You are on page 1of 17

Agricultural & Applied Economics Association

The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates: Opportunities


and Challenges
Author(s): Kathleen Segerson
Source: American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 97, No. 2 (March 2015), pp. 374-
389
Published by: Oxford University Press on behalf of the Agricultural & Applied Economics
Association
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/24476490
Accessed: 03-12-2022 19:56 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Agricultural & Applied Economics Association, Oxford University Press are collaborating
with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Agricultural
Economics

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary
Environmental Policy Debates: Opportunities
and Challenges

Kathleen Segerson

Economists in the field of environmental and from the Science Advisory Board of the U.S.
natural resource economics or agricultural Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)
economics who want to be policy-relevant on the need for more social scientists within
face both unique opportunities and unique the agency, social science in general and eco
challenges relative to economists in many nomics in particular continue to represent
(most) other fields. Those of us who work only a small fraction of the focus of EPA
in academic departments or agencies/ and its work (U.S. Environmental Protection
organizations with economists who are in Agency 2011). This reflects the fact that the
fields like labor, macro-economics, taxation, relevance of economics for environmental
or industrial organization have undoubtedly protection has historically been either ques
seen the contrast. Unlike these other fields, tioned, or at least under-appreciated. Thus,
the field of environmental economics, and while no less important, it is more difficult
often agricultural economics, is inherently for economics to get a seat at the table in
interdisciplinary and linked to the rela- environmental policy debates than in other
tionship between people and nature, either policy contexts. In addition, once at the table,
explicitly or implicitly. Importantly, this rela- economists must work with individuals with
tionship is bidirectional: human well-being different backgrounds and disciplinary per
depends in many ways on goods and ser- spectives who often approach environmental
vices provided by nature, and the supply of policy in very different ways,
those goods and services are affected by and One reason for this seems to be the public
hence ultimately depend on human behavior perception of what the study of economics
(Millennium Ecosystem Assessment 2005). entails and its sphere of relevance. In my
Nonetheless, economics very often plays view, this stems at least in part from how eco
a limited role in interdisciplinary environ- nomics portrays itself. The traditional view
mental policy debates. In some contexts, such of economics is epitomized by the ubiquitous
as monetary policy or tax policy, economists "circular flow" diagram that is introduced
are generally the primary source of policy early on in almost every principles of eco
advice. Federal agencies providing this advice nomics class (see figure 1 for an example),
are largely populated with economists, and This diagram provides the over-arching
the use of economic analysis as the basis for framework that guides how most economists
policy prescriptions is widely accepted. This think about the "system" that they study
is not true in the realm of environmental and leads to a general perception that eco
policy. In fact, some environmental statutes nomics is about markets and flows of money,
explicitly prohibit the use of economic anal- However, the framework embodied in the
ysis as a basis for policy-related decisions traditional circular flow diagram is woefully
(Hahn, Olmstead, and Stavins 2003). Sim- inadequate (incomplete) for studying many
ilarly, despite repeated recommendations economic problems, especially those stud
ied by environmental economists but often
even those studied by colleagues in other
Kathleen Segerson is in the Department of Economics, Univer- fields. An alternative circular flow diagram,

Sity^eCrthorCUthanks James Vercammen for very nsefnl depicted in figure 2, highlights the fact that
comments that helped improve this address. the human System, of which the economy

Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 97(2): 374-389; doi: 10.1093/ajae/aaul04


Published online December 3, 2014
©) The
The Author
Author2014.
2014. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Agricultural and Applied Economics
Association. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 375

Goods and services . .Goods andservices


Goods and services
Goods andi services^^^^^^^
services^^^^*"®!
MarketsMarkets
for goods
for goods

/P*
and services

B B Money Money 1

Ecosystem Impacts
Households Firms
Services

Money Money M B

Markets for
factors 1^/ Factors

Figure 2. Alternative circular flow diagram


Figure 1. The standard circular flow diagram
and reductions in biodiversity. The need
to understand and address these problems
is one part, is linked to the natural system, has led to calls for more closely integrat
with the two sub-systems comprising an over- ing natural and social sciences, particularly
arching "coupled natural-human (CNH)" ecology and economics, as part of an effort
or "socio-ecological" system (Berkes and to ensure the continued flow of ecosystem
Folke 2000; Liu et al. 2007). Just about all services needed to sustain the well-being of
production and consumption decisions made present and future generations (National
within the human system, that is, the econ- Research Council 2005; Carpenter et al. 2006;
omy, have implications for the natural system, Liu et al. 2007; Polasky and Segerson 2009).
and clearly conditions or changes in the nat- Many ecologists now see work on ecosystem
ural system have implications for the human services as a means of putting ecosystem pro
system. Importantly, the flows depicted in tection on a more equal footing with other
this alternative circular flow diagram are (mainly commercial) interests, and hence
not exchanges involving money, but rather have embraced it as a means of justifying
impacts and flows of goods and services that ecosystem protection not just for its own
often occur outside of markets. sake but also for its contributions to human
Note that this perspective extends beyond welfare. This has provided an opportunity for
simply recognizing that environmental exter- collaboration between economists and ecol
nalities exist and people demand (and are ogists, not only in understanding the coupled
willing to pay for) environmental quality, human-natural system but also in advocat
two long-time pillars of the field of environ- ing policies to protect it (Naidoo et al. 2006;
mental economics. The CNH perspective is a Polasky and Segerson 2009; Bateman et al.
systems approach that is inherently long run 2011; Ten Brink 2011).
and dynamic, and recognizes the importance Opportunities to work in an interdis
of time lags, feedback loops, and thresholds ciplinary setting and participate in policy
(Liu et al. 2007). It builds on the concept of discussions are increasingly available to
ecosystem services, defined as the benefits environmental economists who seek them,
that ecosystems provide to humans (Daily However, even when opportunities arise,
1997). The concept of ecosystem services efforts to inject economic reasoning and
emerged in response to the growing appreci- analysis into environmental policy debates
ation of the important role that ecosystems face challenges that must be overcome if eco
play in providing goods and services that nomics is to play a prominent role in those
contribute to human well-being, as well discussions. Here I reflect on what I see as
as a growing awareness of the scale of the some of the opportunities for such efforts, as
impact of human actions on ecosystems and well as some key challenges they face,
the flow of these services (e.g., Daily 1997;
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment 2005).
Concerns about reductions in the flow of
services include not only traditional envi- Opportunities: What Economics Brings to
ronmental problems such as air and water the Table
pollution (sulfur dioxide emissions, ground
level ozone, and eutrophication), but also Environmental policy is, of course, about
climate change, global changes in the nitro- protecting the environment, which requires
gen cycle, deforestation, loss of wetlands, an understanding of the natural/biophysical

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
376 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

system, for example, how ecosystems func costs will be explicit monetary out-of-pocket
tion and how the biosphere interacts with costs (such as the cost of adding a catalytic
the atmosphere and the hydrosphere (Folke converter to a car, or the additional cost of
1999). It is this perspective that permeates a hybrid vehicle), while in other cases they
most scientific debates about environmen can be non-monetary, such as the reductions
tal protection and discussions within, for in convenience or comfort from adjusting
example, the Science Advisory Board at the thermostats to reduce energy use. In addition,
EPA. This is not surprising, given the EPA's protecting one aspect of the environment,
mission "to protect human health and the such as the population of a predator species,
environment. " Where does economics fit can come at the expense of another aspect,
within this mission? such as its prey. Recognizing and explicitly
While focused on environmental protec acknowledging the potential for tradeoffs and
tion, the EPA's mission clearly reflects a the need to evaluate policy choices in terms
coupled natural-human systems perspective of those tradeoffs is a critical perspective that
that recognizes the links between environ economics brings to policy debates.
mental protection and people. As such, this Preferences/Substitutability. A key to
mission cannot be met by relying solely on evaluating tradeoffs is, of course, compar
information from the biophysical sciences. It ing tradeoffs that would have to be made
must also consider how the environment is to the tradeoffs that people are willing to
impacted by human activity, and how changes make, which depend on their preferences,
in environmental quality affect humans. In particularly the extent to which they view
fact, several of the program areas within different goods and services as substitutable.
the EPA Office of Research and Develop The tradeoffs people are willing to make
ment include an emphasis on sustainability,1 between environmental services and other
suggesting a clear role for economics. goods and services, or across different envi
While detailed economic studies can pro ronmental services, relate directly to the
vide quantitative estimates of both sides of welfare changes that result from environ
the relationship between humans and nature mental changes, and hence to the link from
depicted in figure 2, much can also be gained the natural to the human system depicted
simply by injecting an economic perspective in figure 2. However, assessing the tradeoffs
based on some very fundamental economic people are willing to make goes beyond sim
principles/concepts into policy discussions. ply recognizing that nature affects people,
This requires not only an understanding of and explicitly acknowledges that people care
these principles/concepts, but also an appre not only about environmental protection
ciation for their relevance to environmental but also about the provision of other goods
policy, something that is generally not obvi and services that provide utility. In addi
ous when taught in standard economics tion, it recognizes that the extent to which
courses. Particularly important are the fol individuals are willing to trade one for the
lowing four basic economic concepts, familiar other will vary with individual preferences
to all economists: and circumstances. Thus, if scientists advo
Scarcity/Opportunity Costs/Tradeoffs. The cate for policy based on their own personal
concept of scarcity and opportunity cost is preferences, that is, based on the tradeoffs
fundamental to all economic approaches. It that they would be willing to make, the result
reflects both technology/production possibil ing decisions will not necessarily reflect the
ities and resource availability. It recognizes preferences of others. Agreeing on tradeoffs
that, although "win-win" opportunities can across generations, as reflected in the choice
sometimes be found (e.g., from reductions of a (utility) discount rate, is particularly
in waste or improvements in energy effi challenging.
ciency), in general protecting human health Choice/Behavioral Responses/Incentives.
and the environment will come at the cost of Whether intentionally or not, policies create
giving up something else. Sometimes those incentives for self-interested individuals to
change their behavior in ways that enhance
their own utility. Recognizing these behav
1 These six program areas are as follows: Air, Climate and ioral responses is critical to effective policy
Energy; Chemical Safety for Sustainability; Safe and Sustainable design. As documented in the popular book
Water Resources; Human Health Risk Assessment; Home
land Security; and Sustainable and Healthy Communities. See
Freakonomics (Levitt and Dubner 2005),
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2012a). examples abound across many contexts of

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 377

cases where failure to anticipate a behavioral ecological properties. While there are clearly
response led to a policy that had unintended some parallels—for example, regarding the
consequences and/or was ineffective. Antic finiteness of resources—these principles are
ipating behavioral responses can reduce the quite distinct from those that characterize an
likelihood of such outcomes. In addition, it economic perspective.2
broadens the range of policy options that
can be used to achieve a given goal, by rec
ognizing that incentive-based policies might The Role of Economics in Environmental
be a preferred alternative to, for example, Policymaking
technology mandates or other "command
and-control" policies, since they can provide Broadly speaking, economics and the fun
incentives to reduce the overall costs of
damental principles outlined above can
meeting environmental targets. play an important role in environmental
Spillover Effects. Spillover effects can policymaking in two key contexts: (1) esti
result either from interactions through mar mating benefits and costs (i.e., quantifying
kets (e.g., general equilibrium effects) or tradeoffs people would have or be willing to
from interactions through utility or produc make), and (2) designing effective policies
tion functions (e.g., externalities or public that recognize the importance of behavioral
goods). Both have implications for how a responses and spillovers.
decision or policy targeted at one group can With regard to the first context, there
affect others. In addition, the latter have is, of course, a long history regarding the
implications for the efficiency of market estimation of benefits and costs in environ
transactions, or, more generally, private deci mental and natural resource economics,
sions. As with behavioral responses, policies both in theory and practice, and I do not
that fail to anticipate spillover effects can attempt to summarize that literature here.3
be ineffective or even counter-productive. Rather, I simply note that, for federal envi
The standard circular flow diagram in figure ronmental statutes the signal about the role
1 is helpful for thinking about market inter of economics, in particular the quantifica
actions, but is not sufficient for identifying tion and monetization of tradeoffs, is mixed.
the role and implications of externalities and Some statutes, such as the Clean Air Act
public goods. and the Endangered Species Act, generally
The above four concepts are familiar to prohibit the consideration of costs in set
all economists, and, in fact, we probably take ting regulations, while others, such as the
them for granted. Most of us are so used to Toxic Substance Control Act and the Federal
thinking in these terms and talking to other Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act
economists who think in these terms that
allow it (Hahn, Olmstead, and Stavins 2003).
we fail to recognize how unique this way of More explicit guidance on the consideration
thinking is; we also fail to realize that people of tradeoffs appears in a series of Execu
with other disciplinary backgrounds do not tive Orders, starting with Executive Order
view the world from this same perspective. 12291 issued by President Reagan in 1981,
This should not be too surprising, since we up through Executive Order 13563, issued
undoubtedly are not familiar with the basic by President Obama in 2011 (see textbox 1).
principles that define other disciplines or This order applies to all "major" federal
the way that other disciplines think about regulations. Unlike the original Executive
the world. To see this, it is interesting to Order 12291, subsequent Executive Orders,
contrast the above basic principles with a including the latest one, do not require a
list of fundamental principles from ecology. strict benefit-cost test, under which a regu
Scheiner and Willig (2008) list the following lation would not be adopted unless it was
seven concepts/principles that define a gen determined that benefits exceed costs. Rather,
eral theory of ecology: (1) heterogeneous the requirement is simply that benefits and
distribution of organisms across space and costs are taken into account (considered) and
time; (2) interactions of organisms with their
environment; (3) contingencies determine
distributions; (4) environmental hetero
geneity across space and time; (5) finite and 2 See Tilman, Polasky, and Lehman (2005), and Polasky and
Segerson (2009) for further discussion.
heterogeneous resources; (6) mortality of * See, for example, Just, Hueth, and Schmitz (2004), and
organisms; and (7) evolutionary cause of Freeman, Herriges, and Kling (2014).

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
378 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

that, for any regulation that is adopted, ben miles per gallon for model year 2025. The
efits justify costs. It is clear in statement 3 in Regulatory Impact Analysis for the emissions
textbox 1 that the concept of "benefits" being standards presented lifetime present values
invoked here is not the welfare-theoretic and annualized values for costs, benefits,
concept of compensating or equivalent vari and net benefits (under alternative discount
ation used by economists, but a broader rates), which showed that the benefits of the
(looser) concept that includes consideration regulation exceed the costs. More impor
of distributional impacts and equity (presum tantly for the discussion here, the analysis
ably not in a formulaic way). Interestingly, considered a wide range of impacts affecting
consistent with economic prescriptions, the benefits and costs, including those related to
Executive Order also advocates the use of climate change, energy security, particulate
performance standards over design standards matter, refueling time, and rebound effects
and incentives over direct regulation. (in terms of both the benefits of additional
Given that a requirement to consider driving and the cost of additional congestion,
benefits and costs for proposed major reg noise, and accidents). Thus, this Regulatory
ulations, including major environmental Impact Analysis is clearly much more com
regulations, has been in place for over 30 prehensive than many of the earlier ones
years, an important question is whether it examined by Hahn and Dudley (2007) and
has had an impact in increasing the role that would presumably rank very high on their
economics plays in environmental policy scorecard.
making. A paper by Hahn and Dudley (2007) The above discussion suggests that the
examined a sample of EPA Regulatory Executive Orders related to benefit-cost anal
Impact Analyses (RIAs) from 1982-1999, ysis provide a prominent role for economics
and used a scorecard method to rate those in the evaluation of major environmental
analyses based on the extent to which they regulations, and there is at least some evi
included basic economic information. These dence that as a result agencies are generating
authors found that, while all Regulatory quite comprehensive information about the
Impact Analyses monetized at least some associated benefits and costs. In fact, in a
costs, only about 50% monetized at least recent commentary entitled "The Stunning
some benefits, with only about 30% pre Triumph for Cost-Benefit Analysis," Cass
senting some measure of net benefits. Hahn Sunstein (2012), the former Administrator
and Dudley concluded that, based on what of the White House Office of Information
was included/missing, the quality of the and Regulatory Affairs, states: "Endorsed
Regulatory Impact Analyses was gener for more than three decades and by five
ally quite low, with no clear trend toward presidents, cost-benefit analysis is here to
improvement. They interpret this as sug stay." Of course, generating comprehensive
gesting non-compliance with the Executive information about benefits and costs does
Orders. Nonetheless, Hahn and Dudley are not guarantee that this information will be
guardedly optimistic about the future use of considered in final policy decisions, but at
benefit-cost analysis in Regulatory Impact least the information is available as an input
Analyses. into those decisions.4
A recent example provides some support In addition to the requirement to consider
for this guarded optimism. In 2012 the EPA benefits and costs, the Executive Orders also
conducted a Regulatory Impact Analysis for call for greater use of performance standards
regulations it was issuing under the Clean Air and economic incentives. Much progress
Act that set fleet-wide average carbon diox has been made here as well. For example,
ide emission standards (expressed in terms although environmental taxes are not com
of grams/mile) for cars and light trucks (U.S. mon in the United States,5 tradable permits
Environmental Protection Agency 2012b). have been successfully used in a number of
These standards were issued in conjunction places to reduce pollution (Goulder 2013),
with new Corporate Average Fuel Economy allocate development rights for farmland
standards issued by the Department of Trans
portation. If the EPA's emissions standards
are met entirely through improvements in 4 In general, the quality of information can vary considerably,
and it is often difficult for policy makers to distinguish high-quality
fuel efficiency, the EPA estimates that they
from low-quality information.
would correspond to a projected average fuel 5 Environmental taxes are more commonly used in Europe.
efficiency for cars and light trucks of 54.5 See, for example, Prasad (2009).

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 379

Textbox 1. Excerpt from Executive Order 13563

Our regulatory system must... take into account benefits and costs, both quantitative and qualitative.
[T]o the extent permitted by law, each agency must:

1. Propose or adopt a regulation only upon a reasoned determination that its benefits justify its
costs (recognizing that some benefits and costs are difficult to quantify);
2. Tailor its regulations to impose the least burden on society, consistent with obtaining regulatory
objectives;
3. Select... approaches that maximize net benefits (including potential economic, environmental,
public health and safety, and other advantages; distributive impacts; and equity);
4. To the extent feasible, specify performance objectives ...
5. Identify and assess available alternatives to direct regulation, including providing economic
incentives to encourage desired behavior, such as user fees or marketable permits, or providing
information

Source: http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2011/01/18/improving-regulation-and-regulatory-review-executive-order (accessed on November 11,


2014).

preservation (Tan and Beckmann 2010), and environmental policy table, economics and
allocate fishing quotas (Costello, Gaines, economists still play a limited role in envi
and Lynham 2008). Challenges remain, ronmental policy arenas. For example, of
particularly in the context of agricultural the approximately 18,000 EPA employees,
water pollution (Fisher-Vanden and Olm relatively few are economists. The EPA's
stead 2013), but the potential for economic National Center for Environmental Eco
incentives to be more cost-effective than nomics employs about 30 economists,6 and
traditional regulatory approaches has clearly some economists work in the EPA's pro
been recognized by policymakers. Nonethe gram offices or in the Office of Research
less, environmental policy continues to rely and Development (ORD). However, only
heavily on regulations and standards. The 1.57% of the ORD science staff, which totals
new corporate average fuel economy stan approximately 1,200 employees, are social
dards are an example. Standard welfare scientists.7 The EPA Science Advisory Board
analysis implies that, in a neoclassical world, has repeatedly recognized the need for
energy taxes are a more efficient way to more social scientists (including economists)
achieve energy conservation than energy to help the EPA meet its mission to pro
efficiency standards, due at least in part to tect human health and the environment.
the rebound effect (Parry, Evans, and Oates For example, in a recent letter to the EPA
2014). Interestingly, some recent work in Administrator, the Science Advisory Board
behavioral economics suggests this conclu stated: "Investment in social and behavioral
sion might not hold if the standard rationale sciences is needed to complement ORD's
choice assumption embodied in neoclassical investments in ecological and human health
models is relaxed (Gillingham and Palmer research," (U.S. Environmental Protection
2014; Tsvetanov and Segerson 2014). While Agency 2012a). The challenge, however, is
this work might imply the need to re-think not just to increase investment in social sci
(or at least temper) the standard policy pre ence research but also to integrate insights
scriptions regarding taxes versus standards, from economics and other social sciences
it clearly has not played a key role in the (i.e., an economics/social science perspective)
historical and continued reliance on the use into policy discussions dominated by bio
of regulation and standards rather than eco physical scientists. This integration is clearly
nomic incentives to achieve environmental needed (e.g., National Research Council
(and other natural resource management) 2005; Carpenter et al. 2006; Polasky and
goals. Segerson 2009) but often not easy. Numerous
challenges exist.

Challenges
6 See http://yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eed.nsf/webpages/Staff.
html (accessed on November 11, 2014).
Despite the progress that has been made 7 Personal communication with Angela Nugent, EPA Science
in bringing an economic perspective to the Advisory Board Staff Office, July 18, 2014.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
380 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.
Concepts and Terminology interdisciplinary setting without a clear exp
. . . . . lanation can lead to confusion.
A critical challenge in interacting across dis- These are two exampies where the same
"Pjrs .1S simply communication (Proops word js usec[ differently by various disciplines,
1999), including establishing a common but a p0tcntial confusion can in principle
understanding of commonly used concepts be resolved b dearl defini how a term
and terminology. As noted above there are is used In other cases_ however, underly
parallel structures across some disciplines, ing fundamental philosophical differences
such as economics and ecology (Tilman, Qr perSpectiVes exist that cannot be easily
Polasky, and Lehman 2005; Polasky and resolved, and hence make collaboration and
Segerson -009)· F°r example, although the integration across disciplines difficult. Three
contexts are different, both disciplines recog- areas where such differences often arise are:
mze the finiteness of resources and study the (1) what it means to «value„ something; (2)
behavior of interacting agents. When parallels what it means for something to be «opti.
such as these exist, the 'translation of con- mal„ that is> what criteria should be used for
cepts from one discipline to another can be ranking alternatives; and (3) how to handle
relatively easy. distributional issues.
However, sometimes the same word
means something very different in differ
ent disciplines, reflecting more fundamental The Concept of Value
differences in perspectives. An example is the
concept of an equilibrium. Economists define Standard economic theory defines value
an equilibrium in terms of market clearing in terms of the tradeoffs that individu
and "an economic balance at which no indi- als are willing to make, as reflected in the
vidual would be better off doing something concepts of compensating and equiva
different" (Krugman and Wells 2006). In con- lent variations (willingness-to-pay and
trast, in ecology an equilibrium is a dynamic willingness-to-accept). This presumes that,
concept defined in terms of a biophysical for any reduction in the quantity of some
steady state (DeAngelis and Waterhouse good or service, there is an increase in the
1987). The economic definition of an equilib- quantity of some other good or service that
rium under which supply is equal to demand would leave the individual at the same level
and individual actors have no incentive to of utility as before. These values need not be
change does not ensure that the system as expressed in monetary terms. For example,
a whole is in a dynamic ecological equilib- the economic value of reducing one type
rium. The Millennium Ecosystem Assessment of risk (such as fatality risk from natural
(2005) documents the ecosystem dégrada- disasters) can be expressed in terms of the
tion that is occurring across the planet as a increase in another type of risk (such as
result of production and consumption (past fatality risk from traffic accidents) that the
and present). If a market equilibrium is individual would be willing to accept (Vis
degrading critical ecosystems on which the cusi 2009). However, in practice economists
associated production/consumption activi- typically "monetize" values, which allows for
ties depend, that market equilibrium is a simple means of aggregating values across
not an equilibrium for the system as a individuals and comparing them to costs,
whole. Monetizing values can lead to two sources
Similarly, the concept of efficiency has a of confusion over terminology. First, non
very specific meaning in economics (defined economists typically assume that monetized
by Pareto efficiency) that differs from values are synonymous with "commercial"
the meaning of the term as used in other values. Second, economists refer to mone
disciplines, where it often refers to minimiz- tized values as "benefits," while in everyday
ing some form of input/output ratio (e.g., language the word "benefit" is broadly used
Patterson 1996). This latter condition does to refer to something beneficial (e.g., a ben
not ensure economic efficiency. For exam- efit of improved air quality is reduced infant
pie, maximizing fuel efficiency does not mortality), as reflected in Executive Order
necessarily yield Pareto efficiency. Most indi- 13563. Both of these can create considerable
viduals in other disciplines are not familiar confusion over the use of these terms, but in
with the specific way in which economists principle this can be resolved through clearly
use this term. Thus, using the term in an defining the terms.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 381

Confusion over terminology, however, individuals have well-defined prefer


is not the crux of the issue regarding the ences, which they reveal consistently in a
concept of value. More importantly, while number of ways (e.g., through behavior
well-accepted within neoclassical economics, or surveys). An alternative view is that
even when the economic concept of value is preferences are constructed through a
clear to others, it is not universally accepted cognitive process, particularly for com
outside of economics. Different disciplines plex and unfamiliar goods, and hence
define and/or measure values differently cannot be elicited through standard eco
(Brown 1984; Rolston 1991; Dietz, Fitzgerald, nomic valuation methods.
and Shwom 2005; Spash 2006). Key areas of Are values associated only with changes
divergence in views about defining values in goods and/or services? In economics,
relate to the following questions:8 the concept of a change is fundamental
to defining economic values. However,
• Should values be defined in anthro some view values as a set of principles,
pocentric terms? Some people believe concepts, or beliefs that guide decisions
that the natural world has value apart and evaluations or seek to assign value
from how it contributes to human wel to an entire ecosystem or even the set
fare. Under this biocentric or ecocentric of ecosystems in some geographical
view, all species may have intrinsic value, domain.
or the condition of the ecosystem as What is the relevant baseline? Although
a whole (health, integrity, resilience) economic values are defined in terms
may have intrinsic value. Examples of of a change from some current or alter
alternative definitions of value that are native level, they do not embody any
not explicitly based on human prefer judgment about whether that level is
ences include values defined in terms "good" or "bad," or how it was arrived
of energy content or contributions to a at (in particular, whether it is higher or
pre-specified conservation goal such as lower than some other reference level).
preserving biodiversity or sustainability. However, when an ecosystem is already
• Should values be defined in utilitarian or degraded, some might advocate a base
deontological terms? Even with agree line defined in terms of some alternative
ment on an anthropocentric approach "desired" level.
to value, the notion of defining values in
terms of contributions to human welfare
and substitutability, rather than rights
Optimality/Normative Evaluation Criteria.
or moral obligations, is not universally
accepted. Deontological rights-based The debates surrounding the above issues
approaches do not embody principles of reflect different views about the sources and
substitutability and tradeoffs. nature of value. These views often give rise to
• Who should determine value when the different views about the normative criteria
public does not have full information? that should be used to evaluate policy options
Consumer sovereignty assumes that to determine which option is "best." Within
individuals are the best judges of what is economics, the standard criteria are: (1) cost
in their own best interest, and that their
effectiveness (does it achieve the goal in the
preferences are valid regardless of how least cost way?), and (2) efficiency (does the
they are viewed by others. However, policy maximize net benefits?). A large body
when the public does not understand or of literature has used benefit-cost analysis to
"appreciate" the contributions of ecosys evaluate policy options based on integrated
tems, some suggest that expert judgment, ecological-economic models.9 Despite this
rather than public values, should be the growing body of literature and its acceptance
basis for policy decisions. by economists and some others, using eco
• Are the preferences that underlie values nomic efficiency to define optimality and
well-defined or constructed? A founda
drive policy decisions is controversial. Out
tional assumption of economics is that side of economics, other objectives are often

8 For more details and related references, see Polasky and


Segerson (2009). See Polasky and Segerson (2009) for related references.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
382 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.
advocated. For example, the mission of con Distributional Issues
servation biology is to conserve the Earth's
Related to the issue of normative criteria
biological diversity, and, as a result, conser
vation biologists often rank policy outcomes
is the question of how to evaluate tradeoffs
across individuals. When the same individuals
based on how well they achieve this goal
(or groups) bear both benefits and costs, the
(Polasky 2012). Because of the complexity
of joint ecological-economic systems, some rationale for basing choices on net benefits
seems much stronger (and less controversial)
natural scientists prefer to think about system
resilience rather than any deliberate attempt
since the choice would ensure Pareto superi
ority. However, when the costs and benefits
to maximize expected net benefits (e.g.,
Perrings 2006). While not an explicit norma are borne by different individuals, either
tive criterion, under the resilience approach
intra-temporally or inter-temporally (e.g.,
different generations), then, absent compen
actions are desirable if they increase an
sation, a means of evaluating tradeoffs across
ecological system's ability to tolerate distur
individuals is needed.10
bances or promote flexible human responses
through learning or adaptation. Similarly, A standard approach to addressing intra
temporal distribution is to present estimates
some advocate using sustainability as a broad
of aggregate benefits and costs (or net bene
normative goal (Ayres 2008). While the spe
fits) accompanied by information about how
cific interpretation of this goal can vary (e.g.,
those benefits and costs are distributed across
Pezzey and Toman 2002), sustainability is
often viewed as an alternative to standard different groups of interest (e.g., Arrow
economic efficiency as a normative goal et al. 1996) or to use welfare weights when
aggregating benefits and costs across groups
(e.g., Ayres 2008). Viewing sustainability as
(Pearce, Atkinson, and Mourato 2006). For
efficiency subject to constraints (see Zil
berman 2014) implies a tradeoff between inter-temporal distributions, weighting is
just being efficient and being sustainable. typically used, where the weights are based
on a chosen or assumed discount rate. While
However, under certain conditions, efficient
paths are also sustainable paths. For exam many economists would eschew the use of
welfare weights in aggregating intra-temporal
ple, Heal (1998) derived sustainability as
an efficient outcome when society places benefits and costs, most accept discounting
in some form as a means of weighting and
a positive value on the very long run and
aggregating inter-temporally (Frederick,
people intrinsically value environmental
assets. Including environmental stocks in the
Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue 2002).
Outside of economics, however, discount
utility function can also yield a sustainable
solution to an otherwise standard model of ing has long been and continues to be quite
the efficient use of an exhaustible resource controversial, especially in environmental
contexts involving the very long run (such
(Krautkraemer 1985). As these works show,
as climate change or nuclear waste disposal)
a potentially fruitful approach is to charac
terize cases in which efficient paths are also
(e.g., Ackerman and Heinzerling 2004). In
sustainable. my view, this stems at least in part from a
confusion over the underlying rationale for
Despite the differing principles or philoso
discounting, and, in particular, the distinc
phies that can underlie various normative
tion between utility discounting (the rate at
criteria, the different rules can lead to policy
which society would trade utility in the future
prescriptions regarding environmental pro
tection that are similar, at least qualitatively
for utility in the present) and consumption
discounting (the rate at which society would
(e.g., Eichner and Pethig 2006; Polasky 2012).
trade consumption in the future for consump
Thus, in practice there may be little difference
tion in the present).11 While dating back to
in terms of decision-making from different
the work of Ramsey (1928), this distinction
perspectives on appropriate normative crite
has been emphasized only fairly recently,
ria. Nonetheless, getting to a common policy
most notably in the debates over policy
prescription can be challenging when the
debate focuses not on the commonality of
the final policy prescription, but rather on 10 Of course, the difficulty of making such intra-personal utility
the ideological differences underlying the comparisons is well-recognized within economics. See Kaldor
different normative criteria that are being (1939).
11 These are, of course, social discount rates. Comparable def
explicitly or implicitly applied (Polasky and initions apply to private discount rates, which may differ from
Segerson 2009). their social counterparts.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 383

responses to climate change (e.g., Heal 2009). problem motivating recent interest in valuing
This highlights the fact that a positive (con- ecosystem services is a push to more fully
sumption) discount rate does not necessarily incorporate the value of ecosystem services
imply giving less weight to the utility of future into benefit-cost analyses and policy decisions
generations relative to current generations. (Daily et al. 2009; ten Brink 2011). Many
Instead, discounting could simply reflect an ecologists have endorsed it for that reason,
expectation that consumption levels (wealth) and economic valuation is playing an increas
will increase over time, and a belief that the ingly important role in highlighting the
marginal utility of consumption is decreasing, contributions of ecosystem services to human
welfare (see, for example, Bateman et al.
2011). Yet, the use of economic valuation to
_ quantify the benefits of ecosystem protection
ο LxamPles is controversial (Goulder and Kennedy 1997;
Chee 2004; Norton and Noonar 2007; Sagoff
Many examples can be used to illustrate the 2011). Underlying the economic estimation
opportunities and challenges discussed above. Gf benefits is an anthropocentric perspective
The following briefly discusses two notable tbat focuses on the services that ecosystems
contexts in which they have arisen. provide to humans, a perspective that is
not universally accepted. In fact, the title of
Valuing and Protecting Ecosystem Services a major EPA report (U.S. Environmental
Protection Agency 2009), "Valuing the
As noted above, there is a growing interest Protection of Ecological Systems and Ser
in valuing and protecting/restoring ecosys- vices," was explicitly chosen to be sufficiently
tem services (e.g., Ninan 2014), a term that broad to allow for valuing systems inde
is broadly defined to include provisioning pendently of the services they provide to
services (such as food, fuelwood, and fresh humans.
water), regulating services (such as flood in addition, even with an anthropocen
protection, climate regulation, pollination, trie focus on services, valuing those services
and pest control), cultural services (such requires the adoption and application of a
as aesthetic and spiritual roles), and sup- specific concept of value. As noted above,
porting services (such as soil formation, different scales or means of expressing values
nutrient cycling, and primary productiv- exist (Brown 1984), and there are different
ity) (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment views on the importance of the factors that
2005). This broad definition includes not only influence those values, which tend to vary
direct benefits, but also indirect benefits that across scholarly disciplines. For example,
result from the use of ecosystems or "natu- economists generally emphasize the impor
ral assets" as inputs into the production of tance of (fixed) preferences and income,
other final goods and services that are valued, while psychologists and sociologists focus
such as agricultural products (Barbier 2008). on other internal and external factors such
Economists tend to focus on services that as perceptions, social/cultural influences,
directly enter utility or production functions, and framing effects. As a result, different
while, not surprisingly, ecologists generally disciplines tend to view the valuation of
focus on the ecological functions and pro- ecosystem services differently, employ differ
cesses that contribute to the provision of ent methods for eliciting values, and express
these services. This difference in focus pro- those values using different measures or
vides modeling challenges (e.g., ensuring scales (Dietz, Fitzgerald, and Shwom 2005;
that outputs from ecological models can be U.S. Environmental Protection Agency 2009).
used as inputs into economic models), but These differences can generate debates about
in principle the two disciplinary perspec- the appropriateness of different valuation
tives can be integrated, thereby facilitating concepts and methods and create significant
collaborative work related to defining and challenges for reaching interdisciplinary
quantifying changes in service flows (see, e.g., consensus. They have led to calls for other
National Research Council 2005; Carpenter approaches, such as expressing tradeoffs
et al. 2006; U.S. Environmental Protection in non-monetary terms (Daily et al. 2009),
Agency 2009). using other, non-economic valuation methods
However, reaching consensus on valuing (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
those changes is more difficult. A critical 2009), and employing more participatory,

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
384 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

discourse-based approaches to valuation the Hawaii shallow set longline swordfish


(Wilson and Howarth 2002; Chee 2004). fishery between 2001-2004 to protect sea
Without espousing economic valuation, turtles.13 The Endangered Species Act man
economic insights about behavioral responses dates species protection regardless of cost,
and spillover effects can still play a key although economic considerations sometimes
role in designing effective policies and pro play an implicit or explicit role in decisions
grams to increase the provision of ecosystem regarding what actions may be taken (Brown
services (regardless of why an increase is and Shogren 1998; Sinden 2004).
desired). For example, programs or mar In light of limited resources and budgets,
kets that provide "payments for ecosystem benefit-cost analysis clearly has the poten
services" (PES) have received considerable tial to provide useful input into decisions
attention in recent policy debates (Heal regarding the protection of species. However,
2000; Bulte et al. 2008; Jack, Kousby, and using benefit-cost analysis in this context has
Sims 2008), and economists have much to been and remains controversial. For exam
contribute to understanding and design ple, Sinden (2004, p. 210) states: "In practice,
ing PES programs. Key program design cost-benefit analysis flattens our most deeply
issues include: practice vs. performance held emotions, beliefs, and values—our awe
based payments; heterogeneity and targeting; at the profundity of extinction, our rever
imperfect information; multiple inter-related ence for life, and our wonder in the face of
services; scale effects; additionality and slip the magnificence of biodiversity—into the
page; and enforcement (Zilberman and monochromatic dull gray of the monetary
Segerson 2012). Understanding program metric."
impacts, and hence improving program des Given such opposition, economists clearly
ign, requires an understanding of both indi have an uphill battle in convincing some
vidual and market responses, as well as the outside of economics of the usefulness of
biophysical relationships that govern the pro measuring the benefits and costs of species
vision of inter-related environmental services. protection using economic methods. This is
Thus, despite potentially different views on not necessarily because they do not think
the reason(s) to protect ecosystems, there that species protection enhances human
are significant opportunities for interdisci well-being. Rather, it stems from at least
plinary collaboration in designing effective two concerns: (1) measuring benefits in
programs to enhance the flow of services they monetary terms, that is, monetizing changes
provide. in levels of protection, and (2) comparing
benefits and costs to determine appropri
Endangered Species Protection ate actions, thereby invoking an economic
efficiency objective for policy choice. Both
A specific example related to ecosystem of these are objectionable to some people
services where both opportunities and and create a challenge to expanding the
challenges in bringing economics into envi use of economics as a normative tool in this
ronmental policy debates exist is the imple context.
mentation of the Endangered Species Act However, even short of monetizing benefits
(ESA). The ESA seeks to protect endan or endorsing efficiency as a social choice rule,
gered or threatened species by prohibiting as with the provision of ecosystem services
actions that are harmful to these species. more generally, economics can contribute
Implementation of the Act has been the basis to ensuring that policies designed to protect
for numerous regulatory actions, including species are actually effective in doing so
fishery closures designed to reduce bycatch (and hopefully cost-effective as well). Unfor
of threatened or endangered marine species. tunately, sometimes they are not and can
For example, the National Marine Fish actually be counter-productive, that is, harm
eries Service has closed portions of the ful to the species due to behavioral responses
west coast drift gillnet swordfish fishery in or spillover effects. A classic example, of
an effort to reduce bycatch of leatherback course, is the "shoot, shovel, and shut-up"
sea turtles, which are listed as endangered
under the act.12 Similarly, regulators closed
safe-document/commercial-fisheries-descriptions/ (accessed on
November 11, 2014).
12 See http://www.pcouncil.org/highly-migratory-species/stock 13 See http://wpcouncil.org/press/2006Marl4_PRESSREL
assessment-and-fishery-evaluation-safe-documents/current-hms EASE_CM131st_Final.pdf (accessed on November 11, 2014).

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 385

response of landowners who fear that the dis- about ourselves, and serve as a reminder
covery of a threatened or endangered species to all economists, whether they study envi
on their land will trigger restrictions on land ronmental economics, labor economics, or
use that will be detrimental to them (Brown macroeconomics, that production, consump
and Shogren 1998). However, even absent tion, and ultimately human well-being all
illicit behavioral responses like this, standard affect and ultimately depend on the con
market effects can lead to counter-productive dition of the natural system. Second, and
results. For example, there is strong evi- equally importantly, it would change how
dence that fishery closures to protect sea non-economists view the field of economics,
turtles have actually led to increased sea Instead of being viewed as simply the study
turtle bycatch, as the associated reductions of the money flows depicted in the traditional
in swordfish production in the closed fish- circular flow diagram, economics would be
eries has been largely replaced by increased viewed as including, or at least recogniz
harvesting in other areas of the world where ing, the interdependence of the human and
sea turtle bycatch rates are higher, thereby natural systems. This would also help link
increasing overall bycatch (e.g., Rausser et al. economics to the sometimes vague notion of
2009; Chan and Pan 2012). These market sustainability and sustainable development
responses could have been anticipated with (Zilberman 2014).
greater input from economics in the policy Skepticism about economics is also fueled
decisions. by a perception that economists revere unfet
tered markets. However, adopting a coupled
natural-human systems perspective could
also have implications for the interpreta
Moving Forward tion of the Second Fundamental Theorem
of Welfare Economics. The standard inter
The discussion above suggests that, despite pretation is that the markets depicted in the
some successes, the role of economics in standard circular flow diagram generally lead
environmental policy debates continues to be to efficient allocations, except when there is
limited, for at least two reasons: (1) a misun- market failure (from, e.g., an environmental
derstanding about the field of economics and externality). In contrast, the interpretation
what it has to contribute, reflecting a wide- arising from a coupled natural-human sys
spread belief that economics is primarily terns perspective might be that these markets
about the study of markets and money (and often do not lead to efficient allocations, at
that economists revere unfettered markets); least in a dynamic sense, because environ
and (2) skepticism/controversy about the mental externalities are pervasive. To restore
application of normative welfare economics the standard interpretation, one would need
(including formal benefit-cost analysis) to markets that not only cover the exchanges in
environmental policy decisions. Given this, the traditional circular flow, but also include
how might we move forward to increase our all of the ways that human activities by one
role? group affect the well-being of others (current
To begin with, economics could adopt a and future) through the links with the natural
coupled natural-human systems perspective system.
as an over-arching framework. Instead of Second, we could more clearly emphasize
depicting the field of economics using the the distinction between the use of eco
traditional circular flow diagram in figure 1, nomics for positive analysis (understanding
in our introductory principles of economics preferences, behavior, markets, etc.) versus
classes we could start with the alternative its use for normative analysis (ranking policy
circular flow diagram in figure 2. Doing so options). In interdisciplinary discussions of
would signal that economics is about more environmental policy, most objections to the
than markets, that is, it is about the coupled use of economics stem from concerns about
natural-human system, with the traditional its normative use, in particular its attempt to
circular flows being one part of the sys- monetize environmental changes and then
tern (embedded in the human component), compare the monetized benefits to estimates
Describing the field of economics, starting in of costs as a basis for making policy decisions,
principles courses, using the coupled natural- Rather than seeking to monetize as much
human systems perspective would have two as possible in order to evaluate tradeoffs
effects. First, it would change how we think using benefit-cost analysis, we could simply

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
386 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.
focus on increasing awareness of tradeoffs, Bateman, I.J., G.M. Mace, C. Fezzi, G. Atkin
and quantifying them in terms that are most son, and K. Turner. 2011. Economic
useful to policy makers charged with balanc Analysis for Ecosystem Service Assess
ing competing interests and considerations. ments. Environmental and Resource
As Hahn and Sunstein (2002, p. 1493) state, Economics 48:177-218.
"Cost-benefit analysis is not an effort to Berkes, F., and C. Folke, eds. 2000. Linking
reduce all human goods to numbers, but to Social and Ecological Systems: Manage
increase the likelihood that regulation will ment Practices and Social Mechanisms
actually produce human goods." While many for Building Resilience. Cambridge:
environmental economists have long advo Cambridge University Press.
cated using benefit-cost analysis as an input Brown, T.C. 1984. The Concept of Value in
into decisions rather than a normative deci Resource Allocation. Land Economics
sion rule (e.g., Arrow et al. 1996), there is a 60: 231-46.
clear need to emphasize this more. Brown, G.M., and J.F. Shogren. 1998. Eco
Finally, economists should acknowledge nomics of the Endangered Species Act.
and work within the realm of the funda Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (3):
mental differences in perspectives across 3-20.
disciplines that give rise to controversies Bulte, E.H, L. Lipper, R. Stringer, and D. Zil
over the use of economics in this context. berman. 2008. Payments for Ecosystem
Different objective functions can often Services and Poverty Reduction: Con
lead to similar environmental protection cepts, Issues, and Empirical Perspectives.
goals. Focusing on shared goals rather Environmental and Development Econo
than ideological differences (differences mics 13 (3): 245-54.
in motivation) can increase the prospects for Carpenter, S., R. Defries, T. Dietz, H.A.
collaboration. Similarly, regardless of how Mooney, S. Polasky, W.V. Reid, and R.J.
environmental targets/goals are set, we could Scholes. 2006. Millennium Ecosystem
emphasize the contributions that economics Assessment: Research Needs. Science
can make to ensuring that those goals are 314: 257-58.
actually met, that is, that a given approach Chan, H.L., and M. Pan. 2012. Spillover
will be effective, and will reduce the cost Effects of Environmental Regulation for
of meeting the goal, that is, increasing cost Sea Turtle Protection: The Case of the
effectiveness. Understanding and anticipating Hawaii Shallow-set Longline Fishery.
behavioral responses and spillovers can con Honolulu, HI: National Océano
tribute to meeting goals more effectively graphie and Atmospheric Administra
and efficiently, even when there are differing tion, National Marine Fisheries Service
views on the appropriate normative criteria Technical Memo, NOAA-TM-NMFSPI
for setting those goals. FSC-30.
Chee, Y.E. 2004. An Ecological Perspec
tive on the Valuation of Ecosystem
References Services. Biological Conservation 120:
549-65.
Ackerman, F., and L. Heinzerling. 2004. Costello, C., S.D. Gaines, and J. Lynham.
Priceless: On Knowing the Price of 2008. Can Catch Shares Prevent Fish
Everything and the Value of Nothing. eries Collapse? Science 321 (5896):
New York: New Press. 1678-81.
Arrow, K.J, M.L. Cropper, G.C. Eads, R.W. Daily G.C., ed. 1997. Nature's Services: Soci
Hahn, L.B. Lave, R.G. Noll, PR. Port etal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems.
ney, et al. 1996. Is There a Role for Washington DC: Island Press.
Benefit-cost Analysis in Environmental, Daily, G.C., S. Polasky, J. Goldstein, P.M.
Health, and Safety Regulation? Science Kareiva, H.A. Mooney, L. Pejchar, T.H.
272: 221-22. Ricketts, J. Salzman, and R. Shallen
Ayres, R.U. 2008. Sustainability Eco berger. 2009. Ecosystem Services in
nomics: Where do We Stand? Ecological Decision Making: Time to Deliver. Fron
Economics 67: 281-310.
tiers in Ecology and the Environment 1
Barbier, E.B. 2008. Ecosystems as Natu (1): 21-8.
ral Assets. Foundations and Trends in DeAngelis, D.L., and J.C. Waterhouse. 1987.
Microeconomics 4 (8): 611-81. Equilibrium and Nonequilibrium

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 387

Concepts in Ecological Models. Hahn, R.W., and C.R. Sunstein. 2002. A


Ecological Monographs 57 (1): 1-21. New Executive Order for Improv
Dietz, T., A. Fitzgerald, and R. Shwom. 2005. ing Federal Regulation? Deeper and
Environmental Values. Annual Review of Wider Cost-benefit Analysis. University
Environment and Resources 30:335-72. of Pennsylvania Law Review 150 (5):
Eichner, T., and R. Pethig. 2006. Efficient 1489-1552.
Non-anthropocentric Nature Protection. Heal, G. 1998. Interpreting Sustainability. In
Social Choice and Welfare 26:47-74. Sustainability: Dynamics and Uncertainty,
Fisher-Vanden, K., and S. Olmstead. 2013. ed. G. Chichilnisky, G. Heal, and A. Ver
Moving Pollution Trading from Air to celli, 3-22. Dorcrecht: Kluwer Academic
Water: Potential, Problems, and Progno Publishers.
sis. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 . 2000. Nature and the Marketplace:
(1): 147-72. Capturing the Value of Ecosystem
Folke, C. 1999. Ecological Principles and Services. Washington DC: Island Press.
Environmental Economic Analysis. In . 2009. The Economics of Climate
Handbook of Environmental and Change: A Post-stern Perspective.
Resource Economics, ed. J.C.J.M. van Climatic Change 96:275-97.
den Bergh, 895-911. Cheltenham, Jack, B.K, C. Kousky, K.R.E. Sims. 2008.
UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Designing Payments for Ecosystem Ser
Elgar. vices: Lessons from Previous Experience
Frederick, S., G. Loewenstein, and T. with Incentive-based Mechanisms. Pro
O'Donoghue. 2002. Time Discounting ceedings of the National Academy of
and Time Preference: A Critical Review. Sciences of the United States of America
Journal of Economic Literature 40 (2): 105:9465-70.
351-401. Just, R.E., D.L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz. 2004.
Freeman A.M. Ill, J.A. Herriges, and C.L. The Welfare Economics of Public Pol
Kling. 2014. The Measurement of icy: A Practical Approach to Project and
Environmental and Resource Values: Policy Evaluation. Cheltenham, UK, and
Theory and Methods. Washington, DC: Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Resources for the Future Press. Kaldor, N. 1939. Welfare Propositions of Eco
Gillingham, K., and K. Palmer. 2014. Bridg nomics and Interpersonal Comparisons
ing the Energy Efficiency Gap: Policy of Utility. Economic Journal 49 (195):
Insights from Economic Theory and 549-52.
Empirical Evidence. Review of Envi Krautkraemer, J. 1985. Optimal Growth,
ronmental Economics and Policy 8 (1): Resource Amenities, and the Preserva
18-38. tion of Natural Environments. Review of
Goulder, L.H., and D. Kennedy. 1997. Valuing Economic Studies 52:153-70.
Ecosystem Services: Philosophical Bases Krugman, P., and R. Wells. 2006. Economics.
and Empirical Methods. In Nature's New York: Worth Publishers.
Services: Societal Dependence on Nat Levitt, S.D., and S.J. Dubner. 2005. Freako
ural Ecosystems, ed. G.C. Daily, 23-47. nomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the
Washington, DC: Island Press. Hidden Side of Everything. New York:
Goulder, L.H. 2013. Markets for Pol William Morrow and Company.
lution Allowances: What are the Liu, J., T. Dietz, S.R. Carpenter, M. Alberti,
(New) Lessons? Journal of Economic C. Folke, E. Moran, A.N. Pell, et. al.
Perspectives 27 (1): 87-102. 2007. Complexity of Coupled Human
Hahn, R.W., and P.M. Dudley. 2007. How and Natural Systems. Science 317:
Well Does the U.S. Government Do 1513-16.
Benefit-cost Analysis? Review of Envi Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. 2005.
ronmental Economics and Policy 1 (2): Ecosystems and Human Well-being.
192-211. Synthesis. Washington DC: Island Press.
Hahn, R., S. Olmstead, and R.N. Stavins. Naidoo, R., A. Balmford, P.J. Ferraro, S.
2003. Environmental Regulation in the Polasky, T.H. Ricketts, and M. Rouget.
1990s: A Retrospective Analysis. Har 2006. Integrating Economic Cost into
vard Environmental Law Review 27: Conservation Planning. Trends in
377-415. Ecology and Evolution 21:681-87.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
388 March 2015 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.
National Research Council. 2005. Valuing Ramsey, F.P. 1928. A Mathematical Theory
Ecosystem Services: Toward Better Envi of Savings. The Economic Journal 38:
ronmental Decision-Making. Washington 543-59.
DC: National Academies Press. Rausser, G., S. Hamilton, M. Kovach, and R.
Ninan, K.N., ed. 2014. Valuing Ecosystem Stifter. 2009. Unintended Consequences:
Services: Methodological Issues and The Spillover Effects of Common Prop
Case Studies. Cheltenham, UK, and erty Regulations. Marine Policy 33:
Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar 24-39.
Publishing. Rolston, H. 1991. Environmental Ethics: Val
Norton, B.G., and D. Noonar. 2007. Ecology ues in and Duties to the Natural World.
and Valuation: Big Changes Needed. In Ecology, Economics and Ethics: The
Ecological Economics 63: 664-75. Broken Circle, ed. F.H. Bormann and
Parry, I.W.H., D. Evans, and W.E. Oates. S.R. Kellert, 65-84. New Haven, CT: Yale
2014. Are Energy Efficiency Standards University Press.
Justified? Journal of Environmental Sagoff, M. 2011. The Quantification and Val
Economics and Management 67 (2): uation of Ecosystem Services. Ecological
104-25. Economics 70:497-502.
Patterson, M. 1996. What is Energy Scheiner, S.M., and M.R. Willig. 2008. A
Efficiency? Energy Policy 24 (5): 377-90. General Theory of Ecology. Theoretical
Pearce, D., G. Atkinson, and S. Mourato. Ecology 1:21-8.
2006. Cost-benefit Analysis and the Envi Sinden, A. 2004. The Economics of Endan
ronment: Recent Developments. Paris: gered Species: Why Less is More in the
OECD Publishing. Economic Analysis of Critical Habitat
Perrings, C. 2006. Resilience and Sus Designations. Harvard Environmental
tainable Development. Environment Law Review 28:129-214.
and Development Economics 11 (4): Spash, C.L. 2006. Non-economic Motivation
417-27. for Contingent Values: Rights and Atti
Pezzey, J.C.V., and M.A. Toman. 2002. tudinal Beliefs in Willingness to Pay for
Progress and Problems in the Economics Environmental Improvements. Land
of Sustainability. In The International Economics 82: 602-22.
Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Sunstein, C.R. 2012. The Stunning Triumph of
Economics 2002/2003, ed. T. Tietenberg Cost-benefit Analysis. Bloomberg View.
and H. Folmer, 165-232. Cheltenham, http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/
UK: Edward Elgar. 2012-09-12/the-stunning-triumph-of-cost
Polasky, S. 2012. Are Investments to Pro benefit-analysis (accessed on November
mote Biodiversity Conservation and 11,2014).
Ecosystem Services Aligned? Oxford Tan, R., and V. Beckmann. 2010. Diversity of
Review of Economic Policy 28 (1): Practical Quota Systems for Farmland
139-63. Preservation: A Multicountry Compar
Polasky, S., and K. Segerson. 2009. Integrating ison and Analysis. Environment and
Ecology and Economics in the Study of Planning C: Government and Policy 28
Ecosystem Services. Annual Review of (2): 211-24.
Resource Economics 1:409-34. ten Brink, P. 2011. The Economics of Ecosys
Prasad, M. 2009. Taxation as a Regulatory tems and Biodiversity in National and
Tool: Lessons from Environmental Taxes International Policy Making. London:
in Europe. In Government and Markets: Earthscan.
Toward a New Theory of Regulation, Tilman, D., S. Polasky, and C. Lehman. 2005.
ed. E.J. Balleisen and D.A. Moss, 363 Diversity, Productivity and Temporal
90. Cambridge: Cambridge University Stability in the Economies of Humans
Press. and Nature. Journal of Environmental
Proops, J.L.R. 1999. Integration and Com Economics and Management 49: 405-26.
munication between Environmental Tsvetanov, T., and K. Segerson. 2014. The
Economics and Other Disciplines. Welfare Effects of Energy Efficiency
In Handbook of Environmental and Standards when Choice Sets Matter.
Resource Economics, ed. J.C.J.M. van den Journal of the Association of Environ
Bergh, 1230-42. Cheltenham, UK, and mental and Resource Economists 1 (1/2):
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. 233-71.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Segerson The Role of Economics in Interdisciplinary Environmental Policy Debates 389

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Light-Duty Vehicle Greenhouse Gas


2009. Valuing the Protection of Eco Emission Standards and Corporate
logical Systems and Services: A Report Average Fuel Economy Standards,
of the EPA Science Advisory Board, EPA-420-R-12-016.
EPA-SAB-09-012. Viscusi, W.K. 2009. Valuing Risks of Death
. 2011. Office of Research and Devel from Terrorism and Natural Disasters.
opment (ORD) New Strategic Research Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 38:
Directions: A Joint Report of the Science 191-213.
Advisory Board (SAB) and ORD Board Wilson, M.A., and R.B. Howarth. 2002.
of Scientific Councilors (BOSC), EPA Discourse-based Valuation of Ecosystem
SAB-12-001. http://yosemite.epa.gov/sab/ Services: Establishing Fair Outcomes
sabproduct.nsf/804D 1 A3 A4 A393C028525 through Group Deliberation. Ecological
793000732744/$File/EPA-SAB-12-001-un Economics 41:431-43.
signed.pdf (accessed on November 11, Zilberman, D. 2014. The Economics of Sus
2014). tainable Development. American Journal
. 2012a. Science for a Sustainable of Agricultural Economics 96 (2): 385-96.
Future: EPA Research Program Over Zilberman, D., and K. Segerson. 2012. Top
view 2012-2016, EPA601/R-12/002, Office Ten Design Elements to Achieve More
of Research and Development. Efficient Conservation Programs. Coun
. 2012b. Regulatory Impact Anal cil on Food, Agricultural and Resource
ysis: Final Rulemaking for 2017-2025 Economics.

This content downloaded from 188.169.74.59 on Sat, 03 Dec 2022 19:56:25 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like