You are on page 1of 3

/ Articles / The Cambridge Compromise: A solution to India’s delimitation dilemma?

20 May 2020

The Cambridge Compromise: A solution to India’s


delimitation dilemma?
by Vishwesh Sundar

Search

Search In The Long Run

By Category

Select

PHOTO: Popular
Sansad Bhavan, Delhi. Deepak Gupta via Flickr.

The historical burden


of antisemitism
Tweet Share 20
by Helen Thompson

In response to a question on the need to construct a new parliament building, the Indian
John Maynard Keynes
Union Minister of Housing and Urban Affairs, Hardeep Singh Puri, reasoned that, among
on universal basic
other factors, the current building could not house additional members should there be income
an increase in seats in the Lok Sabha (House of the People). The enlargement of the Lok by Peter Sloman
Sabha is much needed because currently 1.3 billion Indians are represented in
parliament by just 543 representatives. Each Member of Parliament (MP) represents Brexit: The view from
roughly 2.3 million people, approximately equal to the population of Qatar. Contrast this Japan (or the ‘Tokyo
Consensus’)
with the European Parliament, which despite being an elected legislative body of a
by Tomohiko
supranational organisation and not a country, has 705 members (MEPs) representing Taniguchi
446 million people. Thus, in comparison to India, it has roughly 1.5 times the number of
representatives representing around a third of India’s population. In a few years from
now, the Lok Sabha will face the bigger challenge of deciding how the seats of an
enlarged parliament should be apportioned among the Indian states. The Cambridge Minute
According to Article 82 of the Indian Constitution, the Delimitation Commission is
entrusted with the task of redrawing the constituencies based on the most recent census What is In the Long Run?
data. This practice was followed until the 1970s and constituencies were redrawn to
account for decadal changes due to a natural increase in population and migration. This What is In the Long R…
R…
provision meant that states with a higher fertility rate would enjoy greater political
representation across generations. However, it also contradicted Indira Gandhi
government’s objective of population control. Therefore, in 1976, through the 42nd
Amendment, the parliamentary and assembly seats that were determined by the 1971
Census were frozen until the 2001 Census so that states were not penalised for 18 September 2018
effectively executing family planning programmes. Through the 84th Amendment, this
freeze was further extended until 2026 and only the boundaries within the states were
redrawn to equate the population between the state constituencies. This has created a
discrepancy between the number of voters per constituency with some having as many
as 3 million and others less than 50,000. This violates the principle of one-person, one- Follow
vote or the parity in the value of the vote of each elector. In 1971, the states of Tamil
Nadu and Bihar had a population parity of about 42 million and thus got 39 and 40
parliamentary seats respectively. Today, Bihar’s population is approximately 1.5 times
that of Tamil Nadu. Similarly, although the present population of the state of Madhya
Pradesh is slightly more than that of Tamil Nadu, the former has only 29 seats while the
latter has 39.

After nearly 50 years, the Delimitation Commission will be tasked again with redrawing
the boundaries after the first Census of 2026, most likely in 2031. The rationale for this
postponement is that by 2026 India will have reduced the fertility rate to replacement
levels and, consequently, the population of the country will have stabilised. Many political
commentators have already rung alarm bells about the political tensions that are likely to
arise as the political centre of gravity of the country shifts towards the Gangetic belt.
MPs from just the three states of Uttar Pradesh, Bihar and West Bengal will constitute a
third of the parliament. Moreover, the Rajya Sabha (Council of States) will reflect a similar
composition of seat distribution. With the delimitation set to happen in just six years, and
a third postponement unlikely, the task of finding a solution is more urgent than ever. An
idea that is gaining popularity is to increase the parliamentary seats in a way that no
state stands to lose any but additional seats are given to those that are under-
represented. However, this reform would still not assuage the concern of some states
being able to dominate parliamentary discussions as now they would get a bigger
portion of an enlarged pie. At this juncture, it is worth studying the European Parliament
model of representation and the Cambridge Compromise.

While the Cambridge Compromise can be localised to


the Indian context, the bigger challenge would be to
garner the political will to enact such drastic
parliamentary reforms.
In many respects, the European Union (EU) and India are similar. Both have a socially and
culturally diverse population. An example of this is that just as India has recognised Hindi
and English as official languages at the national level and 22 official languages at the
state level, the EU has 24 official languages, of which English, French and German are
used as ‘procedural languages’ in the European Commission, the EU’s executive branch.
Concerning voting and representation, MEPs too have been elected by direct universal
suffrage since 1979, also for a term of five years. However, a striking difference is that
while India is a sovereign country, the EU is a supranational organisation with delegated
sovereignty. This difference is crucial with respect to feelings of belonging and
representation.

Nevertheless, the principle of degressive proportionality used to determine the


distribution of the 705 seats in the European Parliament among the 27 Member States
can be localised to the Indian context. According to this principle, the Member States’
representation ratios, that is, the population figure divided by the number of seats before
rounding, decrease from the more populous to less populous Member States. Care is
also taken to ensure that no smaller Member State receives more seats than a larger
one. The Lisbon Treaty added another safeguard by setting the maximum number of
seats per Member State – currently applying to Germany – to 96 and the minimum
number to 6 for the smallest Member States of Malta, Luxembourg, Estonia and Cyprus.

The Committee on Constitutional Affairs of the European Parliament commissioned a


group of mathematicians to recommend a formula that would apportion the seats of the
European Parliament among Member States in a manner that was ‘durable, transparent
and impartial to politics’. This led to the publication of the Cambridge Compromise of
2011, which was drafted in accordance with the constraints set by the Lisbon Treaty. The
recommendations propose a two-step process termed the ‘Base+prop method’. In the
first stage, a fixed number of seats is allocated to each country. In the second stage, the
remainder is distributed in proportion to population sizes with upwards rounding. This
rule does not apply to the most and least populous countries for which a respective
maximum and minimum ceiling is predetermined. This method can be considered a
suitable compromise between the proportional representation system followed in India
and the strict degressive representation system followed in the US Senate, where every
state has two seats irrespective of its population size.
Despite the composition of the European Parliament broadly adhering to the principle of
degressive proportionality, scholars criticise it as a highly unequal parliament. They argue
that smaller Member States are over-represented, leading to a ‘structural democratic
deficit’ in the EU. The Cambridge Compromise, which could have slightly corrected this
inequality post-Brexit, was also rejected in favour of a ‘pragmatic solution’ where no EU
country loses any seats, while under-represented countries gain between one and five.  

In conclusion, while the Cambridge Compromise can be adjusted and localised to the
Indian context, the bigger challenge would be to garner the political will to enact such
drastic parliamentary reforms. Irrespective of the solution adopted, however, India should
utilise this opportunity to reform representation in parliament in a way that protects the
interests of the smaller states while simultaneously distributing seats to reflect
population differences.

About the author

Vishwesh Sundar is a recent graduate of the Advanced Master in


International Relations and Diplomacy at Leiden University, The
Hague. He was previously a research assistant at the Clingendael
Institute in The Hague and contributed to projects as part of the
EU-India Think Tank Twinning Initiative.

You May Also Like

Railway privatisation
Diluting the secular in India:
state: India’s Opportunities and
Citizenship challenges
Amendment Act
by Chitresh Shrivastva
by Ryan Mitra

GET IN TOUCH ABOUT FOLLOW


We welcome proposals for articles, interviews, In The Long Run brings you political insight
book reviews, and audio and video content. from the University of Cambridge, and around
Contributions should be original and should the world.
not be under consideration elsewhere.
We publish accessible writing on politics and
01223 767261 public policy based on timely reflection and
cutting-edge research. We also publish short
longrun@hermes.cam.ac.uk commentary, interviews, book reviews, and
videos, using today’s news to stimulate new
Alison Richard Building, 7 West Rd,
thinking about the past, present, and future.
Cambridge CB3 9DT

Copyright © 2016-2021 In The Long Run


We are all dead.

You might also like