You are on page 1of 7

A Theory of Social Welfare

L ITTLE ATTENTION has been


directed at the development of a
David Stoesz
theory of social welfare. Most literature A theory ofsocial welfare in the United
analysis is left at the descriptive level.
These deficiencies could be corrected by
a theory that explains how political and
that describes the application of social economic forces shape the institutions of
work theory focuses on social ad-
States is outlined to explain how social welfare over time. Such a theory
ministration and social policy-often political and economic forces shape the should focus on the structure of social
called "macro phenomena." Social ad- stmctural institutions ofsocial welfare. welfare, identify the most influential
ministration theory tends to derive from The theory emphasizes the role of in- groups, and offer some direction on the
sociology and social psychology and terest groups in defining social welfare future of social welfare.
have little relevance for many social and provides an explanation of why
workers (Lipsky, 1980, 1984). Social some groups remain marginal to the
policy on the other hand often is left at welfare enterprise. The interest groups Structural Interests of
the philosophical level. Most attempts to of the social welfare industry are Social Welfare
systematize thinking about social policy classified, and the viability of each Social welfare-a society's provision of
occurred during the 1970s, when group is evaluated according to the social, economic, and health benefits to
elaboration and consolidation of the members who are unable to obtain such
welfare state seemed probable.
dynamics of bureaucratization and pri- benefits by themselves (Barker, 1987)-
As Gil (1976) noted, the basis for vatization. Some predictions about the is manifested by an extraordinarily
understanding social policy consisted of future ofcertain interest groups also are diverse set of institutions in the United
an "underlying humanistic, egalitarian, offered. States. American social welfare includes
democratic philosophy" (p. 166). Using income benefits that are available
a Marxist dialectic, Galper (1975) cri- through insurance and grant programs,
tiqued the liberal basis for the welfare that the significant aspects of social a range of in-kind benefits that include
state but failed to account for the way in welfare can be identified so that the health and mental health care, and
which instruments of capitalism provide system can be enhanced through planned various personal social services. Govern-
beneficial services to the population. change. Although this characteristic has ment departments, voluntary agencies,
Forder (1984) presented an excellent a logical appeal, the extraordinary diver- independent providers, and proprietary
review of social science theories that sity of social welfare in America raises firms coexist and respond to segments
bear on social welfare but fail to present the fundamental question of whether of the social welfare market. American
a synthesis. Progressive expansion of social welfare is systematic. In addition, social welfare is not unlike a large in-
the welfare state led to extensive the political and economic reversals of dustry through which groups exert in-
descriptive explorations of programs the past decade indicate that systemati- fluence to achieve particular objectives.
and services (Kamerman & Kahn, 1976, zation as a general trend is unlikely in When such objectives are self-serving,
1980). Researchers often presented con- the near future. Instead, social welfare groups may be said to have an "in-
cepts as tools for analysis (Dolgoff & seems to be diversifying-if not frag- terest." As interest groups outmaneuver
Feldstein, 1980; Macarov, 1978; Wilen- menting-in a manner that defies the competitors, they develop complex in-
sky & Lebeaux, 1965) and occasionally emphasis on system maintenance that is stitutionallinkages that anchor them in
presented a framework to organize implicit in systems theory. Moreover, the social structure. Eventually,
thinking about social policy (Morris, systems theory does not account for the
1979; Gilbert & Specht, 1986). Yet a for- conservative influences that affect social
mal theory has not followed from these welfare. To the alarm of many profes- the existence of a network of political,
works. Systems theory is the only for- sionals, social welfare is not moving in legal, and economic institutions which
mulation that approaches a theoretical a direction that is compatible with social guarantees that certain dominant interests
level of thought. work values. will be served comes to be taken for
Systems theory became popular dur- Conventional macro theory fails to granted as legitimate, as the only possible
ing the 1970s but was used primarily to provide an adequate account of the con- way in which these ... services can be pro-
vided. People come to accept as inevitable
explain behavior of subsystems that text in which welfare professionals prac- that which exists and even believe that it
comprised individuals, families, and tice or the profound changes that have is a right .... Precisely because of this, the
organizations (Pincus & Minahan, 1973). affected that context. Meyer (1976) has interests involved do not continuously have
Whether systems theory really is a applied a variation of the systems to organize or to defend their interests;
theory in a technical sense, its utility has approach-ecosystems theory-to the other institutions do that for them. (Alford,
diminished. Systems theory assumes context of social work practice. Her 1975, pp. 14, 17)

CCC Code: 0037-8046/89 $1.00 © 1989, National Association of Social Workers, Inc. 101
Groups that become enmeshed inex- Table 1.
tricably in the social structure-to the ex- Classification of Structural Interests in Social Welfare
tent they become manifestations of the
structure-are structural interests. An in- Structure Interest Type Ideology Example
verse conventional interest group theory, Voluntary sector Traditional Repressed Organic bonds Secular and sec·
which assumes that groups have to providers among community tarian nonprofit
scramble for resources, structural in- institutions agencies
terests theory identifies those groups so Welfare state Welfare Dominant Governmental Federal and state
implanted in social reality that their bureaucrats responses to welfare
needs are met virtually automatically. public problems departments
Structural interest groups can be clas- Private practice Clinical Emerging Professional treat- Individual and
entrepreneurs ment of individual group practices
sified into four categories according to disorders
their ability to develop the interinstitu- Corporate welfare Human service Challenging Corporate ex- For-profit health
tionallinkages that result in power and in- executives ploitation of and welfare cor-
fluence: (1) dominant, (2) challenging, (3) human service porations
repressed, and (4) emerging. Alford markets
(1975) proposed the first three types of in-
terests; the author added the fourth,
"emerging," to conform Alford's work in instead, directing future growth is the vice-delivery forms, Charity Organiza-
health care to social welfare. A dominant primary issue. tion Societies and settlement houses
structural interest has consolidated an ex- As implied by the four classifications, were transformed by two influences: (1)
tensive organizational network of person- the evolution of structural interests is a the need for scientifically based treat-
nel and revenues that overshadows other slow process that can consume decades ment techniques on the part of the
structural interests. These manifesta- and the entire careers of professionals workers and (2) the socialization of chari-
tions of dominance are buttressed by an associated with a particular group. In the ty. Together, these factors anchored the
institutional ideology, "an official inter- United States, four structural interests social casework agency in American in-
pretation of the past that makes [other comprise the social welfare industry: dustrial society. The agency provided
organizational arrangements] appear (1) traditional providers (repressed); the grist for scientific casework, which
defective or just a step on the way to the (2) welfare bureaucrats (dominant); was instrumental in the emergence of the
present regime" (Bloom, 1987, p. 249). (3) clinical entrepreneurs (emerging); and social work profession. In turn, the new
A challenging structural interest is (4) human service executives (challeng- schools of social work relied on casework
cultivating a parallel network of organi- ing) (Table 1). agencies for internship training, a
zations large enough to claim some of the substantial part of professional educa-
resources controlled by a dominant tion. After graduation, many profes-
structural interest. This goal can be Traditional Providers sionals elected to work in the voluntary
achieved by demonstrating a superior Traditional providers seek to maintain sector, which ensured a steady supply of
method of service provision, siphoning and enhance traditional social relations, personnel for agencies.
more desirable clients, or simply sway- values, and structures in their com- Voluntary agencies routinized philan-
ing public sentiment in favor of the munities. Traditional providers hold an thropic contributions by socializing chari-
challenging structural interest. A re- organismic conception of social welfare ty. Beginning with Denver's Associated
pressed structural interest previously en- and see it as tightly interwoven with Charities in 1887, the concept of a com-
joyed a dominant status but has been other community institutions. According munity appeal spread until more than 200
demoted by a challenging interest. Once to traditional providers, voluntary non- cities had community chests by the 1920s
a dominant structural interest becomes profit agencies offer the advantages of (Trattner, 1974). Together, the needs of
repressed, it is not likely to regain the neighborliness, a reaffirmation of com- workers for effective treatment tech-
previous position; rather, other groups munity values, a concern for community niques and the economic imperatives for
will bypass it as they seek to establish welfare as opposed to personal gain, and organizational survival functioned to
claims in the field. However, because of freedom to alter programming to con- standardize the social agency. The
the remnants of the institutional network form to changes in local priorities. The casework agency was the organization
that repressed structural interests retain, base of influence consists of private, non- through which professional caseworkers
repression usually means a residual posi- profit agencies, often referred to as the delivered services (National Association
tion in the industry and not outright ex- voluntary sector. of Social Workers [NASW], 1974). By the
tinction. An emerging structural interest Much of the heritage of social welfare 1940s, the social casework agency had
is organizing a network that may can be traced to this structural interest- become a predominant form of service
challenge a dominant interest some time for example, Mary Richmond with the delivery. Currently, much social service
in the future. To attain emerging status, Charity Organization Society movement provision exists in the form of sectarian
a structural interest must be organized and Jane Addams with the Settlement and nonsectarian agencies of the volun-
sufficiently that survival is not a concern; House movement. As predominant ser- tary sector. In 1984, approximately
102 Social Work / March 1989
130,000 organizations spent $21.4 billion linear evolution connecting these struc- private sector solutions to welfare-
providing individual and family counsel- tural interests could have occurred had related problems (Reich, 1983). Still, the
ing, job training, child day care, residen- not Harry Hopkins, the head of the volume of resources and number of per-
tial services, and other social services Federal Emergency Relief Administra- sonnel that depend on public sector
(Hodgkinson & Weitzman, 1986). These tion, prohibited states from turning welfare programs ensure welfare bu-
organizations include the traditional federal welfare funds over to private reaucrats of a dominant role in social
agencies of the voluntary sector-Family agencies (Trattner, 1974, 1985). Denied welfare for the near future.
Service America, the Red Cross, and the the resources to address the massive
Boy and Girl Scouts of America-as well social problems caused by the Great
as newer, more advocacy-oriented ser- Depression, private agencies lapsed in- Clinical Entrepreneurs
vices-gay and lesbian agencies, bat- to a secondary role while federal and Clinical entrepreneurs are professional
tered women's shelters, and programs state agencies ascended in importance. service providers-chiefly social
for refugees and immigrants. An array of welfare legislation fol- workers, psychologists, and physi-
lowed. The flourishing of bureaucratic cians-who work for themselves rather
rationality, concomitant with this than being salaried employees (Piliavin,
Welfare Bureaucrats legislative activity, represented the in- 1968). Important to clinical entrepre-
Welfare bureaucrats are public func- stitutionalization of liberal thought that neurs is the establishment of a profes-
tionaries whose experiments in state-run sought to control the caprices of the sional monopoly. The evolution of that
welfare programs during the Progressive market, to ensure a measure of equality professional monopoly represents a con-
Era were consolidated during the New among widely divergent economic cern of practitioners that their occupa-
Deal, when the federal government classes, and to establish the adminis- tional activity not be subject to political
assumed a leading role in defining the trative apparatus to provide continuity of interference from the state or to the
welfare state. Welfare bureaucrats are these principles. Confronted with a ignorance of the lay public. In the most
civil servants of federal, state, and local rapidly industrializing society that lacked fundamental sense, private practice
jurisdictions who administer the maze of the most basic programs for ameliorating reconciles the desire of professionals for
social insurance, means-tested, and social and economic catastrophe, pro- autonomy with the imperatives of a
federal domestic assistance programs gressives perceived the state as a vehi- market economy. The transition from
(Evans & Robb, 1985, Appendix C). cle for social reform. Solutions focused entrepreneur to professional monopolist
Despite the complexity of mandated on "coordinating fragmented services, is a matter of obtaining legislation that
welfare programs, welfare bureaucrats instituting planning, and extending restricts practice to individuals who are
tend to have a similar orientation to the public funding" (Alford, 1975, p. 2). Im- licensed by the state. According to
provision of social welfare that is rein- plicit in the methods advocated by wel- Alford (1975), "professionalism provides
forced by the vertical integration of the fare bureaucrats is an expectation, if not a way of preserving monopolistic control
welfare bureaucracy: U .S. Department an assumption, that social welfare ad- over services without the risks of com-
of Health and Human Services, state ministration should be centralized, that petition" (p. 199). As an extension of the
human resources departments, and local eligibility for benefits should include all entrepreneurial model of service de-
social welfare departments. The people regardless of income, and that livery, professional monopoly offers
ideology of welfare bureaucrats stresses social welfare should be part of the in- privacy in practice, the freedom to
"a rational, efficient, cost-conscious, stitutional fabric of society. In the United valuate one's worth through setting fees,
coordinated ... delivery system" (Alford, States, Wilensky and Lebeaux (1965) and the security of membership in the
1975, p. 204). Welfare bureaucrats view labeled this orientation to social welfare professional monopoly.
government intervention as more effec- "institutional," meaning that govern- The social worker as clinical entre-
tive than private sector initiatives ment would ensure that citizens would be preneur is a relatively recent pheno-
because authority is centralized, entitled to basic needs as a social right. menon; NASW did not sanction this
guidelines are standardized, and benefits By the mid-1980s, the influence of wel- form of service delivery officially for its
are allocated according to principles of fare bureaucrats had been curtailed. The members until 1964 (Golton, 1973).
equity and equality. Reagan administration all but capped the Before that, privately practicing social
The influence of welfare bureaucrats growth of welfare programs; in 1982, workers identified themselves as psycho-
in social welfare became substantial as a federal governmental expenditures for therapists and lay analysts. Typically,
result of the Social Security Act of 1935. domestic programs peaked at 15.9 per- social workers in private practice relied
To a limited extent, the larger communi- cent of the gross national product, and on referrals from physicians and psychi-
ty chests "exerted a pressure toward ra- that figure has fallen every year since atrists (Golton, 1973), and after World
tionalization of the professional welfare (Advisory Commission on Intergovern- War 11 , began to establish "flourishing
machinery" (Lubove, 1969, p. 197), but mental Relations, 1987; "Up from De- and lucrative" practices (Trattner, 1974,
this pressure did not approximate the ef- pendency," 1986). After election defeats p. 250). By the 1970s, private practice in
fect of the federal welfare bureaucracy, in 1980, 1984, and 1988, many Demo- social work was developing as an impor-
which soon eclipsed the authority of crats equivocated about government tant form of service delivery. In 1975,
traditional providers. Actually, a uni- social programs and instead preferred NASW estimated that from 10,000 to
Stoesz / A Theory of Social WeHare 103
20,000 social workers were engaged in of the market. However, unlike clinical the very markets they serve, thus influ-
private practice (Gabriel, 1977). By 1983, entrepreneurs, human service execu- encing not only consumer demand, but
Barker (1983) speculated that about tives are salaried employees of proprie- also government policy. The capacity to
30,000 social workers, or 32 percent of tary firms and so have less autonomy. As function independently of government
all social workers, engaged in private corporate officers who are accountable coupled with the scale of operations, as
practice on a full- or part-time basis. By to investors, human service executives determined by the large volume of
1985, a large portion of psychotherapy advance an ideology that emphasizes revenues and number of employees,
was being performed by social workers: market strategies for promoting social places human service executives in a
welfare. This approach differs from the strong position to challenge the welfare
Growing numbers of social workers are ideology of welfare bureaucrats, which bureaucrats.
treating more affluent, private clients, thus emphasizes the planning and regulatory
moving into the traditional preserve of the functions of the state. Human service ex-
elite psychiatrists and clinical psycholo- ecutives favor the rationality of the ~argjnalInterests
gists, as well. (Coleman, 1985, p. Cl) marketplace in allocating resources and Social welfare is populated by
evaluating programs and advocate mar- numerous interest groups that have not
Clinical entrepreneurs are an emerg- ket refonn of the welfare state, the do- become as symbiotically attached as
ing structural interest in social welfare. main of welfare bureaucrats, thus structural interests to the social struc-
Continued growth of this group is likely challenging this structural interest. ture. These marginal interest groups
for several reasons. Through local and The entrance of for-profit finns in usually represent special populations
state chapters, NASW has been effective social welfare can be traced to the 1960s, that have been neglected, excluded, or
in expanding the scope of its professional when Medicaid, Medicare, and Civilian oppressed by mainstream society. The
monopoly. In 1983, 31 states had passed Health and Medical Program of the number of these groups reflects the ca-
legislation regulating the practice of U nifonned Services funds were paid to pacity of the American political economy
social work ("Thirty-one Jurisdictions," proprietary nursing homes, hospitals, to maintain equilibrium while excluding
1983); by 1987, the number had in- and mental health facilities (Light, 1986). many groups from full participation in
creased to 45 ("Licensure Act Passed," Since then, human service executives society. A partial list of marginal interest
1987). At the same time, professional rapidly have been creating independent, groups includes black Americans,
groups have lobbied for vendorship for-profit human service corporations women, native Americans, homosexuals,
privileges that allow them more regular that provide an extensive range of ser- residents of rural areas, and Hispanic
income through insurance held by vices nationwide. Human service corpor- Americans. These groups are of great in-
clients. Finally, many students who enter ations have established prominent-if terest to welfare professionals because of
graduate schools do so with the ex- not dominant-positions in several concern for social justice as well as an im-
pressed intent of setting up a private human service markets, including nurs- plicit assumption that welfare would be
practice ("Licensure Act Passed," 1987). ing home care, hospital management, enhanced if marginal interests were well-
Thus, clinical entrepreneurs will become health maintenance, child care, child represented within the social welfare in-
a more influential interest in the future. welfare, home care, life care, and correc- dustry. Unfortunately, the American
tions. In 1981, 34 human service corpora- political economy has contributed to
tions reported annual revenues of more much disparity among groups in social
Human Service Executives than $10 million; by 1985, the number of welfare. Within the context of democratic
Human service executives include the firms had increased to 66 (Stoesz, capitalism, transfonning marginal in-
chief executive officers and management 1988b). In 1985, two human service cor- terests into structural interests remains
personnel of the for-profit human service porations reported annual revenues that extraordinarily difficult.
corporations and franchises that have exceeded the total contributions to the The marginal status of many groups re-
proliferated since the mid-1960s. Promi- United Way of America, $2.6 billion. lates to the nature of the social welfare in-
nent human service executives include Moreover, each of these corporations dustry in the United States (Taylor &
Jack Massey, founder of the largest employed more than 80,000 workers, by Roberts, 1985). In American culture,
human service firm, the Hospital Corpor- far more than the number of state and groups excluded from the mainstream are
ation of America; Tom Beasely, founder local public welfare employees in any expected to gather resources and identirry
(with Massey' s assistance) of the Correc- state in the United States ("Statistical leadership to mount programs to serve the
tions Corporation of America; and Philip Abstract," 1988b). particular group. Although this expecta-
Bredesen, whose health maintenance As the proprietary sector expands to tion is conconant with traditional values,
company, HealthAmerica, was acquired dominate human service markets, oli- such as self-sufficiency and community
by Maxicare, a health maintenancecom- gopolies emerge and a fundamental solidarity, that approach does not ensure
pany founded by Fred Wassennan. change occurs. No longer passively success. The voluntary sector may be able
Human service executives share an dependent on government appropriations, to accommodate only a limited number of
important characteristic with clinical proprietary £inns obtain revenues from in- marginal interests because of financial
entrepreneurs-both are ways of or- dividual consumers and businesses and restraints or may be unresponsive to
ganizing service delivery in the context create a strong base from which to shape groups that violate traditional community
104 Social Work I March 1989
norms. As a result, marginal interest tives. Few students will become exposed Privatization, the use of nongovern-
groups may have to take care of their to agencies that serve marginal popula- mental organizations to provide services,
needs themselves. tions, because those agencies cannot af- has a long history in social welfare in the
In a democratic polity, marginal groups ford the credentialed staff to supervise United States (Abramovitz, 1986; Ben-
can make claims on the social order by interns. New professionals quickly learn dick, 1985; Starr, 1985; Stoesz, 1987). As
seeking benefits through governmental that better-paying jobs are found within Bendick (1985) has observed, this trend
programs, but to do so presents other the structural interests, particularly in is consistent with the American empha-
problems. Government programs are private practice, programs of the welfare sis "on the local, the pluralistic, the
likely to be managed by welfare state, or firms within the corporate voluntary, and the business-like over the
bureaucrats, who have a different welfare sector. In other words, the career national, the universal, the legally en-
understanding of what is best for the path of the typical welfare professional titled, and the governmental" (p. 1).
marginal interest. For a marginal interest leads away from service to marginal in- Before the New Deal, much social wel-
group to get benefits from government terests. Consequently, marginal interests fare was private and provided by agen-
programs, its claim must be interpreted, are less likely to enjoy the representation cies of the voluntary sector. The
programmed, and monitored by agents of of those professionals who could ad- emergency of for-profit health and
the welfare state, who have a welfare vocate effectively on their behalf. Work welfare corporations is, of course, a more
ideology that differs from that of op- with marginal interest groups typically recent example (Stoesz, 1986). With the
pressed groups. The result is likely to be is avocational for welfare professionals growth of health and welfare corpora-
a program that is more consonant with the who find their primary professional ac- tions, however, privatization has taken
ideology of welfare bureaucrats than that tivity within the structural interests of on a new meaning: Privatization has
of the marginal interest group. An attrac- social welfare. become equated with the market econ-
tive solution to this problem is the deploy- omy. Consequently, market reform stra-
ment of a special agency to respond to the tegies of change have emphasized the
needs of marginal interests. Unfortunate- Dynamics of Structural role of private practitioners and human
ly, agencies that are not integrated in the Interests service executives, which operate on a
welfare state proper can be dismantled Two dynamics are central to the for-profit basis and have ignored the
easily, as illustrated by the fate of the Of- viability of structural interests: (1) traditional providers, which do not.
£ice of Economic Opportunity. bureaucratization and (2) privatization. Bureaucratization and privatization in-
Because of these obstacles, members The expansion of civil authority to con- fluence each structural interest different-
of marginal interest groups have power- trol the caprices of industrialization in a ly (Figure 1). In general, human service
ful incentives to work within existing capitalist economy provided the base for executives obtain the most benefit from
structural interests. The success of the welfare bureaucracy that has come bureaucratization and privatization, and
marginal interests in this regard has been to dominate social welfare. The scale of traditional providers have the most to
mixed. As a result of affirmative action, operations implicit in bureaucracy has lose. However, the effect of these forces
black males have been able to secure continued into the postindustrial era, is more complex than this.
positions in the welfare bureaucracy in despite the attempts by liberals to The problem for traditional providers
relatively significant numbers and now dismantle the corporate bureaucracy is to maintain local institutions that sup-
are well established among welfare through antitrust litigation or the at- port community values. In a society in
bureaucrats. White women, however, tempts by conservatives to dismantle the which individuals increasingly are de-
have found independent practice more government bureaucracy through devo- pendent on megastructures of the public
desirable and are represented more lution legislation. Currently, the state and private sectors, this atmosphere is
among clinical entrepreneurs (NASW, bureaucratic apparatus coexists parallel difficult to maintain. At best, national
1985). Despite such changes, the installa- to private sector oligopolies; both types consortia, such as the United Way or sec-
tion of representatives of marginal in- of groups require enormous revenues to tarian associations, offer a symbolic
terests within structural interest has not apply technically sophisticted processes identification but not the vehicle for ac-
resulted in a corresponding increase in to mass populations (Harris, 1981). Ac- cumulating revenues and recruiting per-
the status of their respective group of cordingly, welfare bureaucrats and sonnel that they had provided in the past.
origin, which reflects the power of the human service executives execute stra- Traditional providers have suffered par-
political and economic structure to ap- tegies of bureaucratic reform to further ticularly from budget rescissions exacted
portion opportunity arbitrarily regard- their interests (Alford, 1973). Although by the Reagan administration. Federal
less of who operates the machinery. The human service executives may use other funds to programs in which nonprofit
structural interest of human service ex- terminology for their plans, the plans are agencies have been active (excluding
ecutives remains a bastion of white no less bureaucratic in nature. Human Medicare and Medicaid) were reduced
patriarchy. service executives prefer a rationalized about $26 billion each year, or 25 percent
A subtle, but nonetheless significant, system of service provision, and between 1982 and 1984; yet increased
reason for the subordinate status of bureaucratic reform is a way to realize fundraising efforts compensated for only
marginal interest groups is related to pro- this arrangement, consistent with the 7 percent of this loss (Abramson &
fessional career requirements and incen- second dynamic in social welfare. Salamon, 1986). The interaction of
Stoesz / A Theory of Social Weliare 105
Figure l. choose private practitioners), the client
Dynamics of Structural Interests base for private practitioners will be
eroded seriously. Human services in in-
Scale dustry is a new development, largely
Small Large Privatization limited to Employee Assistance Pro-
Nonprofit Traditional Welfare grams (EAPs). Preliminary studies sug-
providers bureaucrats gest that employers may find industrial
Economy
Clinical Human service human services provided on an in-house
For-profit entrepreneurs executives basis an attractive method for address-
Bureaucratization ing the question of escalating employee
benefit costs (Decker, Starrett, &
Redhouse, 1986; Straussner, 1988). For
privatization and bureaucratization a full-scale "social-industrial complex" this reason, industrial social welfare, the
makes traditional providers particularly under the auspices of the state and monop- provision of welfare directly by an
vulnerable to their competitors in the oly industries. (O'Connor, 1973, p. 54) employer to employees, is particularly
welfare industry, especially the corpora- likely to become a structural interest.
tions managed by human service ex- In the United States, the accumulation of Employees of firms with on-site social
ecutives. To remain viable in a more such accords and the sharing of person- services will find such an arrangement
competitive welfare industry, the volun- nel could evolve into a human service- more convenient than negotiating for
tary sector may have to merge indepen- industrial complex, in which decisions in service with a human service corpora-
dent agencies into oligopolies or establish American welfare are worked out by tion. As major employers seek to reduce
nationwide, centrally controlled fran- welfare bureaucrats and human service the cost of expensive benefit packages by
chises of human service agencies. executives, to the exclusion of other hiring human service workers, employ-
Less vulnerable than traditional pro- groups (Gruber, 1971). ment opportunities will attract profes-
viders by virtue of the bureaucratic For private practitioners, the problem sionals from other structural interests.
leviathan that supports them, bureau- will be to expand their influence without Professional schools will establish
cratic providers are more able to endure flooding the labor market with profes- special curricula and offer certificates in
the trend toward privatization. In re- sionals. In 1975, 2.4 percent of social new specializations-such as, human re-
sponse to cuts in public funds, welfare workers identified private practice as sources management and occupational
bureaucrats may jettison programs, but their primary activity, with 22.6 percent social work-as several schools already
they would prefer to subcontract with the indicating it was secondary employment have done; also, professional associa-
private sector and retain an adminis- (Kelley & Alexander, 1985). In 10 years, tions will publish special journal issues on
trative superstructure that can redeploy this group roughly doubled-7.6 percent industrial social welfare (Hopps, 1988).
frontline workers in the event the public listed private practice as their primary Industrial social welfare already has at-
becomes disenchanted with privatiza- activity, and 40.9 percent as secondary tracted the attention of social policy
tion. For welfare bureaucrats, any other employment (NASW, 1985). Aside from analysts. Under the rationale of "human
structural interest would be a plausible increasing competition among private capital investments," Reich (1983) has
contractee, but human service execu- practitioners for clients, clinical en- suggested using the employer as a source
tives offer a special advantage. Although trepreneurs also must fend off the efforts of a range of social welfare benefits.
traditional providers and private practi- of human service executives to capture Many employers now provide child care
tioners may be reliable contractees, they their clientele through superior as a benefit to employees. Such em-
do not have the scale of organization or marketing. The ability of private practi- ployer-provided benefits make social
the degree of centralization that ensures tioners to do the same is hampered welfare more closely related to produc-
welfare bureaucrats that a large volume because most of their power resides at tivity and may be a preferred method of
of service can be provided in a manner the state level (because states regulate provision for those concerned about the
that is sufficiently accountable. In con- professional practice) and the local level competitiveness of American industry
trast, human service executives can (because of the locality-specific nature of (Stoesz, 1988a).
make this assurance, and this group is private practice). At the national level, Industrial social welfare has indirect
most likely to influence welfare bureau- few professional associations are implications for traditional providers.
crats. As might be expected from the equipped well enough to match the Some employees may question whether
trend toward privatization, the growing power of human service corporations. continuing to support traditional pro-
influence of human service executives, Perhaps the most serious threat to viders in the community is necessary,
compared with welfare bureaucrats, private practitioners, however, is the because many services are provided by
makes likely the negotiation of issues development of industrial human ser- employers. As more and larger em-
that are important to both parties. Such vices. If this group convinces public and ployers develop employee assistance
a development would be consistent with private employers to provide welfare ser- programs, employers will have less
British observers (Gough, 1979; O'Con- vices in-house rather than through in- justification to make corporate contribu-
nor, 1973) who envision surance (which allows employees to tions to traditional providers out of some
106 Social Work / March 1989
sense that the employer will benefit in- Craib, I. (1984). Modern social theory. New Winston.
directly when employees obtain services York: St. Martin's. Meyer, C. (1976). Social work practice. New
from them. Eventually, corporate con- Decker, ]. T., Starrett, R., & Redhorse, J. York: Free Press.
tributions to philanthropic organizations (1986). Evaluating the cost-effectiveness of Morris, R. (1979). Social policy ofthe American
may decline (Kristol, 1982). As a conse- employee assistance programs. Social welfare state. New York: Harper & Row.
Wor~31, 391-393. National Association of Social Workers.
quence of dynamics of structural inter- Dolgoff, R., & Feldstein, D. (1980). (1974). Social casework: Generic and specific.
ests, industrial social welfare promises to Understanding social welfare. New York: Washington, DC: Author.
expand, probably at the expense of tradi- Harper & Row. National Association of Social Workers.
tional providers and private practitioners. Evans, D., & Robb, C. (Chairs.). (1985). To (1985). NASW data bank. Silver Spring,
The theory of social welfare provides form a more perjectunion. Washington, DC: MD: Author.
a preliminary orientation to the context National Conference on Social Welfare. O'Connor, ]. (1973). The fiscal crisis of the
of social welfare in the United States. As Forder, A., et al. (1984). Theories of welfare. state. New York: St. Martin's.
a structural theory, it emphasizes the role London, England: Routledge & Kegan Piliavin, I. (1968). Restructuring the provision
of interest groups in defining social Paul. of social services. Social Work, 13, 34-42.
welfare and provides an explanation of Gabriel, E. (1977). Private practice in social Pincus, A., & Minahan, A. (1973). Social work
work. In Encyclopedia of social work (pp. practice. Itasca, IL: F. E. Peacock.
why some groups remain marginal to the 1054-1059). Washington, DC: National Reich, R. (1983). ThenextAmericanfrontier.
welfare enterprise. Finally, the theory of- Association of Social Workers. New York: Times Books.
fers predictions about the future of Galper, ]. (1975). The politics ofsocial services. Starr, P. (1985). The meaning of privatization.
groups that have been instrumental in Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. In Workingpaper6: Privatization (pp. 1-44).
American social welfare. The theory in- Gil, D. (1976). Unravellingsocialpolicy. Cam- Washington, DC: National Conference on
vites empirical investigation and en- bridge, MA: Schenkman. Social Welfare.
courages welfare professionals to pursue Gilbert, N., & Specht, H. (1986). Dimensions Statistical abstract of the United States, 86.
a depth of analysis that identifies causes of social welfare POlicy. Englewood Cliffs, (1988). Washington, DC: U.S. Government
for the "complexity and difficulty" in- NJ: Prentice-Hall. Printing Office.
herent in social welfare (Craib, 1984). Golton, M. A. (1973). Private practice in social Stoesz, D. (1986). Corporate welfare: The
work. In Encyclopedia of social work (pp. third stage of welfare in the United States.
Such exploration is as useful for those 949-955). Washington, DC: National Social Work, 31, 245-249.
concerned about macro phenomena as for Association of Social Workers. Stoesz, D. (1987). Privatization: Reforming
clinicians who must conform practice Gough, I. (1979). The political economy of the the welfare state. Journal of Sociology and
theory to the contexts in which they work. welfare state. London: Macmillan. Social Welfare, 14, 3-19.
Gruber, M. (1971). The welfare industrial Stoesz, D. (1988a). Functional conception of
References complex. The Nation, 212, 808-811. social welfare. Social Work, 33, 58-59.
Abramovitz, M. (1986). The privatization of Harris, M. (1981). America now. New York: Stoesz, D. (1988b). Human service corpora-
the welfare state: A review. Social Work, Simon & Schuster. tions and the welfare state. Society/Transac-
31, 257-264. Hodgkinson, V., & Weitzman, M. (1986). tion, 25, 53-58.
Abramson, A., & Salamon, L. (1986). The Dimensions of the independent sector. Straussner, S.L.A. (1988). Comparison of in-
nonprofit sector and the new federal budget. Washington, DC: Independent Sector. house and contracted-out employee
Washington, DC: Urban Institute. Hopps, J. G. (Ed.). (1988). Social work in an assistance programs. Social Work, 33,
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental industrial setting [Entire issue]. Social 53-55.
Relations. (1987). Significant features of Work, 33 (1). Taylor, S., & Roberts, R. (1985). Theoryand
fiscal federalism, 1988 edition, volume 1. Kamerman, S., & Kahn, A. (1976). Socialser- practice of community social work. New
Washington, DC: Author. vices in the United States. Philadelphia: York: Columbia University Press.
Alford, R. (1973, Winter). The political Temple University Press. Thirty-one jurisdictions regulate profession
economy of health care. Politics and Socie- Kamerman, S., & Kahn, A. (1980). Socialser- as states pass laws at record rate. (1983,
ty,127-164. vice in international perspective. New September). NASW News, p. 1.
Alford, R. (1975). Health care politics. Chicago: Brunswick, NJ: Transaction. Trattner, W. (1974). From poor law to welfare
University of Chicago Press. Kelley, P., & Alexander, P. (1985). Part-time state. New York: Macmillan.
Barker, R. (1983, October). Private practice private practice. Social Work, 30, 254-258. Trattner, W. (1985). The first days of Social
primerfor social work. NASW News, p. 13. Kristol, I. (1982, October 17). Charity and Security. Public Welfare, 43, 17-21.
Barker, R. (1987). The social work dictionary. business shouldn't mix. New York Times, UPfrom,dependency. (1986). Washington, DC:
Silver Spring, MD: National Association of sec. 3, p. 2. U.S. Government Printing Office.
Social Workers. Licensure act passed. (1987, September). Wilensky, H., & Lebeaux, C. (1965). In-
Bendick, M. (1985). Privatizing the delivery NASW News, p. 8. dustrial society and social welfare. New
of social welfare service. In Workingpaper Light, D. (1986). Corporate medicine for pro- York: Free Press.
6: Privatization (pp. 1-73). Washington, fit. Scientific American, 255, 38-45.
DC: National Conference on Social Lipsky, M. (1984, March). Bureaucratic
disentitlement in social welfare programs.
David Stoesz, DSW, is Assistant Professor,
Welfare.
Bloom, A. (1987). TheclosingoftheAmerican Social Service Review, 2-27. School of Social Work, San Diego State
mind. New York: Simon & Schuster. Lubove, R. (1969). The professional altruist. University, San Diego, CA 92182, and
Coleman, D. (1985, April 3). Social workers New York: Atheneum. Director, policyAmerica.
vault into a leading role in psychotherapy. Macarov, D. (1978). The design of social
New York Times, p. Cl. welfare. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Accepted October 26, 1988

Stoesz / A Theory of Social Welfare 107

You might also like