforcement of antimonopoly laws are limited it didn’t amount to much. The Japanese industries
and penalties for violations are small. It is fair to that benefited the most from public loans, other
say that antimonopoly law has imposed fewer con- subsidies, and protectionism were mostly politi-
straints on the practices of corporations in Japan cally powerful but economically anemic ones such
than in the USA. Furthermore, the patent laws of as coal mining, textiles, and shipbuilding. Japan
Japan afford only weak protection for inventions, prospered despite government experiments with
promote the early revelation of discoveries, and industrial policy, not because of them.
encourage the licensing of inventions on terms fa- The record of monetary and fiscal policy in Japan
vorable to users. All of this is quite sensible from includes both successes and failures. Japan has en-
the point of view of promoting the rapid diffusion dured fifteen business recessions since 1950, tem-
within Japan of foreign innovations and, perhaps porary downward deviations from the economy’s
for that reason, was optimal, given the country’s equilibrium growth path. But avoiding all of these
status as a late developer. recessions—including the three recessions of the
The preceding remarks are quite at variance with 1990s “lost decade” and the 2008 global reces-
the popular notion that a coterie of elite govern- sion triggered by the Lehman bankruptcy—would
ment bureaucrats direct the allocation of resources have been equivalent to about a 1–2% perma-
in Japan’s economy. Proponents of that view focus nent rise in Japan’s national income. To put this
particular attention on the public-sector financial in perspective, contemplate that technological ad-
intermediaries of Japan. The postal saving system vance, on average, accomplishes this every year in
of Japan, founded in 1875, allows individuals to Japan.
make time deposits and purchase life insurance at The overall picture here is that Japan’s macroe-
post office establishments throughout the coun- conomic policy has mattered very little. But there
try. It may be the largest depository institution in have been policy mistakes. Japan’s Heisei recession
the world. Postal savings deposits now comprise a that so weakened the asset positions of commercial
whopping 22% of all financial deposits in Japan. In banks there, followed the unnecessary and sharp
a process known as the Fiscal Investment and Loan monetary contraction of 1990 directed by the Bank
Program, these postal deposits and other public of Japan governor, Mieno Y(asushi). In the years af-
funds are transferred to government financial in- ter that event, the Bank of Japan entered uncharted
stitutions, which issue loans to local governments territory in which the conventional ways of con-
and to private businesses. By manipulating the ducting monetary policy had become inoperative,
process just described, it seems that the govern- a world of zero or even negative interest rates and
ment of Japan might have redirected the allocation firmly entrenched deflation. Before this, the Bank
of loanable funds toward favored industries that of Japan conducted monetary policy by adjusting
would have been shunned by profit-seeking fi- its ongoing securities market transactions to influ-
nancial intermediaries. Favored sectors in Japan ence short-term interest rates, with the interbank
have also enjoyed special tax breaks and subsidies, overnight interest rate—the call rate, Japanese ana-
and special exemptions from antimonopoly laws, logue of the US federal funds rate—as its operating
but these have not really had much bite. During target. Through arbitrage, a lower call rate was
the 1950s, and continuing until 1964, compre- quickly reflected in other interest rates including
hensive foreign exchange rationing conferred de commercial bank prime lending rates. Lower inter-
facto government control of the pattern of im- est rates led banks to expand their loans, and in
ports into Japan. This control was exercised by the doing so increase the stock of money in the form

7
Introduction
of bank deposits, a stimulus to aggregate demand. placed on the added leisure is less than the value
In February 1999, the BOJ had lowered the call placed on the commodities and services that could
rate to zero, previously unimaginable. Lowering have instead been produced and consumed. In
the call rate further had become impossible. This this way, the burden of taxes is greater than the
situation has continued with some interruptions revenue generated. A back-of-envelope calculation
ever since, from February 1999 until August 2000 suggests that the burden of Japan’s taxes is cur-
and then from April 2001 to July 2006 and since rently 6.6% greater than tax revenues, roughly 2%
December 2008. And now the US Federal Reserve of the market value of aggregate output (GDP).
Bank and the European Central Bank face the same Tax reforms such as switching from income taxes
liquidity trap dilemma. The BOJ has tried many to a national sales tax as Japan is now undertak-
things—expansion of the monetary base, massive ing, are aimed at broadening the tax base, lowering
purchases of securities, intervening in the mar- marginal tax rates, and decreasing the excess bur-
ket for Japanese government bonds to lower their den … so that taxes may be raised further with
yields—but has not succeeded in raising Japan’s little political resistance. Whether Japanese taxes
inflation rate and escaping the zero-interest-rate are high enough or Japanese government spending
situation. Japanese economy watchers need to be is low enough are political questions to be resolved
apprised of these developments if they are to fol- through elections.
low current events.
Japan’s recessions and deflation since the 1990s
have eroded incomes and pushed households and Economic institutions and practices
businesses into lower marginal tax brackets and peculiar to Japan
reduced tax revenues. Furthermore, the aging of
the Japanese population has increased government Much of the fascination with Japan’s economy,
spending on retirement pensions and health care and the greatest challenge for economists, arises
relative to the wages and incomes subject to tax- from the many unique institutions and practices,
ation. The result of all this been an explosion of and peculiar features, of the Japanese economy.
Japanese government debt, alarming to many, less These include the Japanese employment sys-
alarming to the fully informed. All government tem (lifetime employment, seniority-based wages,
expenditures must eventually be funded by taxes. and enterprise unions), the self-organization of
Accumulating government debt merely postpones Japanese firms into business groups, the special
tax collection. Questions about government debt arrangements between Japanese banks and their
are fundamentally questions about taxes: Are cur- client firms, and the complex and fragmented
rent taxes high enough? Is the structure of taxes Japanese marketing system. Satisfying economic
minimally burdensome? Are the taxes fair? These explanations for such structures can take a variety
questions are complicated because the incidence of different forms. They can relate the peculiari-
and burden of each tax depends on the behav- ties to underlying givens like geography. They can
ior people adopt in attempts to avoid tax bur- identify the apparent peculiarities as illusory in
dens. For instance, taxes on corporate income in- the sense that the Japanese arrangements solve a
duce corporations to supply less output, employ universal problem no less satisfactorily than alter-
fewer workers, and sell at higher prices, which natives might do. And finally, they can relate the
shifts the tax burden away from corporate share- peculiarities to a confluence of historical events
holders and onto the corporation’s customers and unique to Japan. The best explanations fit more
employees. Such tax shifting is extensive to the than one of these patterns.
point that virtually all taxes may be presumed Japan’s distribution system, though frequently
to be taxes on work and on the reward from labeled “inefficient,” is manifestly not. Japan’s pro-
paid employment, which induce wasteful substi- liferation of small stores reflects its geography. The
tution of leisure for the commodities and ser- ubiquity of stores affords households the added
vices that may be purchased with the wages from convenience of next-door shopping, which they
paid employment. It is wasteful because the value particularly value because it enables them to shop

8
Introduction
frequently, maintain low household stocks of daily labor force but have remained largely outside the
necessities, and economize on scarce living space. lifetime employment and seniority-based pay sys-
Japan’s distribution system evolved this way, in tem. The institutions for educating, hiring, and
part, because the geographic centricity of the training employees that evolved in Japan over
country means that the added costs of restocking the last hundred years have favored the career
a superabundance of small stores, as opposed to a advancement of men and foreclosed opportunities
smaller number of large ones, are relatively small. for many Japanese women. This is a dilemma with
From these pivotal observations many others fol- no easy answer.
low. For instance, the large number of small retail In Japan, banks have long played a domi-
shops and owners tipped the political balance in nant role in financial intermediation, collecting
favor of regulations protecting small stores from deposits from households, and extending loans
competition with larger ones. Japan’s Large Store to private businesses and to government. In the
Law, which placed significant legal obstacles to USA, and some other nations, securities markets
the opening of stores with large floor space, con- are a more important source of funds and banks
tributed further toward the proliferation of small less important. Here the Japanese peculiarity may
stores, but probably would not have been toler- be less consequential than is often supposed. The
ated in Japan if it had imposed very large costs universal problems that financial intermediaries
or tended to run counter to the economic forces must face invite a range of possible solutions,
already shaping Japan’s distribution sector. The none necessarily superior to the others. Govern-
complexity of marketing channels in Japan, for in- ment regulations play an important role in de-
stance the large number of wholesale steps, is also termining which specific arrangements emerge in
derivative of the ubiquity of small stores; explain any nation, but there is a fundamental arbitrari-
the one, and the other follows. ness to it, in the sense that one set of arrange-
The employment practices that pertain to the ments solves the problems about as well as some
regular male employees of the large compa- others might have done. The dominant role of
nies, about one-fifth of Japan’s labor force, rep- banks in Japanese financial intermediation owes
resent a sophisticated response to the universal a lot to government regulations that effectively
problems inherent in recruiting, training, orga- cartelized and protected the banks but insured de-
nizing, and motivating workers. These practices posits. When Japanese regulatory constraints on
include seniority-based pay and promotion lad- euromarket finance were lifted in the mid-1980s,
ders, mandatory retirement, and on-the-job train- the Japanese domestic banking cartel began to un-
ing. The seniority-based pay schemes discourage ravel. With decartelization, Japanese banks’ profits
quits and, at the same time, enlarge the oner- eroded, and their lending grew reckless. This was
ousness to employees of early dismissal, which particularly so under the expansionary Japanese
enables the employers to economize on the costs of monetary policy following the February 1987 Lou-
training workers in company-specific skills, while vre Accord. The resulting run-up in asset prices in
preserving performance incentives. Other features 1988–9 was followed by a crash in 1990–1 that
of Japan’s labor markets follow from the ones left the Japanese banks’ net worth in a precarious
just noted. For instance, Japan’s low unemploy- state. And the 1990s slow-down in macroeconomic
ment rates largely reflect the infrequency with growth and investment worsened the situation of
which the regular male employees of the large Japanese commercial banks still further. In spite
companies experience bouts of unemployment. of all this, bank loans remain the most important
The organization of workers into enterprise rather source of external funds to Japanese businesses.
than industry-wide unions has also received some Even though Japanese companies are now rela-
encouragement from the strong attachments of tively free to issue securities rather than only re-
workers to their incumbent employers. Women in lying on bank loans for funds, many of them have
Japan have long had high labor force participa- nevertheless retained their strong attachments to
tion rates and now comprise around half of the particular banks.

9
Introduction
The self-organization of Japanese firms into A final comment
business groups originated with the zaibatsu.
The zaibatsu were vast commercial empires, each To know Japan—or any country for that matter—
controlled by a wealthy family through the pyra- is more than an ability to recite a litany of facts
miding of closely held shares; they reached their about its history, geography, institutions, and cul-
fullest development soon after World War I. The ture. Knowledge without insight does not lead to
zaibatsu represented a form of corporate gover- understanding. Disciplined thinking is needed to
nance, highly effective and successful in some organize the disparate facts into a coherent system
industries, but absent and apparently unnecessary that can be grasped whole. Modern economics is
in others, for example cotton-spinning. With the academic discipline underlying this book. It is
the appropriation and disbursal of the zaibatsu the economics of Smith, Malthus, Ricardo, Samuel-
founding families’ shares by the American Occu- son, Becker, Coase, and others—great minds of
pation government of Japan, the zaibatsu were the past who strived to understand the world.
dissolved. But when the Occupation ended, the Economics textbooks that only describe imagi-
constituent member firms of the old zaibatsu soon nary worlds can make the subject seem sterile and
re-established their former alliances. The members pointless. To see the power of economics you must
of each one of the new groups, called financial use it to think about the actual world, of which
keiretsu, traded with one another and were linked Japan is a microcosm and a worthy object of study.
by cross-shareholding. With the demise of the Having extolled the power of economics let me
founding families of the zaibatsu, the large banks hasten to note its limitation. Economics is not
now insinuated themselves into the governance of the be-all and end-all. In universities today, Japan
the former zaibatsu member corporations. Perhaps studies are often represented as multidisciplinary,
this was natural, given the important role of the encompassing not only economics, but also po-
banks as suppliers of funds to the companies, as litical science, sociology, history, literature, and
discussed above. more. We can and should learn from all of them.

10
Incomes and Welfare of the
1
Japanese Today

Japan is a prosperous country. Most of its cit- Technological advance starting in the late nine-
izens eat well, live comfortably, and enjoy the teenth century increased income per person in
many blessings of life in the twenty-first century. Japan by an average of 3% each year over the next
To go beyond such banalities, a precise measure hundred years, ultimately increasing income per
of economic well-being is needed. The national person sixteen-fold. Technological advance is the
income and product accounts provide the con- root and branch of Japanese economic prosperity.
ceptual framework for such a measure. National We might not know that if we had no usable
income records the aggregate monetary value of measure of the contribution of market goods to
the flow of goods produced and traded in the our economic well-being.
market. Market goods are major contributors to One aim of this chapter is to compare the eco-
our well-being. Nonmarket goods such as home- nomic well-being of the Japanese today with that
cooked meals, time away from paid employment, of their own forbears and people of other nations.
and sunny days also contribute to well-being—and Differences in relative prices over time and across
we want to measure their contribution too. But space complicate such comparisons. The way for-
from calculations of national income alone we can ward is rooted in the principal of revealed pref-
still learn much that is worth knowing. erence. It is the bedrock on which all economics
In this book we will use national income rests, the principal that a person’s choices may re-
to gauge and compare the contributions to veal her own consistent ranking of the alternatives
Japanese economic well-being from international before her. Is a Japanese person, in her own estima-
trade (Chapter 8), business cycle stabiliza- tion, better off than her foreign counterpart? If she
tion (Chapter 6), and technological advance could have consumed the same goods as the coun-
(Chapter 17). When in the 1850s Japan opened terpart but chose not to, then the answer is “yes.”
to international trade after two centuries of In the current chapter we will apply this logic.
nearly complete closure, the immediate result Another difficulty in welfare comparisons is how
was a permanent increase in Japanese income to measure the contributions of nonmarket goods.
per person by about 8%. Business recessions— What is the price of a sunny day or an ocean view?
including the ones triggered by the oil shocks And what does that even mean? What is the price
of 1974 and 1979, the Japanese asset price crash of a home-cooked meal or a day off from work?
of 1991, the global financial crisis of 2008, and We will boldly answer these questions and explain
many others—altogether are lowering Japanese how the choices made by Japanese people reveal
economic well-being by the equivalent of a 1% their valuations of non-market goods just as they
permanent reduction in income per person. do for market goods.

The Japanese Economy. Fourth Edition. David Flath, Oxford University Press.
© David Flath (2022). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780192865342.003.0002
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today
Cross-country comparisons of economic well- and work within Japan’s borders are not Japanese
being revolve around a typical or average person, nationals but foreigners. The aggregate income of
but what about the variation within each country? Japanese nationals is reported in the system of na-
The distribution of wealth matters if we are com- tional accounts as the Gross National Income (GNI)
paring a person chosen randomly from Japan with of Japan.1 The aggregate spending on final goods
one chosen randomly from another country. The and services that gives rise to the GNI of Japan—
distribution of Japanese wealth is less skewed than and is in principal equal to it—is the Gross National
that of the USA and some other countries. That Product (GNP) of Japan.
means that a Japanese person chosen randomly is When considering the pace of aggregate pro-
more likely to have an income that is close to the duction in Japan’s economy, our focus will be
national average. An American chosen randomly on all economic activity within the geographic
is likely to have an income well below the na- borders of Japan, including production by non-
tional average. The smaller inequality of wealth in Japanese nationals operating within the country
Japan compared to the US should raise your assess- and excluding production by ex-patriot Japanese
ment of the economic well-being of the average or nationals. The value at current market prices of
typical Japanese compared to that of the typical all final goods and services produced within the
American, even if you are a non-egalitarian. geographic borders of Japan in a given period
There are many topics to address here. We will is the Japanese Gross Domestic Product (GDP).
begin with the basics. Figure 1.1 shows the trajectories of GDP and GNP
(= GNI) for Japan, from 1994 to 2018 calendar
years. They move together, but Japan’s GDP is 1–
National income, GNP, and GDP 4% lower than its GNI, reflecting that the value
of production by Japanese companies outside of
Income is the monetary amount that could be Japan outweighs that of foreign companies within
spent in a given period and leave wealth un- Japan.
changed. Income is not only the basis for spending A rise in income expands consumption possi-
but also the result of it, a manifestation of the cir- bilities, not just in the immediate time period
cular flow of economic activity in which spending but in the future too. This is the fundamental
by one is income for another. Accordingly, there link between income and economic well-being,
are two ways to measure income. One way is to add that a rise in income is a relaxation of the con-
up the incomes in each category—wages, rental straint on spending in the market. The spending
income from the employment of capital (build- itself is promoting economic well-being but not
ings, machines, and tools), and economic profit. always in an obvious or direct way. The aggre-
The second way is to add up the spending on fi- gate spending on final goods and services that
nal goods and services that gives rise to the flow makes up gross product (Y, meaning either GNP or
of income. The restriction to final sales is to avoid GDP) includes final purchases by households (C,
a problem of double counting that would arise “consumption”), by businesses (I, “investment”),
if intermediate transactions were aggregated. For by government (G), and by foreigners (X, “ex-
example, wheat is sold first to the miller, then as ports”). This is represented by the fundamental
flour to the baker, and finally as bread to the house- equation of the national income and product
hold; only the final sale—that of the bread—needs accounts.
to be included for a complete accounting. Aggre-
gate spending on final goods and services is in
Y = C + I + G + X − M,
principal equal to aggregate income.
Consider the income of Japanese “nationals,”
defined to include all citizens and permanent resi- 1
It is “gross” national income because it ignores depreci-
dents of Japan and the government of Japan. Some ation of the capital stock, the depletion of wealth caused by
the wearing out of buildings, machinery, and tools. Net Na-
Japanese nationals are working outside of Japan’s tional Income and its twin, Net National Product, subtract
geographic borders, and some of those who live depreciation from their “gross” counterparts.

12
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today

5,80,000

5,60,000
GNP=GNI

5,40,000
Billions of Yen

5,20,000

5,00,000

4,80,000 GDP Figure 1.1. Gross domestic


product (GDP) and gross
national product (GNP = GNI),
4,60,000
Japan, 1994–2018
Source: Cabinet Office, National
4,40,000
Income and Product Accounts,
94

96

98

00

02

04

06

08

10

12

14

16

18
2008 SNA.
19

19

19

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
where “imports,” M, is subtracted from aggregate spending for purchases of final goods based on
final purchases so that the right-hand side of the who is doing the spending—households, busi-
equation adds up to spending on final goods pro- nesses, government, or foreigners. In thinking
duced by the home country and not by foreign about how national income is used to promote
ones. Here, if Y stands for GDP, then exports and economic well-being, households are the proper
imports have the standard interpretation as cross- focus. Note, then, that businesses are owned by
border sales and purchases. If Y stands for GNP, households, the government is providing a stream
then exports and imports are understood to also of goods and services to households, and the for-
include any cross-border factor payments (wages eign sector is trading with households directly or
and capital rental payments earned by expatriate with the other domestic sectors just identified. This
nationals). This adjustment adds to exports any suggests another useful way of partitioning the
sales of final goods by expatriate nationals (which spending on final goods and services that add up
approximately equals the factor payments they re- to the gross product: spending that is for consump-
ceive), and adds to imports any purchases of final tion, and spending that is for domestic or foreign
goods from foreign producers within the country’s investment.
own borders (which approximately equal the fac- National income is disposed as consumption, in-
tor payments earned by these expatriate foreign vestment, or purchase of foreign assets. That is,
producers). either it is traded for goods and services used up
We next consider how each element of spending by households in the immediate period (consump-
for purchases of final goods and services is mea- tion); or it is used to accumulate machines, tools,
sured, and how each contributes to the economic and other durables that will add to the economy’s
well-being of households. capacity to produce goods and services in future
periods (investment); or it is used to buy land,
Spending is either for consumption, property, or securities from foreigners (accumula-
investment, or accumulation of foreign wealth tion of foreign wealth).
In the national accounts, spending by businesses
The fundamental equation of the national income for final goods and household spending for new
and product accounts (Y=C+I+G+X−M), partitions houses is labeled investment while other spending

13
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today
by households is labeled consumption. Most con- the net accumulation of claims on the future in-
sumption services of houses arise from spending in comes of foreigners, equals exports minus imports
earlier periods. Consequently, a price must be im- (“net exports”). This is because exports not fully
puted to the services of owner-occupied housing. paid for in the current period must entail a promise
A similar imperfect imputation could be made for of future payment. More on this in Chapter 7.
other household durables but is not in the official The fundamental equation becomes the follow-
statistics of Japan (and other nations). ing.
In the national accounts of Japan, government
purchases of final goods are identified as either Y = CC + CI + I + GC + GI + X − M,
consumption or investment, but in the accounts
of the USA (until quite recently) and many other where CC + CI = C and GC + GI = G. Rearranging, we
countries, such an explicit allocation of govern- get this.
ment purchases is not indicated. Of course, in- Consumption Saving
dividual researchers may make their own conjec- Domestic Foreign
tures about the extent of government purchases investment investment
that should be counted as investment and con-
.
sumption. In the Japanese national accounts, gov- Y = CC + GC + I + CI + GI + X – M
ernment purchases of buildings, roads, and other
This expression shows how the gross product Y is
public works are counted as investment, while pur-
devoted either to consumption, including goods
chases for national defense and compensation of
and services households themselves purchase and
government employees are counted as consump-
ones provided to them through the government,
tion.
or to investment, including both domestic invest-
It may seem odd to count defense spending
ment and foreign investment. The consumption
as consumption; military weapons purchased in
obviously contributes to economic well-being; it is
one year will presumably continue to be used
the very embodiment of economic well-being. But
to deter foreign attacks in future years. These
what about investment?
purchases thus represent investments in an eco-
nomic sense, rather than consumption. The rea-
Investment contributes to sustainable
son for treating the entirety of defense spending
consumption
as consumption in Japan’s national accounts is
that the national government is prevented by law The level of economic well-being inherent in the
from issuing bonds in excess of that needed to national accounts is the portion of national in-
finance investment (kensetsu, lit. construction), ex- come devoted to consumption. Investment raises
cept in extraordinary circumstances. Counting de- the possible future level of consumption. Based on
fense spending as consumption thus nominally the Solow growth model (explained in Chapter 4),
restrains appropriations for defense.2 The point a market economy will approach a steady state
here is that the economic distinction between con- in which consumption per person rises only with
sumption and investment in principle guides the technological advance. In this way of thinking,
presentation of national income accounts, but in higher fractions of national income devoted to in-
fact it does so only imperfectly. vestment will sustain higher steady-state levels of
Based on this discussion, we modify the funda- consumption. Japan’s once high saving rate and
mental equation by noting that spending on final correspondingly high investment rate enabled it
goods by households C includes both consump- to attain a higher sustainable consumption level.
tion CC and investment in the form of spending To argue as some have that Japan’s saving lowers
for housing CI . And spending on final goods by
government G also includes both consumption in 2
In fact, in every year since 1974 the national government
the form of services that government provides to has issued bonds in excess of that needed for investment.
Special deficit-covering bonds had to be authorized in each
households GC and investment in the form of pur- year by the Diet. It seems that extraordinary circumstances
chases of durable goods GI . Foreign investment, have in fact become ordinary.

14
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today
economic well-being because it takes away from which is a reflection of the obvious difficulties of
immediate consumption is to adopt a myopic view international trade in these items.
that places little weight on future consumption Comparison of national incomes or consump-
possibilities. The upshot is that steady-state con- tion levels converted into common currency units
sumption is the embodiment of economic well- at current exchange rates imperfectly accounts for
being and tends to rise or fall along with national the differences in relative prices across countries.
income. For instance, the dramatic appreciation in the yen
from 260 yen/dollar in 1985 to 135 yen/dollar in
1990, a period in which domestic inflation rates
Consumption levels and national income
in Japan and the USA were roughly the same, did
Table 1.1 reports for Japan and the other G7 not have a great effect on the relative consumption
countries in 2018, each’s per-capita GDP and its possibilities (“purchasing power”) of Japanese and
composition, partitioned into consumption and Americans. There are many consumption goods
investment. Investment, the acquisition of durable in both countries that are not easily traded in-
goods and of claims on future foreign income, ternationally. The 1985 fall in the yen price of
is, by definition, gross accumulation of wealth— dollars meant a fall in the yen prices of goods
saving. But only the portion of investment beyond that Japanese bought from Americans relative to
what is needed for replacing the buildings, ma- the yen prices of goods in Japan not traded in-
chines, and tools that have depreciated with use ternationally, including land. The rise in Japanese
represents a net accumulation of wealth. Net sav- purchasing power was not as great as if yen prices
ing is gross saving minus depreciation, shown in of all goods bought by the Japanese had fallen in
the table. For Japan and most other countries with the same proportion as the change in the exchange
advanced economies, consumption (private and rate.
public combined) absorbs the greater part of ex-
penditures on final goods, ranging from around
75% to 85% of GDP. Basic economic numeracy lies Real income indices and revealed
in knowing this and other such facts evident in the preferences
table.
The national accounts are computed in the do- Another way of ranking the consumption possibil-
mestic currency of each respective country. Inter- ities of citizens of different countries is to deter-
national comparisons of consumption per person mine for the representative citizen of each whether
based on these accounts must make some assump- her income is enough to have purchased a com-
tion about the rate of conversion between cur- parable consumption bundle to that chosen by
rencies. The simplest procedure is to use current the other given the prices in her own country. If
exchange rates, and that is what we have done in another’s chosen bundle was attainable, then the
the first column of the table. one reveals by her choice a preference for her own
This procedure (conversion at current exchange bundle. If for example an American could have
rates) is justified by the purchasing power parity (PPP) purchased a similar consumption bundle to that
thesis. Under the strongest form of this thesis, the chosen by the Japanese but did not, then the Amer-
price of each good will be the same in all coun- ican must prefer her own bundle. This procedure
tries that trade freely with one another if reckoned requires us to determine the value of each one’s
in the currency units of any one of the coun- consumption bundle in the domestic prices of ev-
tries, based on current exchange rates. In a trivial ery other country. Kravis, Heston, and Summers
sense the PPP thesis is true, for divergences from have done this for 34 countries, including Japan, in
PPP can always be associated with some barrier 1975 and for 60 countries, again including Japan,
to trade that is the result of either government in 1980.3 More recently, The World Bank has
interference with trade or natural impediments.
Consumption activities that use land tend to have 3
Irving B. Kravis, Alan Heston, and Robert Summers,
higher relative prices within Japan than elsewhere, World Product and Income, International Comparisons of Real

15
16
Table 1.1. GDP per capita and its composition; Japan and selected other nations 2018

Units = % GDP unless otherwise noted


Consumption Domestic investment Foreign investment
Country Population Exchange rate Per-capita GDP CC Gc I CI GI X−M X M Net saving Gross Saving Depreciation GNI=GNP
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today

(ths) ($ per person) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)

Canada 37,058 1.296 C$/$ 46,311 78.9 57.9 20.9 22.5 10 8.5 4 −2.0 32.1 34 4 20.6 16.6 98.7
France 67,265 0.847 €/$ 41,446 77.2 53.9 23.3 22.9 13.5 6 3.4 −1.0 31.7 32.8 3.7 21.9 18.2 101.9
Germany 82,906 0.847 €/$ 47,639 72 52.1 19.9 21.2 12.5 6.3 2.4 6.2 47.4 41.3 9.1 27.3 18.2 102.8
Italy 60,459 0.847 €/$ 34,499 79.3 60.3 19 17.8 10.4 5.3 2.1 2.4 31.5 29.1 2.7 20.2 17.6 101.1
Japan 126,443 110.423 ¥/$ 39,186 75.4 55.6 19.8 24.1 16.9 3.4 3.8 0.2 18.5 18.3 1.8 24.4 22.6 103.7
UK 66,436 0.75 £/$ 43,062 84 65.5 18.5 16.9 10.1 4.1 2.7 −1.4 30.6 32 0.9 15.5 14.6 98.5
US 327,436 1 62,853 82.1 68 14.1 20.7 11.2 6.4 3.2 −3.1 12.2 15.3 1.6 17.6 16 101.2
OECD* 1,350,252 PPP 39,384 77.3 60.1 17.2 22.4 n.a. n.a. n.a. 0.3 30 29.7 n.a. 22.7 n.a. n.a.

* The Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development is a consortium of 37 of the developed countries including the seven also listed here separately, the “G-7".
Source. OECD.Stat, National Accounts at a Glance.
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today

Table 1.2. Revealed preferences, 2017

Value of Japanese bundle at prices of Value of foreign bundle at Japanese prices


respective country ÷
÷ Japanese income
Income of respective country

Revealed preferred to Japanese


bundle
Germany 0.79 1.32
France 0.82 1.27
United States 0.94 1.23
Canada 0.90 1.16
Ambiguous
United Kingdom 1.01 1.09
Italy 1.01 1.03
New Zealand 1.09 1.01
Revealed dis-preferred to
Japanese bundle
Australia 1.09 1.00
Sweden 1.06 1.00
Norway 1.15 0.91
Ireland 1.24 0.86
Israel 1.35 0.85
Switzerland 1.51 0.76

This comparison is based on 26 consumption categories. Two of the categories are government goods and services, those provided
collectively and those provided individually. The 26 categories include all final goods other than investment goods. The prices are
relative to world price and the quantities (volumes) are the corresponding amounts consistent with expenditure.
Source: Constructed by the author using data from: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, Purchasing
Power Parities and the Size of World Economies, Results of the 2017 International Comparison Program, 2020.

continued and expanded this international com- bundle over that of the Japanese. The representa-
parison project to include 176 countries in 2017.4 tive Japanese citizen had a revealed preference for
Some of the data from the World Bank study is their bundle over that of the representative citizen
depicted in Table 1.2. from Australia, Sweden, Norway, Ireland, Israel, or
In 2017, the representative Japanese could have Switzerland. But the representative Japanese did
purchased the consumption bundle of the UK, not reveal a preference for their bundle over that
Italy, New Zealand, Australia, Sweden, Norway, of the Briton, Italian, or New Zealander; nor vice
Ireland, Israel, or Switzerland, but not that of Ger- versa.
many, France the USA, or Canada. (For instance, It could have happened that this procedure
the value of the US bundle at Japanese prices was would have produced the startling conclusion that
1.23 times that of the Japanese bundle.) But nei- the representative citizens of two countries each
ther could the representative citizen of the UK, had a revealed preference for their own chosen
Italy, or New Zealand have purchased the con-
sumption bundle of the Japanese. The represen-
tative citizen of Germany, France, the USA, or Gross Product, Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University
Press, 1982; and UN and Commission of the European Com-
Canada could have purchased the Japanese bun- munities, World Comparison of Purchasing Power and Real
dle. (For instance, at US prices the value of the Product for 1980 (Phase IV of the International Comparison
Project), Part One: Summary Results for 60 Countries, 1986, and
Japanese bundle was 94% the value of the US Part Two: Detailed Results for 60 Countries, 1987.
one.) From this we conclude that the represen- 4
International Bank for Reconstruction and Develop-
tative citizens of the Germany, France, the USA, ment/The World Bank, Purchasing Power Parities and the Size of
World Economies, Results of the 2017 International Comparison
and Canada each had a revealed preference for his Program, 2020.

17
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today
bundle over that of the other. This would indicate in shared spaces outside the home for social activ-
a difference in tastes. In fact, international com- ities at home—the Japanese would feel the pinch
parisons of this sort have found little evidence of of land scarcity far more than they do.
taste differences between any pairs of countries. Many cultural differences between the Japanese
way of daily life and that of Americans and oth-
ers are merely time-honored ways of adapting to
The index number problem
persistent scarcity of land and other goods, and
The ambiguous comparisons (in 2017) for Japan are not, as it might superficially appear, the re-
and the UK, Japan and Italy, and Japan and New sult of fundamental differences in preferences.5 For
Zealand reflect what is called the index number instance, many Japanese sleep on futons that are
problem. This is the problem or impossibility of folded and put away each morning, rather than
constructing a single statistic or index, based only on beds that permanently occupy space. The fu-
on the quantities and prices of the goods, that tons allow the same space that is used for sleeping
will in all cases correctly rank consumption bun- at night to be used for other activities during the
dles in order of preference. That the representative day. The traditional diet, which derives protein
Japanese cannot have purchased the British bun- from soybeans, fish, or sea products, is a natu-
dle does not allow us to infer whether they prefer ral adaptation to the scarcity of red meat in a
the British bundle or their own. mountainous island nation with little pastureland.
Too much has been made of the fact that exactly The beautiful but compact Japanese garden and
duplicating American standards of suburban living miniature bonsai afford a touch of nature but with-
in Japan is beyond the means of all but the very out occupying much space. The ubiquitous coffee
wealthiest Japanese. For it may well be the case shops and small bars and restaurants enable social
that the reverse is also true: exactly duplicating the activities to use shared public spaces, further econ-
Japanese bundle while in the USA may be beyond omizing on scarce land. All the cultural items just
the means of most Americans. In each country mentioned, and perhaps others as well, are exam-
some items are relatively scarcer than in the other ples of substitution in response to relative scarcity.
country. In Japan, compared with the USA and For instance, Susan Hanley even goes so far as to
other countries, consumption activities that use suggest that the ubiquity in Japan of multigen-
land tend to be relatively scarce. On the other erational living arrangements and relatively small
hand, items of consumption that are relatively less family sizes are further adaptations to the scarcity
scarce (can be obtained at lower real marginal cost) of space.6
in Japan than elsewhere include public health and
safety, public order, and national defense.
Nonmarket goods
Substitution
Comparison of the Japanese consumption bun-
Scarcity of some goods relative to others can be off- dle with those of other countries based on na-
set in inventive ways. In Japan, land is scarce and tional income and product accounts encompasses
expensive, but the Japanese economize by living in only market goods, including those purchased
smaller dwellings than they would if land were less by governments. Many important contributors
scarce, and by keeping smaller stocks of food and to economic well-being are omitted in such a
daily necessities but making more frequent shop-
ping trips. Further economies are achieved by con- 5
For a formal statement of this view of culture, see Gary
ducting social activities in shared spaces outside Becker and George Stigler, “De Gustibus Est Non Disputan-
dum,” American Economic Review, vol. 67, no. 2 (March1977),
the home, either at eating and drinking establish- 76–90.
ments or the workplace. If it were not for these 6
Susan B. Hanley, “Traditional Housing and Unique
substitutions, both in production—substitution of Lifestyles: The Unintended Outcomes of Japan’s Land Pol-
icy,” in John O. Haley and Kozo Yamamura (eds.), Land Issues
shopping time for household storage space—and in Japan: A Policy Failure? Society for Japanese Studies, 1992,
in consumption—substitution of social activities 195–222.

18
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today
comparison. These are nonmarket goods, goods Shadow prices of nonmarket goods
that are enjoyed but not bought and sold. Though
Nonmarket goods are traded only in an indirect
such goods are not traded directly, actions can re-
or roundabout fashion, so their prices too, can
sult in their diminution and augmentation and
only be observed indirectly. These “shadow prices”
the goods are in that sense objects of choice. The
equal the marginal values that optimizing individ-
most important nonmarket goods are household
uals place on the nonmarket goods.
production, leisure, and amenities.
Home production is gauged to economize on the
household resources. One decides to clean or shop
Household production
for oneself or one’s family on consideration of the
“Household production” refers to goods produced
price of paying someone else to do it. The principle
and consumed within the household. These in-
cost of home production is forgone leisure, which
clude preparation of meals at home, child-rearing,
is itself a nonmarket good.
care of aged parents at home, cleaning one’s own
Leisure itself may be had only at the sacrifice of
house, shopping, and so on. Notice that only
other goods. More leisure taken means less of other
goods consumed at home as well as produced
goods are produced. The shadow price of leisure is
there are nonmarket goods. Commuting to work is
the value of output lost when an increment of la-
among the productive activities of households but
bor is withheld either from home production or
it does not directly result in consumption. Com-
from outside employment7 —what economists call
muting to work is an intermediate good rather
the value of marginal product of labor. In the compet-
than a final one. The other examples of house-
itive economy, the wage rate also equals the value
hold production just mentioned are final goods,
of marginal product of labor. For this reason, the
but they are nonmarket goods. They are not traded
shadow price of leisure and of home production
directly and are not included in GNP in any way,
can be approximated by wage rates.
a significant omission.
Amenities would seem to entail no choice and
thus command no price in any meaningful sense.
Amenities
What is the price of a beautiful day? But in fact,
“Amenities” are present in the environment and
even beautiful days do have a price. Some ge-
are not the result of human artifice. These are sun-
ographic regions have more sunshine than oth-
shine, beautiful scenery, clean air, and the like.
ers. As the pursuit of sunshine congests those ar-
There is a growing awareness that human actions
eas, the price of land there is bid up, and wages
are eroding amenities. The process of urbaniza-
driven down. Migration will cease only when the
tion and industrialization converts natural areas
marginal individual finds all places to live and
into displeasing zones of pollution. Amenities are
their attendant employment opportunities equally
scarce goods. Their presence contributes to eco-
agreeable, given the land prices and wages. The
nomic well-being and their diminution erodes it.
places with more amenities will come to have
But they are nonmarket goods, neither produced
higher land prices and lower wages than those
nor traded directly and not counted as income in
lacking amenities. From these compensating dif-
the national income and product accounts. Envi-
ferentials in land prices and wages, one can infer
ronmental damage reduces economic well-being
but does not reduce the GDP.
7
Allocation of time across household production, leisure,
Leisure and market work is indeed affected by the marginal wage
rate. In the mid-1990s the Japanese government reduced the
“Leisure” is idleness from economic pursuits. threshold for number of hours worked beyond which pre-
Leisure is valued just as commodities and services mium over-time compensation would have to be paid. This
induced a reduction in working hours per week, which was
are. One may have more commodities and less largely accompanied by an increase in leisure by both men
leisure and consider oneself worse off than be- and women and an increase in time devoted to household
fore. The national income and product accounts production by men and a decrease by women. Jungmin Lee,
Daiji Kawaguchi, and Daniel S. Hamermesh, “Aggregate Im-
measure the economic value of commodities and pacts of a Gift of Time,” American Economic Review Papers &
services only, not leisure. Proceedings, 102 (3), 2012, 612–616.

19
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today
the marginal values that individuals place on the amenity value of around ¥75,000 per month more
amenities. These represent the hypothetical prices than the cities with the lowest amenity values.
that people would be willing to pay if amenities
could be augmented so that there were fewer rainy Comparing the value of nonmarket goods in Japan
days or cleaner air. Using this method, Blomquist, and the United States
Berger, and Hoehn found that in the United States, Much of what has been written about the qual-
the 1980 shadow price of reducing average humid- ity of life in Japan compared with other countries
ity by 1% was $43 per year, of increasing sunshine amounts to an enumeration of nonmarket goods
by 1% was $48 per year, of being on a coastline in Japan and elsewhere.13 Such lists are informa-
was $468 a year, and so on.8 Akai and Ohtake ap- tive but difficult to incorporate into systematic
plied a similar method to calculate shadow prices evaluations of overall economic well-being. For
revealed by the 1985 variation in house rents and this it is necessary to construct shadow prices of
wages across Japanese cities with populations ex- the nonmarket goods. There were two early at-
ceeding 100,000 persons. They found that varia- tempts to estimate the contribution of nonmarket
tion in life expectancy at birth explained much goods to economic well-being in the USA based on
of the variation in house rents and wages. An in- shadow prices: one by Nordhaus and Tobin,14 and
crease in life expectancy at birth of about 6 months the other by Eisner.15
had a shadow price of ¥434,000 per month (at Nordhaus and Tobin proposed adjustments to
the time, 1985, equivalent to around $2000 per the national income and product accounts to re-
month).9 The Akai and Ohtake association of life flect the economic value of nonmarket goods.
expectancy with environmental amenity comports These adjustments include an imputation of the
with the finding of Muller that ambient air pol- value of household services, the value of leisure,
lution has had a large effect on mortality across the opportunity costs of educating students, and
the United States.10 As air quality has improved, changes in the value of environmental amenities
premature deaths in the US associated with am- (which they inferred as the difference in wage
bient air pollution (mostly among the elderly)
have fallen from 435,000 in 1957 to 108,000 in
2016—a hugely valuable contribution to American 8
Glenn C. Blomquist, Mark C. Berger, and John Hoehn,
economic well-being not reflected in the national “New Estimates of Quality of Life in Urban Areas,” American
accounts. Economic Review, vol. 88 (March 1988), 89–107.
9
The shadow prices of environmental amenities, Akai Nobuo and Ohtake Fumio, “Chiikikan kankyō
kakusa no jisshō bunseki (Empirical analysis on regional dis-
once inferred, can be used to compute the dif- parities of environment),” Nihon Keizai Kenkyū (Economic
ference in values of environmental amenities be- Journal of Japanese Center of Economic Research), Vol. 30,
1995, 94–137.
tween cities. Blomquist et al. found a $5,146 per 10
Nicholas Z. Muller, “Long-Run Environmental Account-
year11 difference in amenity value between the ing in the US Economy,” NBER Chapters, in: Environmental
American city with the highest amenity value and Energy Policy and the Economy, volume 1, 2019, 158–191,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
(Pueblo, Colorado) and the one with the lowest 11
The $5,146 per year amounted to 31% of 1980 GNP per
(St Louis, Missouri). Akai and Ohtake found even person = $16,700.
12
wider variation in amenity values across Japanese The ¥750,000 per month corresponds to about 3.9 times
the 1985 GNP per person (= ¥2.303-million).
cities. At the top end, with the prefectures in which 13
See e.g. Naomi Maruo, “The Levels of Living and Welfare
the cities lie shown in parentheses, Yonago (Tot- in Japan Reexamined,” Japanese Economic Studies, vol. 8, no.
tori), Hirosaki (Aomori), Beppu (Oita), Morioka 1 (Fall 1979), 42–93.
14
William D. Nordhaus and James Tobin, “Is Growth Ob-
(Iwate), Niigata, and Kagoshima had amenity val- solete?” in NBER Fiftieth Anniversary Colloquia Series, Eco-
ues around ¥750,000 per month higher than the nomic Research: Retrospect and Prospect, v, Economic Growth,
New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press, 1972.
cities at the low end, Ashikaga (Tottori), Toyota 15
Robert Eisner, “The Total Income System of Accounts,”
(Aichi), Isesaki (Gunma), and Okazaki (Aichi).12 Survey of Current Business, vol. 65, no. 1 (January 1985),
The cities at the top end of amenity value are out- 24–35. For a critique of Eisner’s analysis, see Richard Rug-
gles, “Review of The Total Incomes System of Accounts by
liers. Tokyo ranked twenty-fifth among the 189 Robert Eisner,” Review of Income and Wealth, series 37, no. 4
cities (in other words in the top eighth) with an (December 1991).

20
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today

Table 1.3. Estimated value of nonmarket goods as a percentage of GNP, Japan, and the USA

USA Japan
Nordhaus and Tobin 1965 Eisner 1981 Kanamori–Muto 1980 Economic Planning Agency 1996

Household production
Household chores 48% 33% 11% 15.20%
Student time 10%
Leisure 101% 28%
Amenities −6% −5%

Sources: William D. Nordhaus and James Tobin, “Is Growth Obsolete?” in NBER Fiftieth Anniversary Colloquia Series, Economic
Research: Retrospect and Prospect, v, Economic Growth, Columbia University Press, 1972; Robert Eisner, “The Total Income System of
Accounts,” Survey of Current Business, vol. 65, no. 1 (January 1985), pp. 24–35; Hisao Kanamori, “Japanese Economic Growth and and
Economic Welfare,” in Sheigeto Tsuru, (ed.), Growth and Resources Problems Related to Japan, New York: St Martin’s Press, 1980
(updated to 1980 by Hiromichi Muto et al., “Nihon no keizai seicho to fukushi,” in Futo et al., Sofutoka to GNP tokei: sofutonomikusu
shirizu, vol. 2, Tokyo: Okurasho,1985); Economic Planning Agency, ‘Monetary Valuation of Economic Welfare,’ in Shigeto Tsuru, (ed.),
Growth and Resources Problems Related to Japan, New York: St Martin’s Press, 1980 (updated to 1980 by Hiromichi Muto et al., ‘Nihon
no keizai seichō to fukushi,’ in Futo et al., Sofutoka to GNP tokei: sofutonomikusu shirizu, vol. 2, Tokyo: Okurasho, Unpaid Work in
1996,” May 21, 1998. English version here: http://www5.cao.go.jp/98/g/19981105g-unpaid-e.html.

rates between urban and rural places). Their adjust- of leisure each week than do American men and
ment for annual degradation of the environment women.
amounted to 6% of the GNP in 1965. They also Second, household production may in some
proposed elimination of the US defense budget ways be more significant in Japan. A relatively large
from the national product on the grounds that fraction of Japanese women who participate in the
it represents procurement of intermediate goods labor force are employed in small family businesses
only. that are often complementary with home produc-
Eisner proposed a different set of adjustments tion. A further indication of significant home pro-
from those of Nordhaus and Tobin but in the same duction is the larger percentage of the aged cared
general spirit. Eisner made no adjustment for the for at home by their grown children. In Japan, as
eroding value of amenities. He did impute an op- in the USA, payments to retirement homes add to
portunity cost to student education and household the national income as reported in the national
work. Eisner treated the defense budget as only income and product accounts, but care for the
partly intermediate. aged at home is a nonmarket good and is not re-
Similar adjustments for Japan to the Nordhaus– flected. This omission is more serious for Japan
Tobin and Eisner ones for the USA, constructed by than for the USA or other countries. Despite this,
Kanamori and Muto, yielded quantitatively simi- the estimate of value of household production in
lar additions to the estimated national income as Japan produced by Kanamori and Muto is less than
shown in Table 1.3. Some differences may never- that for the USA produced by Nordhaus and Tobin
theless be worth noting. First, the Japanese have and by Eisner. One reason is that Muto adopted
apparently enjoyed fewer leisure hours. Leisure is a much less expansive definition of household
a normal good. As people become wealthier, they production. Muto considered only full-time house-
demand more of it. Over the decades, the average wives as performing any household production,
work week has gradually shrunk in all the devel- whereas Eisner and Nordhaus and Tobin counted
oped economies, more in the USA than elsewhere. all time devoted to household production activ-
In Japan, until recently, the typical work week still ities by all persons in the economy, including
included Saturday morning. Data on the allocation those who are employed, or are unmarried, and
of time across countries is reported in Table 1.4. It is of all ages and both sexes. The EPA estimates in-
apparent from the figures in the table that Japanese cluded household production by men in Japan.
men and women both enjoy about one hour less Notice in Table 1.4 the dramatic imbalance of

21
Incomes and Welfare of the Japanese Today

Table 1.4 Hours per week devoted to various activities by men and women in Japan and other countries, 1999–2006

(Units=hours per week)


Japan U.S.A. Canada Germany France U.K.

Male Work and Studies 49.1 47.4 46.6 36.1 40.8 41.6
Job and travel as part of 35.5 30.2 30.9 17.6 22.1 22.8
or during job
Studies 4.0 1.9 2.1 2.4 2.2 2.5
Commuting to and 2.5 n.a. −1.7 1.5 1.4 1.8
from work or studies
Housework and family 7.2 15.3 15.3 14.7 15.1 14.6
member care
Leisure 118.9 120.6 121.4 131.9 127.2 126.4
Sleep 56.2 58.4 56.8 57.6 59.9 58.3
Meals and other 17.5 10.8 16.1 16.1 21.0 14.4
personal care
Volunteer activities 0.3 1.3 1.3 1.1 1.1 0.6
Watching TV 15.7 17.4 14.8 14.1 14.8 16.8
Travel (not commuting 6.0 n.a. n.a. 7.4 5.6 7.1
and not job-related)
Other 8.8 6.4 10.1 8.7 8.6 9.0
Total 168.0 168.0 168.0 168.0 168.0 168.0

Female Work and Studies 49.7 48.1 47.0 36.9 42.7 38.6
Job and travel as part of 16.7 21.1 21.4 9.4 10.9 10.9
or during job
Studies 3.4 2.2 2.5 2.2 2.1 2.5
Commuting to and 1.1 n.a. −1.3 0.8 0.9 1.0
from work or studies
Housework and family 28.6 24.8 24.4 24.5 28.8 24.3
member care
Leisure 118.3 119.9 121.0 131.1 125.3 129.4
Sleep 52.8 58.9 57.7 58.1 63.7 58.8
Meals and other 21.5 14.5 16.9 16.9 21.1 15.3
personal care
Volunteer activities 0.3 1.5 1.7 1.0 0.8 0.8
Watching TV 15.3 15.5 10.8 10.2 14.1 15.2
Travel (not commuting 6.3 n.a. n.a. 7.4 2.7 7.5
and not job-related)
Other 6.1 9.2 7.3 8.8 8.6 12.0
Total 168.0 168.0 168.0 168.0 168.0 168.0
Survey Date 2006.10 2006.1 2005.1 2001.4 1998.2 2000.6
~2006.12 ~2005.12 ~2002.4 ~1999.2 ~2001.9
Age of tabulated 10 years 15 years 15 years 10 years 15 years 10 years old
old and old and old and old and old and and over
over over over over over

Source. Govt of Japan, Statistics Bureau, 2006 Survey on Time Use and Leisure Activities, Summary of Results, Questionnaire B, Table 1,
p. 24. http://www.stat.go.jp/english/data/shakai/2006/k-gaiyou.htm
(Primary sources: Japan:“2006 Survey on Time Use and Leisure Activities Volume 8“; Korea: Korea National Statistical Office, “2004
Report on the Time Use Survey“; U.S.A.: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), “News-American Time Use Survey-2006 Results”; Canada:
Statistics Canada,” Overview of the Time Use of Canadians 2005”; EU: EUROSTAT,” Comparable time use statistics-National tables from
10 European countries-February 2005.”)

22
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
smoke candle, certain of the smoke grenades and in various forms
of colored smokes. The basis of this was the Berger Mixture, which
had the composition:
Zinc 25
Carbon tetrachloride 50
Zinc oxide 20
Kieselguhr 5
This formula produced a light gray carbon smoke, with much
carbon in the residue. In this mixture the zinc and carbon
tetrachloride react to form zinc chloride and carbon; the kieselguhr
keeps the mixture solid by absorbing the tetrachloride, while the zinc
oxide is practically useless, as its absorbing power is small.
In order to accelerate the reaction and to oxidize the carbon,
thereby changing the color of the smoke from gray to white, an
oxidizing agent was added. Sodium chlorate was chosen for
economic reasons. The reaction now proved to be too violent, and
the zinc oxide was replaced by ammonium chloride. This cooled the
smoke, retarded the rate of burning and added to the density of the
smoke, since the obscuring power of the ammonium chloride is high.
The kieselguhr was replaced by precipitated magnesium carbonate,
which is as good an absorbent, gives a much smoother burning
mixture, and also adds somewhat to the density of the smoke by
virtue of the magnesium mechanically expelled. The mixture then
had the composition:
Zinc 34.6
Carbon tetrachloride 40.8
Sodium chlorate 9.3
Ammonium chloride 7.0
Magnesium carbonate 8.3

Size of Smoke Particles


In the problem of smoke production, the size of the particle is of
great importance. Being a physical quantity it can easily be
correlated with such physical properties as settling, diffusion,
coagulation, and evaporation. These factors are more important in
connection with toxic smokes, since there the penetration factor
must be considered.
Smoke appears to consist of particles of all sizes from 10⁻³ cm.,
which may just be resolved by the unaided eye, to molecular
dimensions, 10⁻⁸ cm. The larger particles settle out most rapidly and
so do not remain long in suspension.

Measurement
Wells and Gerke have developed a form of ultra-microscope
which is well adapted to the measurement of the size of smoke
particles. The ultra-microscope is a low power microscope using
intense dark ground illumination for viewing particles which are too
small to be seen by transmitted light. They are rendered visible in
this way, since any object, no matter how small, which emits enough
light to affect the retina is visible, provided the background is
sufficiently dark. Thus stars are visible at night and dust particles are
easily seen in a sunbeam in a darkened room. The larger particles,
viewed in this way, do not appear larger but brighter. The apparent
size of the particles is determined by the diffraction pattern and is
thus dependent only on the optical system used to view them. The
more intense the incident light, the brighter the particles appear. In
the ultra-microscope described, the image of an intense source,
such as a concentrated filament lamp, or an arc, is focused upon the
particles in the microscopic field, but the axis of the illuminating
beam, instead of coinciding with the axis of the microscope, as
ordinarily used, is perpendicular to it. The beam itself, therefore,
never enters the microscope at all, but passes under the objective
into a blackened chamber where it is absorbed. The field of the
microscope is made dark by placing underneath the objective
another “black hole” or blackened chamber with an opening just a
little larger than the field.[34]
The method used for measuring the velocity consisted in causing
the particle to describe a definite stroke many times in succession in
an electric field. This was accomplished by reversing the direction of
the field with a rotating commutator. The convection due to the
source of light is perpendicular to this motion so that a zigzag line is
obtained (see Fig. 88). The amplitude of this oscillation is an
accurate measure of the distance traversed by the particle under the
electric force for a definite small interval of time. The speed of the
rotating commutator and the electric field are both susceptible of
precise measurement, so that the size of a single particle is precisely
determined.

Fig. 87.—Ultramicroscope for Measuring Size of


Smoke Particles.
Fig. 88.—Measurement of Smoke Particles by Use
of Ultramicroscope.

When a sample of smoke is viewed in the ultra-microscope, it


appears like the starry heavens, except that the stars are dancing
violently about. At first little distinction is made between the particles,
as there seems to be no order in their motion, but soon it becomes
evident that the brighter particles are more sluggish than the dim
ones. This is due to the greater mass of the bright particles, for they
are larger. The particles are all moving slowly away from the source
of light and eventually diffuse to the walls of the cell.
When the electric field is turned on, about one-third of the
particles immediately migrate, about equally in both directions, to the
two electrodes. If the field is reversed, the direction of migration is
reversed and if the commutator is used the particles oscillate
regularly. Sometimes the particles may be seen to combine and
become neutral, in which case oscillation ceases.

Concentration of Smoke
In measuring the concentration of smokes, the following terms
are useful:
Density. The density of a smoke is defined as the reciprocal of
the thickness of the smoke layer in feet necessary to obscure a
given filament. Thus six inches of a smoke of density 2.0 is required
to obscure an electric light filament, whereas one requiring four feet
would have a density of 4. Another way to show the significance of
this definition is to point out that if a definite weight of a stable smoke
is diluted with air after it is formed, the product of the volume by the
density always remains constant. Any marked variation in this rule
may be taken as evidence that the particles of smoke are
undergoing a change, in most cases due to evaporation.
Total Obscuring Power. The volume of smoke produced per unit
weight of material used is the second factor in determining the value
of a smoke. The product of this volume per unit weight by the density
of the smoke is the real measure of effectiveness, and is called the
total obscuring power (T. O. P.) of the smoke. If the volume is
expressed in cubic feet per pound and the density in reciprocal feet,
the unit of T. O. P. is square feet per pound. That is, it expresses the
square feet of a smoke wall, thick enough to completely obscure a
light filament behind it, which could be produced from a pound of the
reacting substances. The total obscuring power of some typical
smokes are as follows:
Phosphorus 4600
NH₄Cl(NH₃ + HCl) 2500
SnCl₄ + NH₃ + H₂O 1590
Berger Mixture 1250
SnCl₄ + NH₃ 900
SO₂ + NH₃ 375
In all measurements of density, and therefore of T. O. P., the rate
of burning must be considered. If a slow burning material be
compared with a rapid one, the former will not reach its true
maximum density, as a great deal of the smoke may settle out during
the time of burning. Comparisons of T. O. P. are significant only
when made on smoke mixtures of the same type and in about the
same quantities.

Measurement
Two methods of measuring the effectiveness of a smoke cloud
have been devised, one, the smoke box, which measures the
obscuring power directly by observing at what distance a lamp
filament is obscured by intervening smoke, the other, the Tyndall
meter, which measures the intensity of the scattering of the light.
The earliest measurements of smoke intensity are perhaps those
of Ringelmann (Revue Technique, 19, 286), who devised the well
known chart of that name, intended mainly for measuring intensities
of black smoke issuing from a chimney at a distance. The first
measurements for military purposes are probably due to Bertrand,
who made numerous comparative studies with his “salle
opacimetrique.” This was a room 23 × 14 × 3.6 meters, with 7
windows. Two doors, one provided with 3 oculars 2 cm. in diameter,
gave access to the room. On the other door, opposite the first, were
hung several black signs. Six pairs of columns were spaced along
the room at measured distances. When a smoke is produced in the
room, the black paper signs first become invisible, then the door
itself, and finally the columns, pair by pair. They reappear in the
reverse order, and as a measure of relative opacity Bertrand took the
time elapsing between the detonation and the reappearance of the
farther door.
Fig. 89.—Tyndall Meter.
Fig. 90.—Cottrell Precipitation Tube.

Smoke Box. The smoke box, used by the C. W. S., was


constructed of wood with tight joints, and had a moveable brass rod
running through it to which was attached a small size 25-Watt Mazda
lamp. The density of each smoke introduced in the box is determined
by moving this lamp back and forth until a point is reached when the
pattern of the filament can just be distinguished by the observer
looking in at the glass window, external light being excluded by a
black cloth. The thickness of the smoke layer between the glass
window and the light is recorded as the measure of the smoke
density. For field tests, a larger box, 6 × 8 × 8 feet (288 cubic feet)
was constructed. The observation light was moveable in a line
connecting the mid-points of opposite sides of the box. To insure
uniform distribution of smoke, a fan with 18-inch blade revolved at
any desired speed between 60 and 250 r.p.m. With this, results are
obtained indicating both the original density and its stability.
Tyndall Meter. The Tyndall meter was first devised for studying
smokes and mists. Tolman and Vliet adapted it to Chemical Warfare
purposes, and used it in studying the properties of smokes.
The apparatus (Fig. 89) consists eventually of an electric light
bulb, a condensing lens giving a beam of parallel light which passes
through the diaphragm, and a Macbeth illuminometer for measuring
the strength of the Tyndall beam. In case the material is a liquid
suspension or solution, it is introduced into a cylindrical glass tube,
while smokes and mists are premixed directly through the apparatus.
The long closed tubes are provided, respectively, for absorbing the
beam after it has passed through the disperse system and for giving
a dark background for observing the Tyndall beam. Methods of
standardization are given in the Journal of the American Chemical
Society, 41, 299.
A third method for analyzing smokes consists in the use of an
electrical precipitator. This apparatus consists essentially of a
modified Cottrell Precipitator, with a central wire as cathode
surrounded by a cylindrical foil as anode (Fig. 90). The smoke to be
analyzed is drawn through the apparatus at a known rate, and the
particles of smoke precipitated on the foil by means of a high
voltage, direct current. The determination of concentration is made
by weighing the foil before and after precipitation.

Apparatus for Smoke Production

Smoke Box

The smoke box was developed for the Navy for use when it was
desirable to have the smoke screen generated away from the ship.
(The smoke funnel, described later, was operated on board ship).
The float consists of an iron container (holding the smoke mixture)
surrounded by an iron float to support the apparatus when it is
thrown into the water (Fig. 91). The iron container consists of a
cylinder 22 inches high and 10 inches in diameter. One inch holes
are bored 1½ inches from the top of this cylinder, from which the
smoke is emitted. The iron float is about 2 feet in diameter and 8
inches deep. This box holds approximately 100 pounds of smoke
mixture, and is so constructed that it will float one hour. When
ignited, the mixture burns 9 to 9½ minutes. The smoke produced has
a T. O. P. of about 1900. Fig. 92 shows the Navy Smoke Box in
action.
Fig. 91.—Navy Smoke Box.
Fig. 92.—Navy Smoke Box in Action.

Smoke Candle

Smoke candles are used for producing a cloud of smoke for


screening purposes in or behind the lines. They are made by
packing about three pounds of the modified Berger Mixture in a
container (Fig. 93) (galvanized can 5¼ inches by 3½ inches) and are
lighted by means of the match head type of ignition. Smoke is given
off at a uniform rate for about 4 minutes, forming a dense, fog-like
cloud which hangs low (Fig. 94). This smoke is absolutely harmless,
and can be breathed without discomfort. The obscuring power is
high and, with a favorable wind, a small number of the candles will
produce a screen sufficiently dense to allow operations to be carried
out unseen by the enemy.
Fig. 93.—B. M. Smoke Candle.

Smoke Grenade

The smoke grenade is also designed for use in trench and field
warfare, where it is desired to produce a dense smoke screen. It is
made by packing 340 grams of the standard smoke mixture in an
ordinary light metal gas grenade. Around the top of the grenade are
vents closed by a zinc strip. The ignition is caused by the standard
bouchon when the grenade is thrown. The heat of the reaction burns
through the zinc strip and a dense cloud of smoke is evolved for 45
seconds.
Fig. 94.—Smoke Cloud from B. M. Candle.

Stannic chloride has also been used extensively in hand


grenades, as it gives a very disagreeable cloud of smoke upon
detonation. Due to the high prices and urgent need of tin for other
purposes, silicon tetrachloride was substituted for tin tetrachloride
towards the close of the war. A mixture of silicon tetrachloride and
chloropicrin was also used. This not only gives a very good smoke
cloud, but combines with it the toxic properties of the chloropicrin
cloud.
The method of firing the smoke grenade is the same as that of
any grenade using the same type of bouchon. Usually the grenade is
grasped in the hand for throwing in such a manner that the handle of
the bouchon is under the fingers. The safety clip is pulled out with
the other hand and the grenade is thrown with an overhand motion.
When the grenade leaves the hand, the handle of the bouchon flies
off, allowing the trigger to hit the cap which ignites the fuse.
The white phosphorus combined hand and rifle grenade became
the standard smoke grenade by the end of the war. Stannic chloride
was used to clear out dugouts, but not as a smoke producer.

Stokes’ Smoke Shell

Fig. 95.—Stokes’ Smoke Shell.

The Stokes’ smoke shell was perfected to furnish a means of


maintaining the best possible smoke screen at long ranges by
means of an easily portable gun. The 3-inch Stokes shell, as
adapted for combustion smokes, weighs about 13 pounds and
contains about 4 pounds of standard smoke mixture. This shell is
designed to produce a continuous screen over a period of 3 to 4
minutes.

Livens Smoke Drum


The Livens smoke drum was designed for use with the 8-inch
Livens projector, so as to produce a smoke screen of large volume
and long duration at long ranges. The drum, as adapted for
combustion smokes, weighs 17.5 pounds empty and 49 pounds
loaded. The smoke-gas mixture was specially adapted for use in the
Livens drum.

Fig. 96.—Livens Smoke Bomb.

Smoke mixtures in Livens were never used to any considerable


extent in the war and it is questionable if they ever will be. A Livens
can usually only be fired once before resetting, hence Stokes
mortars are used whenever possible.
Smoke Funnel

The smoke funnel was developed for the production of a white


smoke cloud from the stern of a vessel. The smoke producing
materials are liquid ammonia and silicon tetrachloride, with carbon
dioxide as a compressing medium. This is the most satisfactory
compressing medium, because: (1) The silicon tetrachloride is forced
out at nearly constant pressure. (2) The carbon dioxide is easily
compressed to a liquid and can be handled in this form. Further, it
has a vapor pressure of 800 pounds at 60° F., and a cylinder can be
nearly emptied without loss in efficiency. (3) Carbon dioxide is
sufficiently soluble in silicon tetrachloride to cause the latter to
effervesce and thus materially aid in its evaporation on spraying. (4)
Liquid carbon dioxide, behaving in a manner similar to liquid
ammonia, affords a means for the silicon tetrachloride to “keep pace”
with the ammonia, under changes in temperature, and thus ensures
a more nearly neutral, and therefore the most effective, smoke.

Fig. 97.—Navy Smoke Funnel.


The smoke funnel proper consists of an open end cylinder, about
2 feet in diameter and 7 feet long, mounted in a horizontal position
on an angle iron frame. At one end is an 18-inch fan securely
fastened to the cross supports. This fan is operated by hand, through
gears giving a ratio of about 30 to 1. The silicon tetrachloride enters
the cylinder through a pipe, which terminates in four spray nozzles,
while the ammonia enters through a single nozzle. The air forced
into the funnel serves to hydrolyze the silicon tetrachloride and mixes
the vapors. The resulting reaction evolves a dense white cloud of
very large volume and high obscuring power. One set of cylinders is
capable of maintaining this cloud for over 30 minutes. Under normal
conditions the discharge is at the rate of 2 pounds of silicon
tetrachloride to 1 pound of ammonia. To stop the smoke, the silicon
tetrachloride is closed first, the ammonia allowed to run about half a
minute, and the fan is shut off last.

Fig. 98.—Navy Smoke Funnel in Operation.

Smoke Knapsack
The smoke knapsack furnishes a portable apparatus for smoke
production. The gross weight is about 70 pounds; when in operation
it gives a dense white smoke for about 15 minutes. The operation
may be intermittent or continuous and the quantity of smoke is
sufficient to completely hide one platoon of men in skirmish
formation with a 5-mile per hour enfilade wind. The apparatus
consists of two steel tanks about 26 inches in height and 6 inches in
diameter. From the side of each tank, but near the bottom, extends a
short pipe on which is placed a suitable valve. A flexible armored
hose connects the valve to a short length of pipe which is equipped
with spray nozzle. The cylinders are charged with silicon
tetrachloride and ammonia under pressure. The valves may be
operated with the left hand, while the sprayer apparatus is held in the
right. The release buckles are within easy reach of both hands.

Shell

While many special devices have been developed by means of


which the gas troops and infantry are able to set up smoke clouds on
short notice, the smoke shell, fired by the artillery, always played an
important part in this work. In the same way that a large number of
the poison gases were adapted to artillery use, so were most of the
smoke producing substances.
As a filler for smoke shell, phosphorus easily ranks first, and is
approached only by sulfur trioxide in very humid weather. A rough
approximation to the relative values of some of its rivals is given in
the following table:
White phosphorus 100
Sulfur trioxide 60-75
Stannic chloride 40
Titanium chloride 25-35
Arsenic chloride 10
Comparison of the value of different forms of phosphorus for shell
purposes has invariably pointed to the superiority of the white
variety. Mixtures of white and red (2 to 1) have also proved effective.
A complete barrage over a front of 200 yards can be established
in from 40 seconds to 1 minute and maintained by firing a salvo
followed by battery fire of 3 seconds. Four 4.5-inch howitzers could
maintain an effective barrage over a front of 1000 yards. The
influence of sunshine is very marked, as in moist, cool weather one
shell every 15 seconds is sufficient.

Fig. 99.—Smoke Screen for Tanks.

Screening Tanks
Tests have demonstrated (see Fig. 99) that successful smoke
screens for tanks may be produced by spraying oleum into the
exhaust. On a 7-ton tank of the Renault type (40 H. P.) 110 cc. per
minute produced a large volume of smoke, which had excellent
covering power, and which could be made intermittent or continuous
at will.

You might also like