You are on page 1of 14

Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Research Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/respol

Performance of Spanish universities in technology transfer: An empirical analysis


Aida Caldera a,∗ , Olivier Debande b
a
ECARES - Université Libre de Bruxelles, Av. F.D. Roosevelt 50, CP 114, 1050 Brussels, Belgium
b
European Investment Bank, Rue de la Loi 227, 1040 Brussels, Belgium

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper investigates the performance of universities in the transfer of technology using a unique
Received 29 June 2009 university-level dataset for Spain. The results suggest that universities with established policies and
Received in revised form 26 April 2010 procedures for the management of technology transfer perform better. Universities with large and expe-
Accepted 29 May 2010
rienced technology transfer offices (TTOs) generate higher volumes of contract research, but the TTO
Available online 21 July 2010
characteristics appear to matter less for university performance in terms of licensing and creation of
spin-offs. Furthermore, universities with a science park perform better than those without, which sug-
JEL classification:
gests that the agglomeration of knowledge close to universities has a positive effect on universities’
O31
O32
technology transfer performance.
O33 © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
L3

Keywords:
Industry–science relations
Technology transfer
Universities

1. Introduction acteristics including university ownership (public versus private),


academic quality, local high-tech demand conditions, license con-
Improving university technology transfer performance in tract design and the characteristics of the university technology
Europe attracts a lot of attention among policymakers, as evidenced transfer office (Jensen and Thursby, 2001; Thursby and Kemp, 2002;
by the large amount of policy initiatives in this field (see for instance Thursby and Thursby, 2002; Siegel et al., 2003; Di Gregorio and
the European Commission, 2004, 2008). However, there has been Shane, 2003). Most of these studies analyse the performance of US
very limited analysis on the efficiency of university technology universities and explore a variety of different outcome measures,
transfer systems. The commercialisation of university research has including the number of patents and licenses, license income, and
important economic and policy implications. University–industry the formation of spin-off companies.
research collaborations, licensing agreements and university- The objective of this paper is to contribute to the under-
based firms can result in additional revenue for the university and standing of university technology transfer by investigating the
employment opportunities for academic researchers and students. role of policies on performance. Spain makes an interesting case
In addition, technological spillovers may stimulate additional R&D because public spending on R&D has tripled during the last
investment and job creation at local level. decade and technology transfer initiatives have flourished within
The effectiveness of university research commercialisation is Spanish universities (COTEC, 2003). To investigate university tech-
affected by a number of factors. Several papers have shown that nology transfer performance we compile a unique dataset based
technology transfer performance is influenced by university char- on confidential survey data for Spain and investigate the deter-
minants of university performance in three main activities: R&D
university–industry contracts, licensing of technologies and the
creation of spin-offs. For that purpose we estimate a number of
∗ Corresponding author. Present address: O.E.C.D., Economics Department, 2 Rue
performance equations where university technology transfer out-
André Pascal, 75775 Paris CEDEX 16, France. Tel.: +33 1 45 24 15 67;
comes are expressed as a function of three main determinants:
fax: +33 1 44 30 63 83.
E-mail addresses: aida.calderasanchez@oecd.org (A. Caldera), university technology transfer policies, technology intermediaries,
o.debande@eib.org (O. Debande). such as technology transfer offices and science parks, and univer-

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.respol.2010.05.016
A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173 1161

sity characteristics in terms of size, research quality, ownership and Schankerman, 2008), we find mixed evidence regarding the effect
technological orientation. The empirical results are controlled for of TTO characteristics on licensing and the creation of spin-offs.
regional and general macro-economic effects and for the poten- The characteristics of the TTO do not influence university licens-
tial endogeneity of university policies and performance using the ing activities and only the size of the TTO, but not its experience,
pre-sample scaling approach developed by Blundell et al. (1999, positively affects the rate of creation of spin-offs.
2002). The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. The next sec-
Our paper expands on the existing literature in various respects. tion identifies the determinants of university technology transfer
To begin with, we investigate the role of university policies on performance, paying special attention to the particularities of the
technology transfer performance. The theoretical literature on Spanish case. Section 3 describes the dataset. Section 4 presents the
university technology transfer underscores the importance of well- empirical framework that underlies the empirical work and Section
defined university intellectual property policies to motivate the 5 describes the baseline econometric results and Section 6 a robust-
participation of researchers in technology transfer activities (e.g. ness check with respect to the potential endogeneity of university
Macho-Stadler et al., 1996; Lach and Schankerman, 2008). How- policies. The concluding remarks in Section 7 summarise the main
ever, except for a few studies, notably Lach and Schankerman findings and give indications for future research.
(2004, 2008), there is little empirical evidence on the effect of uni-
versity policies on technology transfer performance. The richness 2. Determinants of university technology transfer
of our dataset allows us to investigate the effects of university performance
rewarding systems, the procedures for disclosure of inventions, and
university spin-off policies on performance. Secondly, rather than This section describes the main determinants of university per-
focusing on one single outcome, we examine multiple measures formance based on previous literature. To facilitate the discussion
of university performance. Previous research has studied univer- we classify the determinants into three categories: (1) university
sity performance in licensing or the creation of spin-offs (e.g. Lach technology transfer policies, (2) technology transfer intermedi-
and Schankerman, 2008; Chukumba and Jensen, 2005), but there is aries, and (3) the institutional characteristics of the university.
far less evidence on university–industry R&D contracts, despite the
importance of this source of revenue for European universities. Sur- 2.1. University technology transfer policies
vey evidence presented by Conti and Gaulé (2008) shows that these
contracts are at least as important as license agreements to a large Previous studies have underlined the importance of universi-
number of European universities. Thirdly, we are the first to inves- ties’ policies and in particular their institutional strategic approach
tigate the performance of Spanish universities in the transfer of towards the valorisation of their research (Siegel et al., 2007). In
technology. There are very few studies analysing the performance most countries, universities aim at facilitating the transfer of their
of European universities (e.g. Chapple et al., 2005; Conti and Gaulé, know-how in a fast and efficient way into commercial activities
2008, 2009; Sapsalis et al., 2006) and this study contributes to fill (European Commission, 2008). Debackere and Veugelers (2005)
this gap. Finally, we go one step further than the existing litera- argue that to achieve this objective universities need to set up a
ture and not only investigate the role of technology transfer offices clear strategy, notably a set of guidelines to manage the transfer of
(TTOs) on performance, but also of university science parks. By tak- technology, without hampering the other, fundamental, university
ing into account the role of science parks the analysis is enlarged missions of teaching and research.
and considers the potential geographical spillovers from science An important barrier in the commercialisation of university
parks on university performance. research is the failure of academics to disclose their inventions
Our results suggest that university policies are important deter- to the university TTO (Siegel et al., 2003, 2007). Recent evidence
minants of university technology transfer performance. First, we suggests that adequate university policies may contribute to solv-
find that universities with internal rules regulating the participa- ing this problem. Jensen and Thursby (2001) and Macho-Stadler
tion of researchers in the transfer of technology perform better than et al. (1996) show that well-defined licensing contracts can act as
universities without such internal rules. The results show that uni- an incentive mechanism to stimulate inventors to disclose their
versities with a rule on the potential conflict of interest between inventions and to participate in the commercialisation process.
researchers’ academic and external activities perform better. These Additional evidence by Lach and Schankerman (2008) shows that
results suggest that well-defined university rules improve perfor- American universities giving a higher share of royalties to the
mance by giving researchers incentives to participate in the transfer inventor generate more inventions and higher licensing income.
of technology, confirming the insights from the theoretical litera- This incentive effect appears to work both by inducing the sorting
ture analysing the management structure and incentive schemes of scientists across universities and by increasing scientists’ efforts.
within universities (e.g. Aghion et al., 2005; Macho-Stadler et al.,
1996, 2007; Lach and Schankerman, 2008). Second, we find that 2.2. Technology transfer intermediaries
universities allocating a larger proportion of royalties to the inven-
tor generate more licensing income, in line with evidence by Lach To manage the transfer of technology between the suppliers of
and Schankerman (2008) for the US. Finally, universities granting innovations (university scientists) and those who can potentially
researchers leave of absence for setting-up a spin-off company are commercialise them universities establish specialised intermedi-
more successful in creating spin-offs. And so are universities with ary structures. University TTOs are typically the most important
a stake in a risk capital fund confirming the importance of uni- intermediaries in the commercialisation of university research.
versities’ venture capital funds in bridging the financing gap for However, university science parks may also play a role on university
university-based spin-offs. performance to the extent that science parks are created with the
The results further show that universities with a science park purpose to generate knowledge clusters and improving the transfer
perform better than universities without a science park suggesting of technology between universities and industries.
possible spillovers from science parks on university performance.
Moreover, universities with larger and more experienced TTOs 2.2.1. Technology transfer offices
generate more and larger revenue from R&D contracts. By con- In Spain TTOs are the main institutions responsible for the trans-
trast, contrary to previous evidence on American universities (e.g. fer of university research (RedOTRI, 2006). University researchers
Jensen and Thursby, 2001; Thursby and Kemp, 2002; Lach and are required by the university charter to disclose their inventions to
1162 A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173

the university TTO. Almost every Spanish university has a TTO pro- Moreover, a number of studies have shown that private univer-
viding a number of services including: (i) evaluation of the quality sities achieve better performance in terms of scientific publications
of inventions disclosed by researchers, (ii) support for patent appli- and technology transfer activity (Adams and Griliches, 1998; Siegel
cation, (iii) negotiation of licensing contracts, (iv) contact point for et al., 2003). Lach and Schankerman (2008) suggest that a poten-
collaborative and contract research, and (v) support for researchers tial reason for that is that scientists at private institutions are more
in the creation of university-based spin-offs. responsive to royalty incentives. They also show that TTOs are also
Previous research on TTOs identifies a number of key factors more effective in private universities, suggesting that such institu-
impacting TTO productivity (e.g. Belenzon and Schankerman, 2009; tions are more commercially orientated.
Chukumba and Jensen, 2005; Coupé, 2003; Siegel et al., 2003;
Thursby and Kemp, 2002). This research shows that successful tech- 3. Data description
nology transfer not only depends on the quality of the research
and the involvement of the inventor, but crucially also on the size The key source of our data is the RedOTRI technology transfer
and the experience of the TTO. Among others, Siegel et al. (2003) survey, which is conducted annually by the network of Spanish
find that larger TTOs generate more technology transfer outcomes. university technology transfer offices (RedOTRI). This unique sur-
Friedman and Silberman (2003) and Lach and Schankerman (2004) vey provides us with confidential data on universities’ technology
find that older TTOs execute more licenses, suggesting that effi- transfer activities for 52 universities out of 71 universities in Spain
ciency gains arise as TTOs gain experience in the management of over 2001–2005. The dataset is representative of the Spanish pop-
university technology transfer. Friedman and Silberman (2003) fur- ulation of universities. On average it covers over 70% of Spanish
ther suggest that TTO’s age matters since successful TTOs need to universities, which account for the great majority of academic
build a qualitative portfolio of inventions, which is time intensive. scientists (97%), students (78%) and research production (91%) mea-
sured in terms of completed doctoral thesis.
The survey gives annual information for each university on three
2.2.2. University science parks
types of technology transfer outcomes: the number and income
About half of all Spanish universities have a science park. Based
from university–industry R&D contracts, the number and income
on the definition by the national organisation of science parks, uni-
from licensing contracts and the number of spin-offs created with
versity science parks aim at facilitating the interaction between
the support of the university TTO. In addition, the survey provides
universities and firms located in the park and the creation and
information on university technology transfer policies, the charac-
growth of firms resulting from university research (APTE, 2006).
teristics of the TTO and whether or not the university has a science
Although the literature on university technology transfer has
park. On university technology transfer policies, the survey asks
not investigated the role of science parks in the process, previ-
universities whether or not they have internal rules regulating the
ous research suggests the importance of geographic proximity for
following aspects: (i) the procedure for disclosure of an invention
successful university–industry relations (Agrawal and Cockburn,
to the TTO; (ii) the ownership and distribution of the copyrights
2003). For instance Mansfield (1998), who explores the relationship
from commercialisation of inventions; (iii) academic scientist con-
between academic and industrial R&D suggests that universities
flict of interests between teaching and other external activities;
are more likely to license technology to firms located nearby as
(iv) the participation of university academic scientists/researchers
the further development of the technology often requires ongoing
in R&D contracts; and (v) the participation of university academic
collaborative efforts. We distinguish two main channels through
scientists/researchers in the creation of a spin-off.
which sciences park may influence university technology transfer
In addition the survey provides annual information on two
performance. First, geographical proximity facilitates information
university policies to support the creation of spin-offs. First, on
flows, reducing searching and monitoring costs and increasing
whether or not the university has a programme to help researchers
the probability of successful university–industry relations. Sec-
to create spin-offs. And second, on whether the university has a
ond, science parks provide support infrastructure for the further
stake in a risk capital fund to finance the early stages of spin-offs.
development of inventions. Given that the majority of university
To conclude the survey gives annual information on the character-
inventions are in an embryonic stage at the moment of disclosure,
istics of the TTO including the number and fields of specialisation of
these incubation services can facilitate the development and test-
the personnel working at the TTO, the year the TTO was created, on
ing of the new technology and the sharing of development costs
university ownership (private/public), and whether the university
(Jensen and Thursby, 2001; Siegel et al., 2003).
has a science park and a medical school or not.
To complement the survey information, we compile data on the
2.3. University characteristics university size, research quality and royalty sharing arrangements
from public sources. We compile yearly information on the number
The last determinant of university technology transfer perfor- of academic staff working in each university from the annual survey
mance the literature suggests is the institutional characteristics of on university education by the Spanish national statistical institute.
the university. A number of recent empirical studies have found To measure university research quality, we use three indicators.
that the size of the university is positively related to the amount First, we construct a quality index for each university as the ratio of
of technology transfer (e.g. Belenzon and Schankerman, 2009). the number of publications in top scientific journals per researcher
Besides size, previous research finds that the research quality of based on the study of Moya-Anegón et al. (2007) that covers publi-
the university also matters. Universities producing higher qual- cations in the Science Citation Index, the Social Citation Index and
ity research generate more licenses and higher licensing income the Arts & Humanities Index. We construct a second indicator using
as shown by Chukumba and Jensen (2005). Thursby and Kemp information on the number of invention disclosures to the TTO
(2002) further suggest that the portfolio of disciplines offered by available from the RedOTRI Survey for the years 2003 and 2005.
the university can also play a distinctive role as some fields of study And third, we use information on the percentage of professors that
are more likely to produce research more attractive for industries. obtained a research leave and on the average number of research
Recent empirical studies support this hypothesis and show that the leaves per faculty from the Foundation CYD survey. Research leaves
presence of biomedical and engineering faculties appear to be asso- are granted to university academic scientists by a National Commit-
ciated with higher levels of patenting and licensing activity (e.g. tee based on the number of international publications and therefore
Lach and Schankerman, 2008). are expected to be correlated with research performance. To con-
A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173 1163

Table 1
Summary statistics, 2001–2005.

Variable Mean Median SD Min Max

Income R&D contracts (thousands of Euros) 4,614 2,898 5,695 0 57,900


Number R&D contracts 180 132 167 0 878
Income licenses (thousands of Euros) 31 4 97 0 483
Number of licensing agreements 2 1 4 0 35
Number of spin-offs 2 1 4 0 31

Regulation R&D contracts (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.82 1 0.39 0 1


Regulation spin-offs (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.35 0 0.48 0 1
Regulation conflicts of interest (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.06 0 0.23 0 1
Regulation copyrights (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.34 0 0.47 0 1
Regulation invention disclosures (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.81 1 0.39 0 1
Spin-off program (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.65 1 0.48 0 1
Access to financing (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.19 0 0.39 0 1
Share of licensing royalties for inventor (%) 53.04 50 12.44 20 90

TTO size (no. employees) 11 7 10 1 58


TTO age 12 13 4 1 20
Specialized employees in R&D contracts (%) 20 18 13 0 70
Specialized employees in licensing (%) 5 5 4 0 25
Specialized employees in spin-offs (%) 6 5 5 0 25
Science park (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.46 0 0.50 0 1

University size (no. faculty) 1,659 1,320 1,152 151 6,197


No. of publications per faculty 3.06 1.42 4.26 0.04 20.01
Percentage of faculty with research leave 53.10 52.50 11.68 28.00 80.00
Average no. of research leaves per faculty 1.08 1.01 0.38 0.50 2.16
No. invention disclosures to the TTO 10.51 6.00 11.31 0 42.00
University ownership (public = 1, private = 0) 0.86 1 0.35 0 1
Medical school (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.55 1 0.50 0 1
Polytechnic school (yes = 1, no = 0) 0.07 0 0.25 1 0

clude, we compile information on the share of the royalties from as previously employed in the literature. We estimate the following
licensing an invention that goes to the inventor, from the study on baseline equation:
Spanish universities patenting rules by González-Albo Manglano
Yit = ˇ0 + ˇ1 Policiesi + ˇ2 ScParkit + ˇ3 TTOit + Zit B + ˛r + ˛t + εit
and Zulueta Garca (2007).
Table 1 gives some basic descriptive statistics over 2001–2005. (1)
We observe quite some variation in performance among univer-
sities. The median R&D contract is only about half the mean and where Yit is the outcome variable for university i in year t cap-
differences in performance among universities are even larger turing the university performance. We consider five measures
in the number of spin-offs, and especially in terms of licensing of performance: the log of R&D contracts income, the number
agreements signed and income generated. While not displayed in of R&D contracts, the log of licensing income, the number of
Table 1, the distribution of outcomes over universities is particu- licensing agreements and the number of spin-offs.2 The explana-
larly skewed to the right for licensing and spin-offs, with almost tory variables include university policies (Policiesi ) the technology
half of the universities generating zero licensing and spin-offs. In transfer intermediaries, science park (ScParkit ) and TTO (TTOit ), and
what follows, we investigate formally the determinants of univer- other university characteristics, Zit . Region fixed effects ˛r con-
sity performance in R&D contracts, licensing and spin-off creation trol for regional differences in economic conditions and annual
using regression analysis. fixed effects, ˛t , take into account macro-economic shocks, such as
changes in national policies or revenue shocks affecting university
funding.
4. Empirical model and estimation method
4.1. University technology transfer policies
In order to investigate the determinants of university technol-
ogy transfer performance we estimate a series of performance
The first set of determinants, covers university policies in three
equations where technology transfer outcomes are expressed as
areas: the management of the technology transfer process, royalty
a function of the main determinants identified by the previous
sharing arrangements and support for spin-off creation. We mea-
literature and discussed in Section 2. The baseline specification
sure each policy by dummy variables taking the value 1 whenever
is a model similar to those specified by Lach and Schankerman
the university has an internal rule and 0 otherwise. In general, we
(2004, 2008) and Chukumba and Jensen (2005). A number of studies
expect universities with a given internal rule to perform better than
use frontier analysis instead and construct a best practice fron-
universities without one. As discussed in Section 2, survey evidence
tier using data on universities’ inputs and outputs (e.g. Chapple
et al., 2005; Thursby and Kemp, 2002). Two methods are typically
used to estimate the best practice frontier: data envelopment anal-
ing all deviations from the frontier to technical inefficiency. SFE is very inflexible, as
ysis (DEA) and stochastic frontier estimation (SFE). However, both
it requires making strong assumptions about the functional form of the production
of these methods have well-known drawbacks (Van Biesebroeck, function and about the structure of the error term.
2007).1 For this reason we prefer to use linear regression analysis, 2
It should, however, be stressed that using the number of spin-offs as a perfor-
mance measure may not be a reliable indicator of good performance if spin-offs
survival depends on the financial support of the university. In that case, it would
be advisable to complement the information on the number of spin-offs with infor-
1
DEA is deterministic, thus sensitive to measurement errors and outliers, which mation on spin-off growth and rate of survival. However this type of data is not
can lead to upwardly biased estimates of the technical efficiency scores by attribut- available for Spain.
1164 A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173

by Jensen et al. (2003) shows that university researchers often do commercialise it.3 Third, the effect of ownership on performance,
not disclose valuable inventions to the TTO. Such rules can help measured by a dummy variable taking the value 1 if the university
to reduce information asymmetries by clarifying researchers’ role is public and 0 if the university is private, is not obvious. On the one
and benefits from commercialising the technology and increase hand, as suggested by Belenzon and Schankerman (2009), private
researchers’ incentives to participate in technology transfer activ- universities may be more flexible and have closer ties with firms
ities. leading to better private universities’ performance. On the other
An additional policy variable that enters Eq. (1) is the percentage hand, public universities in Spain are generally older than private
of royalties from licensing an invention that goes to the inven- ones, so more likely to have longer research experience and mar-
tor. Lach and Schankerman (2004, 2008) show that royalty sharing ket reputation, which may translate into better performance. To
arrangements are key determinants of performance. They show conclude, we control for university research orientation with two
that American universities awarding a larger share of licensing dummy variables: a medical school dummy taking the value 1 if the
income to the inventor generate more income. Finally, the spin- university has a medical school and 0 otherwise, and a polytechnic
off equation includes a dummy variable measuring whether or university dummy, takes the value 1 if the university is polytechnic
not the university has a spin-off programme and a dummy vari- and 0 otherwise. The university’s technical orientation is expected
able measuring whether the university has a stake in a risk capital to influence performance, as universities specialised in fields like
fund. Anecdotal evidence from Spain suggests that university pro- biotechnology or technical sciences will be more likely to generate
grammes to support the creation of spin-offs are key for university valuable research output for the business sector than universities
success in creating spin-offs. Furthermore, given that university specialised in social sciences.
spin-offs typically face major obstacles to access funding due to
information asymmetry and uncertainty, university-affiliated ven- 4.4. Estimation method
ture capital funds may boost spin-off creation by bridging the
financing gap. We estimate Eq. (1) pooling the data over the sample period
and clustering the error terms at university level to control for
intra-university serial correlation. We do not use panel regression
4.2. Technology transfer intermediaries techniques because a variance decomposition of the dependent
variables shows that most of the relevant variation in the data is
The second set of determinants are technology transfer interme- cross-sectional. The equations having as dependent variable the
diaries: the university technology transfer office„ and the university logs of R&D contract income and licensing income are estimated
science parks,. The vector includes TTO characteristics covering by OLS.4 The equations having as dependent variable the count of
standard measures such as TTO size, proxied by the number of pro- the number of R&D contracts, licenses and spin-offs, are estimated
fessionals working at the TTO, and age, measured by the number using a Negative Binomial model.
of years the TTO has been operational. In line with the existing An alternative approach for modelling the count variables would
literature, we expect TTO size and age to positively affect uni- be to use the common Poisson formulation, but, as pointed out by
versity performance. In larger TTOs staff may specialise in those Hausman et al. (1984), the Poisson model is highly restrictive, since
areas where they have a specific expertise. Older TTOs should be it imposes a data distribution for which the mean is equal to its vari-
more experienced in the management and valorisation of technol- ance. As discussed in the data section the outcome variables show
ogy transfer (e.g. Conti and Gaulé, 2009). Additionally, we include a a significant amount of over-dispersion with high standard devia-
measure of TTO specialisation proxied by the share of TTO profes- tions and notable differences between the mean and median values
sionals specialised in each type of technology transfer outcome. As (see Table 1). Hence, the Negative Binomial specification, which is
described in Section 2, Spanish TTOs provide a broad range of ser- a generalisation of the Poisson distribution, to take into account
vices, and we expect higher TTO specialisation in a given outcome to over-dispersion may be more appropriate. We validate below the
lead to better university performance through economies of scale. choice of the Negative Binomial over the Poisson model conducting
We measure the presence of a university science park by a dummy a likelihood test of the over-dispersion parameter and showing that
variable taking the value 1 if the university has a science park and it is significantly different from zero, which reinforces our choice
0 otherwise. We expect the presence of a university science park to of the Negative Binomial model.
positively affect university technology transfer performance. Geo-
graphical proximity enhances science-industry relations (Agrawal
5. Baseline empirical results
and Cockburn, 2003). In addition, university science parks usually
host technology incubators, which decrease development costs and
5.1. R&D contracts
facilitate spin-off formation. Both of these factors can contribute to
increasing the transfer of technology.
Table 2 reports the parameter estimates for Eq. (1) with
two alternative dependent variables: R&D contracts income and
number of R&D contracts. All regressions take into account inter-
4.3. University characteristics
university correlations clustering the error terms at university
The vector Zit controls for more general university characteris-
tics like size, research quality, ownership and technical orientation
3
identified by the literature as having an influence on university We also experimented with two other proxies for university research quality
(the number of invention disclosures and the percentage of academic scientists hav-
technology transfer performance (e.g. Belenzon and Schankerman,
ing been granted a research leave), but the results on the variables of interest do not
2009; Siegel et al., 2003; Thursby and Kemp, 2002). First, university change and they are not significant, so we did not report them. These results are
size measured by the number of academic scientists is expected available from the authors upon request.
4
to positively affect performance as larger universities are likely As suggested by one referee, the error terms in the specifications with log R&D
to generate more research. Second, university research quality, contracts and log licensing income might be correlated. Therefore as an alternative
we jointly estimated the equations using seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR). The
measured by the number of publications in top scientific jour- Breusch Pagan test of independence indicates that the error terms in both equations
nals per researcher, is expected to positively affect performance as are not correlated, therefore individual OLS estimates are prefered. The results from
universities generating higher quality research could more easily the SUR test are available upon request.
Table 2
Baseline regression results for R&D contracts.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number
income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D
contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts

TTO size 0.601 0.503 0.548 0.426 0.538 0.374 0.505 0.369 0.487 0.345 0.443 0.261 0.505 0.375 0.508 0.375
(0.134)*** (0.084)*** (0.136)*** (0.084)*** (0.138)*** (0.084)*** (0.136)*** (0.084)*** (0.136)*** (0.080)*** (0.136)*** (0.075)*** (0.136)*** (0.083)*** (0.137)*** (0.083)***
TTO age 0.038 0.043 0.041 0.057 0.042 0.057 0.050 0.072 0.027 0.030 0.041 0.055 0.040 0.052
(0.019)** (0.012)*** (0.020)** (0.013)*** (0.020)** (0.013)*** (0.021)** (0.012)*** (0.021) (0.011)*** (0.020)** (0.012)*** (0.021)* (0.013)***
TTO specialization in 0.003 0.012 0.004 0.012 0.005 0.014 0.001 0.005 0.004 0.012 0.004 0.012
R&D contracts
(0.005) (0.003)*** (0.005) (0.003)*** (0.005) (0.003)*** (0.005) (0.003)* (0.005) (0.003)*** (0.005) (0.003)***
Science park dummy 0.327 0.120 0.320 0.102 0.272 0.007 0.288 0.097 0.332 0.127
(0.119)*** (0.073)* (0.119)*** (0.069) (0.119)** (0.064) (0.123)** (0.073) (0.120)*** (0.073)*

A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173


Rule on R&D contract −0.377 −0.686
dummy
(0.239) (0.144)***
Rule on conflict of 1.017 1.471
interests dummy
(0.385)*** (0.202)***
Rule on copyrights −0.158 −0.146
dummy
(0.128) (0.082)*
Rule on invention 0.066 0.181
disclosures dummy
(0.177) (0.113)

Controls for university characteristics


University size 0.960 0.762 0.791 0.586 0.780 0.548 0.757 0.544 0.721 0.485 0.896 0.791 0.750 0.538 0.756 0.542
(0.118)*** (0.076)*** (0.145)*** (0.088)*** (0.147)*** (0.086)*** (0.145)*** (0.086)*** (0.146)*** (0.083)*** (0.152)*** (0.081)*** (0.145)*** (0.086)*** (0.145)*** (0.085)***
Number of 0.047 0.074 0.046 0.072 0.047 0.077 0.055 0.080 0.051 0.074 0.050 0.072 0.050 0.077 0.056 0.083
publications/faculty
(0.018)** (0.012)*** (0.018)** (0.012)*** (0.018)** (0.011)*** (0.018)*** (0.011)*** (0.018)*** (0.011)*** (0.018)*** (0.010)*** (0.018)*** (0.011)*** (0.018)*** (0.012)***
Public university 0.614 1.047 0.638 1.012 0.682 1.229 0.711 1.247 0.844 1.501 0.489 0.853 0.751 1.310 0.729 1.290
dummy
(0.270)** (0.174)*** (0.268)** (0.168)*** (0.285)** (0.175)*** (0.280)** (0.175)*** (0.291)*** (0.173)*** (0.288)* (0.163)*** (0.281)*** (0.176)*** (0.285)** (0.177)***
Medical school dummy 0.097 0.385 0.093 0.363 0.084 0.315 0.096 0.315 0.186 0.469 0.024 0.193 0.093 0.313 0.105 0.336
(0.143) (0.090)*** (0.142) (0.088)*** (0.144) (0.087)*** (0.141) (0.086)*** (0.152) (0.088)*** (0.141) (0.077)** (0.141) (0.086)*** (0.143) (0.087)***
Polytechnic university 0.543 −0.107 0.521 −0.110 0.536 −0.031 0.510 −0.039 0.541 0.025 0.607 0.155 0.532 −0.026 0.516 −0.018
dummy
(0.191)*** (0.120) (0.190)*** (0.118) (0.193)*** (0.117) (0.189)*** (0.117) (0.190)*** (0.109) (0.190)*** (0.103) (0.190)*** (0.117) (0.191)*** (0.117)

R-squared 0.74 – 0.74 – 0.74 – 0.75 – 0.76 – 0.76 – 0.75 – 0.75 –


Likelihood ratio test of – 5013.82 – 4274.12 – 3972.40 – 3950.70 – 3673.41 – 2445.13 – 3953.33 – 3596.78
alpha = 0 statistics
Probability – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000
Observations 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206

Notes: Results from estimating Eq. (1) with log R&D contracts income and number of R&D contracts as dependent variables. Income refers to the income from R&D contracts. Number refers to the number of R&D contracts. The
income equations are estimated by OLS, while the number equations are estimated using a Negative Binomial model. Robust standard errors, reported in brackets, are clustered at the university level. ***, **, * denote statistical
significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively. All regressions include a constant and a complete set of region and year dummies.

1165
1166 A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173

level. Each column of Table 2 reports alternative specifications of income than private universities. Finally, the presence of a medi-
Eq. (1) where the various explanatory variables enter subsequently. cal school has no effect on R&D contract income, but has a positive
The different specifications are controlled regional and year fixed and highly significant effect on the number of R&D contracts. On
effects. the other hand, the dummy for polytechnic universities has a posi-
Considering the effect of TTO characteristics, columns (1)–(8) tive effect on R&D contract income, but no effect on the number of
show that larger TTO size is associated with better performance. contracts.
An increase in TTO size of one professional (about a 10% increase)
is associated with a rise in R&D contract income of about 44–60 5.2. Licenses
percentage points. As shown in columns (2)–(8), the number and
income from R&D contracts are higher for older TTOs. An additional The results from estimating Eq. (1) with licensing income and
year of TTO experience translates to an increase in R&D income number of licenses as dependent variables are reported in Table 3.
of between 4 and 5 percentage points, depending on the speci- A number of interesting findings emerge. First, TTO characteris-
fications. Columns (3)–(8) show that TTO specialisation on R&D tics affect university licensing performance less than in the case
contracts does not appear to significantly impact R&D contracts of R&D contracts. Although TTO size has a positive and signifi-
income, however, TTO specialisation has a significant and positive cant effect on the number of licenses, it has no effect on licensing
effect on the number of R&D contracts generated. This result might income (columns 1–8 in Table 3). TTO age does not significantly
indicate that TTO incentives are biased in favour of maximising the affect licensing activity, except for three out of fourteen specifica-
number of contracts, irrespective of the flow of income generated tions where size has a negative effect on licensing income. Finally,
by such contracts. TTO specialisation has no effect on licensing outcomes. One possi-
Regarding the role of science parks, columns (4)–(8) show that ble reason for the lack of impact of TTO characteristics might result
universities with a science park generate more R&D income than from the fact that Spanish TTO offices are primarily focused on the
universities without one. Universities with a science park generate management of R&D contracts, having very limited expertise on
about 30% more income than universities without one. However, licensing activities and the creation of spin-offs.
the effect of science parks on the number of R&D contracts, although Second, we find that universities with a science park gener-
positive, is only significant in two out of five specifications, and only ate a higher licensing income, but science parks have no effect
at the 10% level. This result may suggest that science parks are a on the number of licenses. Although the coefficient on the sci-
source of positive spillovers for universities leading to higher R&D ence park dummy is only significant at 10% in four out of five
contracts income. Spillovers may materialise through researchers’ specifications, this result tends to suggest that the local concen-
interaction with firms located in the science park and the exchange tration of high-tech firms has a positive effect on the volume of
of ideas which is facilitated by close proximity. licensing operations. Technology-intensive firms located in science
Columns (5)–(8) of Table 2 explore the effects of university tech- parks generate demand for university research, notably via licens-
nology transfer policies on R&D contract activity. These variables ing deals. According to the Spanish association of science parks
enter one by one into the equation because they are alternative (APTE, 2006), biotech firms, firms in the semi-conductors industry,
proxies for the university technology transfer policies and institu- and IT firms represent most of the companies located in univer-
tional regulatory framework. First, the university rule on conflicts sity science parks in Spain. These sectors are research intensive
of interest has a positive effect on the amount and volume of R&D and are expected to create a substantial demand for university
contracts (column 6 of Table 2). This result indicates that a regu- research.
lation clarifying potential conflicts of interest between researchers Table 3 further shows that the university royalty sharing pol-
teaching and external activities can improve performance by reduc- icy significantly affects licensing income, but has no effect on the
ing moral hazard problems and uncertainty in the appropriation of number of licenses. The estimated coefficient of the inventor roy-
revenues from external research activities. alty share is positive and highly significant (column 5 of Table 3).
Second, the university rule on the participation of researchers The size of the coefficient suggests that an increase of 10% points
in R&D contracts has a negative effect on the number of R&D con- in the inventor’s share should generate, on average, about an 80%
tracts, but no effect on income. The same result is obtained for the increase in license income, which would imply an increase from
rule on copyrights from inventions, which has a negative, although EUR 46,000 to EUR 83,000 in average licensing income.
only significant at the 10%, effect on the number of R&D contracts, Regarding the impact of the university technology transfer rules,
but no effect on income. Both results may have a similar inter- only the variable indicating whether a university has a rule to deal
pretation. These rules give the university the right to share with with conflicts of interest has an impact on licensing activities. The
the researcher the benefits from the commercialisation of the IPR rule on conflict of interests has a positive and significant effect
generated by an external research activity. This result therefore on licensing income and on the number of licenses (column 6 of
suggests that such rules hurt university commercialisation activity Table 3). The rules on copyrights and invention disclosures have no
by decreasing researchers’ incentives to engage in external activ- effect on licensing activity.
ities. Finally, the variable measuring whether the university has a With respect to the effect of the other university control vari-
rule on the procedure to disclose inventions has no effect on R&D ables, the results indicate that larger universities generate more
activity. license income and more licenses, as shown in columns (1)–(8)
Regarding the remaining variables that control for differences of Table 3. This finding supports the results of Belenzon and
in university characteristics reported at the bottom of Table 2, we Schankerman (2009), Chukumba and Jensen (2005) and Siegel et
find, first, that university size, measured by the number of aca- al. (2003) for US universities. Technical universities produce a
demic scientists working at the university, has a significant positive higher licensing income and more licenses, as given by the posi-
effect on both R&D contract income and number of contracts. Sec- tive and significant effect of the polytechnic dummy on licensing
ond, the amount and volume of R&D contracts are higher for better income. This result, although not consistent across all specifica-
research universities. This result suggests that universities with a tions, reflects the fact that technical universities mainly produce
good track record in terms of scientific publication attract more applied research with a higher commercialisation potential. The
research contracts from firms than lesser performing universities. other university variables are not significant except for the pub-
Third, the estimated coefficient on the public university dummy lic ownership dummy and quality of the university that have a
indicates that public universities generate more R&D contracts and negative effect on the number of licenses. The negative effect
Table 3
Baseline regression results for licensing.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number
income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses

TTO size 0.078 0.946 0.350 0.920 0.425 0.899 0.434 0.913 0.981 −0.089 −0.212 0.245 0.417 0.912 0.498 0.925
(0.804) (0.334)*** (0.819) (0.346)*** (0.836) (0.350)** (0.828) (0.353)*** (1.112) (0.390) (0.813) (0.340) (0.831) (0.356)** (0.837) (0.350)***
TTO age −0.173 0.014 −0.190 0.018 −0.200 0.016 −0.065 0.012 −0.286 −0.048 −0.183 0.017 −0.214 0.006
(0.113) (0.049) (0.119) (0.051) (0.118)* (0.052) (0.193) (0.072) (0.115)** (0.052) (0.121) (0.054) (0.120)* (0.052)
TTO specialization in 0.042 −0.015 0.071 −0.014 0.098 −0.044 0.058 −0.051 0.059 −0.014 0.076 −0.017
licensing
(0.087) (0.037) (0.088) (0.037) (0.117) (0.039) (0.084) (0.036) (0.090) (0.038) (0.088) (0.037)
Science park dummy 1.232 −0.103 0.378 −0.518 0.812 −0.432 1.294 −0.103 1.284 −0.064

A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173


(0.677)* (0.273) (0.875) (0.366) (0.658) (0.257)* (0.687)* (0.274) (0.684)* (0.271)
Inventor royalty share 0.083 −0.005
(0.047)*** (0.022)
Rule on conflict of 7.476 3.722
interests dummy
(2.105)*** (0.660)***
Rule on copyrights 0.440 0.006
dummy
(0.769) (0.315)
Rule on invention 0.763 1.070
disclosures dummy
(1.274) (0.672)

Controls for university characteristics


University size 2.890 1.146 3.508 1.110 3.497 1.120 3.370 1.130 4.245 1.397 4.328 2.175 3.362 1.130 3.341 1.271
(0.694)*** (0.313)*** (0.800)*** (0.338)*** (0.802)*** (0.340)*** (0.798)*** (0.342)*** (1.298)*** (0.498)*** (0.809)*** (0.401)*** (0.800)*** (0.342)*** (0.802)*** (0.356)***
University quality 0.023 −0.166 0.051 −0.169 0.050 −0.165 0.083 −0.171 0.158 −0.242 0.059 −0.159 0.092 −0.171 0.092 −0.147
(0.116) (0.088)* (0.117) (0.089)* (0.117) (0.088)* (0.117) (0.089)* (0.175) (0.164) (0.112) (0.091)* (0.119) (0.090)* (0.119) (0.086)*
Public university dummy −0.026 −3.026 0.110 −3.071 0.141 −3.080 0.118 −3.105 −3.849 13.905 −1.282 −3.843 −0.042 −3.107 0.248 −2.986
(1.743) (0.878)*** (1.736) (0.893)*** (1.742) (0.889)*** (1.726) (0.890)*** (3.196) (686.210) (1.697) (0.890)*** (1.753) (0.895)*** (1.744) (0.868)***
Medical school dummy −0.534 0.139 −0.394 0.119 −0.283 0.086 −0.089 0.080 −2.707 0.042 −0.793 −0.646 −0.119 0.080 0.009 0.082
(0.830) (0.338) (0.831) (0.345) (0.864) (0.355) (0.863) (0.356) (1.335)** (0.515) (0.849) (0.360)* (0.867) (0.357) (0.880) (0.356)
Polytechnic university 3.024 0.625 3.399 0.606 3.428 0.603 3.245 0.613 1.816 1.944 4.440 1.543 3.153 0.612 3.222 0.527
dummy
(1.070)*** (0.378)* (1.092)*** (0.384) (1.097)*** (0.383) (1.092)*** (0.384) (1.556) (0.441)*** (1.097)*** (0.367)*** (1.107)*** (0.389) (1.095)*** (0.383)

R-squared 0.57 – 0.58 – 0.58 – 0.59 – 0.67 – 0.63 – 0.59 – 0.59 –


Likelihood ratio test of – 105.07 – 104.08 – 103.19 – 101.95 – 93.63 – 57.46 – 101.66 – 96.55
alpha = 0 statistics
Probability – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000
Observations 154 148 154 148 154 148 154 148 101 116 154 148 154 148 154 148

Notes: Results from estimating equation (1) with log licensing income and number of licensing agreements as dependent variables. Income refers to the income from licensing contracts. Number refers to the number of licensing
agreements. The income equations are estimated by OLS, while the number equations are estimated using a Negative Binomial model. Robust standard errors, reported in brackets, are clustered at the university level. ***, **, *
denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent level respectively. All regressions include a constant and a complete set of region and year dummies

1167
1168
Table 4
Baseline regression results for spin-offs.

Dependent variable: (1) (2) (3) (6) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
number of spin-offs

TTO size 1.238 1.244 1.270 1.205 1.090 1.286 1.265 1.284 1.011 0.953
(0.275)*** (0.277)*** (0.277)*** (0.277)*** (0.277)*** (0.307)*** (0.276)*** (0.273)*** (0.287)*** (0.277)**
TTO age −0.010 −0.030 −0.036 −0.069 −0.103 −0.020 −0.038 −0.033 0.056
(0.050) (0.052) (0.051) (0.056) (0.053)* (0.051) (0.051) (0.050) (0.062)
TTO specialization in 0.001 0.003 −0.002 −0.024 −0.003 0.003 −0.010 0.008
spin-offs
(0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.022) (0.026) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024)
Science park dummy 0.706 0.513 0.389 0.638 0.651 0.588 0.557
(0.298)** (0.300)* (0.283) (0.299)** (0.293)** (0.303)* (0.302)*
Rule on participation in 0.927
spin-offs dummy

A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173


(0.344)***
Rule on conflict of 2.974
interests dummy
(0.678)***
Rule on copyrights 0.282
dummy
(0.323)
Rule on invention 0.784
disclosures dummy
(0.545)
Spin-off program dummy 0.794
(0.399)**
Risk capital dummy 0.849
(0.426)*

Controls for university characteristics


University size 0.550 0.584 0.597 0.614 0.433 1.112 0.445 0.522 0.441 0.275
(0.313)* (0.358) (0.358)* (0.351)* (0.343) (0.375)*** (0.346) (0.346) (0.361) (0.357)
University quality 0.057 0.056 0.055 0.068 0.019 0.051 0.025 0.047 0.071 0.033
(0.056) (0.056) (0.057) (0.057) (0.059) (0.060) (0.063) (0.060) (0.057) (0.055)
Public university dummy 1.101 1.115 1.134 1.101 0.300 0.831 0.104 0.490 1.082 0.632
(0.621)* (0.625)* (0.652)* (0.654)* (0.704) (0.712) (0.719) (0.708) (0.661) (0.633)
Medical school dummy 0.082 0.094 0.143 0.141 0.677 −0.393 0.330 0.324 0.367 −0.083
(0.322) (0.327) (0.334) (0.325) (0.351)* (0.334) (0.325) (0.322) (0.339) (0.380)
Polytechnic university 0.579 0.597 0.613 0.626 1.269 1.021 0.680 0.721 0.949 0.570
dummy
(0.374) (0.384) (0.427) (0.417) (0.437)*** (0.406)** (0.404)* (0.401)* (0.432)** (0.411)

Log likelihood −284.56 −284.54 −275.69 −272.90 −261.16 −245.29 −264.08 −263.80 −263.93 −255.70
Likelihood ratio test of 146.16 145.92 138.02 133.91 113.53 63.42 115.36 110.54 127.34 115.50
alpha = 0 statistic
Prob 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Observations 158 158 158 158 158 158 158 158 158 158

Notes: Results from estimating Eq. (1) with number of spin-offs as dependent variable using a Negative Binomial model with robust standard errors, reported in brackets, clustered at the university level. ***, ** and * denote
statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively. All regressions include a constant and a complete set of region and year dummies.
Table 5
Robustness results for R&D contracts.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable: R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number R&D Number
income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D income R&D
contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts contracts

TTO size 1.005 0.744 0.783 0.530 0.760 0.472 0.732 0.471 0.694 0.432 0.723 0.445 0.740 0.492 0.730 0.470
(0.135)*** (0.092)*** (0.137)*** (0.088)*** (0.139)*** (0.087)*** (0.138)*** (0.087)*** (0.137)*** (0.082)*** (0.138)*** (0.084)*** (0.138)*** (0.086)*** (0.138)*** (0.086)***
TTO age 0.081 0.088 0.087 0.102 0.089 0.103 0.095 0.113 0.086 0.093 0.089 0.101 0.080 0.093
(0.018)*** (0.013)*** (0.019)*** (0.013)*** (0.019)*** (0.012)*** (0.019)*** (0.012)*** (0.019)*** (0.012)*** (0.019)*** (0.012)*** (0.020)*** (0.014)***
TTO specialization in 0.006 0.015 0.007 0.015 0.008 0.016 0.006 0.012 0.007 0.015 0.007 0.015
licensing
(0.006) (0.004)*** (0.006) (0.004)*** (0.006) (0.003)*** (0.006) (0.003)*** (0.006) (0.003)*** (0.006) (0.004)***

A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173


Science park dummy 0.331 0.137 0.315 0.116 0.314 0.074 0.314 0.117 0.340 0.140
(0.129)** (0.081)* (0.128)** (0.075) (0.131)** (0.079) (0.133)** (0.081) (0.129)*** (0.081)*
Rule on R&D contract −0.550 −0.824
dummy
(0.251)** (0.154)***
Rule on conflict of 0.306 0.837
interests dummy
(0.401) (0.231)***
Rule on copyrights −0.085 −0.176
dummy
(0.142) (0.093)*
Rule on invention 0.211 0.218
disclosures dummy
(0.200) (0.128)*

Controls for university characteristics


University quality 0.048 0.064 0.048 0.065 0.050 0.073 0.058 0.076 0.052 0.071 0.056 0.072 0.056 0.073 0.062 0.080
(0.020)** (0.014)*** (0.019)** (0.013)*** (0.019)** (0.012)*** (0.019)*** (0.012)*** (0.019)*** (0.011)*** (0.019)*** (0.012)*** (0.020)*** (0.012)*** (0.020)*** (0.013)***
Dummy public university 0.942 1.099 0.907 1.050 0.997 1.348 1.029 1.368 1.194 1.671 0.977 1.205 1.057 1.455 1.073 1.407
(0.297)*** (0.200)*** (0.282)*** (0.180)*** (0.297)*** (0.188)*** (0.293)*** (0.187)*** (0.299)*** (0.182)*** (0.301)*** (0.186)*** (0.297)*** (0.190)*** (0.296)*** (0.189)***
Dummy medical school 0.373 0.739 0.254 0.573 0.220 0.479 0.242 0.481 0.342 0.622 0.225 0.427 0.244 0.482 0.250 0.494
(0.149)** (0.098)*** (0.144)* (0.094)*** (0.148) (0.093)*** (0.146)* (0.093)*** (0.152)** (0.090)*** (0.148) (0.090)*** (0.147)* (0.092)*** (0.146)* (0.092)***
Pre-sample patent stock 0.011 0.005 0.006 0.000 0.007 0.001 0.005 0.000 0.006 0.001 0.006 0.002 0.005 −0.000 0.006 0.002
(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.003)** (0.002) (0.003)** (0.002) (0.003)** (0.002) (0.003)** (0.002) (0.003)** (0.002) (0.003)* (0.002) (0.003)** (0.002)

R-squared 0.67 – 0.70 – 0.70 – 0.71 – 0.72 – 0.71 – 0.71 – 0.71 –


Likelihood ratio test of – 5972.81 – 4384.83 – – 4067.16 – 3741.47 – 3506.56 – 3986.90 – 3905.31
alpha = 0
Probability – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000
Observations 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206 206

Notes: Results from estimating equation (1) with log R&D contracts income and number of R&D contracts as dependent variables and adding the pre-sample patent stock to control for university unobserved heterogeneity.
University controls on size and polytechnic school are dropped because they are highly correlated with the patent stock. Income refers to the income from R&D contracts. Number refers to the number of R&D contracts. The
income equations are estimated by OLS, while the number equations are estimated using a Negative Binomial model. Robust standard errors, reported in brackets, are clustered at the university level. ***, **, * denote statistical
significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent level respectively. All regressions include a constant and a complete set of region and year dummies.

1169
1170
Table 6
Robustness results for licensing.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable: Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number Licensing Number
income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses income licenses

TTO size 1.057 0.919 1.085 0.758 1.190 0.749 1.206 0.759 1.626 0.192 1.019 0.609 0.952 0.692 1.194 0.711
(0.776) (0.299)*** (0.832) (0.306)** (0.845) (0.309)** (0.838) (0.311)** (1.124) (0.389) (0.836) (0.302)** (0.843) (0.314)** (0.828) (0.304)**
TTOage −0.010 0.084 −0.042 0.086 −0.052 0.084 0.147 0.084 −0.071 0.079 −0.023 0.095 −0.138 0.061
(0.108) (0.045)* (0.115) (0.046)* (0.115) (0.046)* (0.184) (0.066) (0.114) (0.044)* (0.115) (0.047)** (0.121) (0.047)
TTO specialization in 0.070 −0.007 0.097 −0.006 0.121 −0.029 0.094 −0.017 0.063 −0.013 0.120 −0.005
licensing

A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173


(0.091) (0.035) (0.092) (0.035) (0.123) (0.040) (0.091) (0.034) (0.093) (0.036) (0.092) (0.035)
Science park dummy 1.255 −0.098 0.690 −0.546 1.046 −0.240 1.391 −0.073 1.359 −0.053
(0.712)* (0.272) (0.912) (0.382) (0.714) (0.264) (0.710)* (0.271) (0.706)* (0.267)
Inventor royalty share 0.154 −0.014
(0.050)*** (0.023)
Rule on conflict of interests 3.989 1.833
dummy
(2.138)* (0.619)***
Rule on copyrights dummy 1.444 0.319
(0.810)* (0.307)
Rule on invention 2.743 1.264
disclosures dummy
(1.378)** (0.636)**

Controls for university characteristics


University quality 0.007 −0.162 0.009 −0.171 0.007 −0.171 0.043 −0.176 0.036 −0.410 0.024 −0.190 0.071 −0.166 0.072 −0.154
(0.120) (0.074)** (0.122) (0.072)** (0.122) (0.072)** (0.123) (0.073)** (0.178) (0.172)** (0.122) (0.075)** (0.123) (0.073)** (0.122) (0.072)**
Public university dummy 1.041 −2.442 1.064 −2.752 1.097 −2.766 1.059 −2.783 0.110 15.461 0.453 −3.113 0.484 −2.923 1.410 −2.578
(1.764) (0.788)*** (1.787) (0.799)*** (1.791) (0.801)*** (1.776) (0.803)*** (3.047) (1,623.696) (1.788) (0.801)*** (1.790) (0.803)*** (1.764) (0.789)***
Medical school dummy −0.219 0.346 −0.202 0.197 −0.049 0.186 0.179 0.178 −0.641 0.169 −0.172 −0.114 0.030 0.191 0.375 0.249
(0.795) (0.291) (0.817) (0.300) (0.843) (0.305) (0.846) (0.306) (1.129) (0.438) (0.858) (0.304) (0.842) (0.305) (0.841) (0.302)
Pre-sample patent stock 0.047 0.016 0.048 0.012 0.049 0.012 0.045 0.013 0.025 0.019 0.051 0.017 0.051 0.013 0.053 0.016
(0.013)*** (0.005)*** (0.014)*** (0.005)** (0.014)*** (0.005)** (0.014)*** (0.005)** (0.017) (0.005)*** (0.014)*** (0.005)*** (0.014)*** (0.005)*** (0.014)*** (0.005)***

R-squared 0.54 – 0.54 – 0.54 – 0.55 – 0.56 – 0.56 – 0.56 – 0.63 –


Likelihood ratio test of – 115.32 – 111.88 – 111.47 – 110.99 – 104.65 – 90.53 – 106.70 – 99.96
alpha = 0
Probability – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000
Observations 154 162 154 162 154 162 154 162 101 116 154 162 154 162 154 162

Notes: Results from estimating Eq. (1) with log licensing income and number of licensing agreements as dependent variables and adding the pre-sample patent stock to control for university unobserved heterogeneity. Income
refers to the income from licensing contracts. Number refers to the number of licensing agreements. University controls on size and polytechnic school are dropped because they are highly correlated with the patent stock. The
income equations are estimated by OLS, while the number equations are estimated using a Negative Binomial model. Robust standard errors, reported in brackets, are clustered at the university level. ***, ** and * denote statistical
significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively. All regressions include a constant and a complete set of region and year dummies.
Table 7
Robustness results for spin-offs.

Dependent variable: (1) (2) (3) (6) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
number of spin-offs

TTO size 1.253 1.261 1.287 1.246 0.976 1.585 1.303 1.295 1.006 0.932
(0.252)*** (0.259)*** (0.262)*** (0.263)*** (0.265)*** (0.291)*** (0.264)*** (0.259)*** (0.280)*** (0.264)*
TTO age −0.006 −0.027 −0.026 −0.132 −0.043 −0.017 −0.047 −0.031 0.055
(0.045) (0.047) (0.046) (0.057)** (0.046) (0.046) (0.048) (0.045) (0.056)
TTO specialization in 0.012 0.013 0.019 −0.010 0.004 0.015 −0.002 0.020
spin-offs
(0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.024) (0.025)
Science park dummy 0.600 0.298 0.369 0.566 0.549 0.452 0.470
(0.292)** (0.296) (0.282) (0.294)* (0.284)* (0.299) (0.296)

A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173


Rule on participation in 1.555
spin-offs dummy
(0.399)***
Rule on conflict of interests 1.883
dummy
(0.575)***
Rule on copyrights dummy 0.445
(0.310)
Rule on invention 1.251
disclosures dummy
(0.559)**
Spin-off program dummy 0.965
(0.390)**
Risk capital dummy 0.737
(0.407)

Controls for university characteristics


University quality 0.033 0.032 0.029 0.039 −0.004 0.020 0.013 0.037 0.041 0.011
(0.053) (0.053) (0.055) (0.055) (0.057) (0.057) (0.061) (0.055) (0.056) (0.055)
Public university dummy 0.897 0.904 0.846 0.839 0.100 0.746 −0.070 0.406 0.799 0.359
(0.593) (0.595) (0.635) (0.640) (0.679) (0.688) (0.695) (0.668) (0.663) (0.633)
Medical school dummy −0.013 −0.003 0.023 0.031 0.321 −0.235 0.173 0.142 0.120 −0.325
(0.284) (0.292) (0.301) (0.294) (0.295) (0.293) (0.301) (0.287) (0.295) (0.343)
Pre-sample patent stock 0.013 0.014 0.015 0.014 0.028 0.012 0.013 0.017 0.016 0.012
(0.004)*** (0.005)*** (0.006)*** (0.005)*** (0.006)*** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.006)*** (0.005)*** (0.005)*

Likelihood ratio test of 131.99 131.83 129.19 126.01 63.65 105.28 96.11 122.52 108.93 95.17
alpha = 0
Probability 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Observations 154 154 154 154 154 154 154 154 154 154

Notes: Results from estimating Eq. (1) with number of spin-offs as dependent variable and adding the pre-sample patent stock to control for university unobserved heterogeneity. University controls on size and polytechnic school
are dropped because they are highly correlated with the patent stock. The regressions are estimated using a Negative Binomial model with robust standard errors, reported in brackets, clustered at the university level. ***, ** and
* denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively. All regressions include a constant and a complete set of region and year dummies.

1171
1172 A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173

of public ownership suggests that public universities generate 6. Robustness check: endogeneity bias
less licenses, which may be explained by the fact that pub-
lic universities do not have close links with the private sector. Lach and Schankerman (2008) point out that university
The negative effect of the quality of university on the number unobserved characteristics, such as commercial orientation or
of licenses may suggest that universities publishing in top sci- managerial ability, may drive both performance and university
entific journals produce more basic research less likely to be policies leading to upward biased estimates of the effects of uni-
licensed to firms. Despite potential synergies between upstream versity policies on performance. The standard solution to address
and downstream research, academic-oriented universities may this endogeneity problem would be to use university fixed effects
face a trade-off between allocating resources to academic research to control for unobserved heterogeneity. But since we only have
or applied research. information on university policies at one point in time, it is not
possible to use university fixed effects in our case.
As an alternative we follow Lach and Schankerman’s (2008)
5.3. Spin-offs example and adopt the pre-sample scaling approach developed
by Blundell et al. (1999, 2002). They show that when fixed effects
The results from estimating Eq. (1) with number of spin-offs cannot be used, an alternative approach is to use the pre-sample
as a dependent variable are reported in Table 4. Each column mean of the dependent variable as an additional regressor to con-
of Table 4 shows different specifications of Eq. (1) exploring the trol for unobserved heterogeneity. Due to the lack of pre-sample
effects of the different explanatory variables on the number of data on the dependent variables, we use instead the stock of pre-
spin-offs. sample patents for each university. We construct the pre-sample
Regarding TTO characteristics, columns (1)–(10) show that from stock using information on the number of patent fillings by each
TTO characteristics only the size of the TTO significantly affects university over 1987–2000 compiled from the Spanish Office of
spin-off activity. We find no evidence, however, that the age and Patents and Marks. The pre-sample patent stock is significantly cor-
specialisation of the TTO affect spin-off activity. This result differs related with university technology transfer outcomes. The sample
from other studies (e.g. Chukumba and Jensen, 2005) who find that correlation between the stock of patents and the various depen-
experienced TTOs generate more spin-offs. Our finding may reflect dent variables is respectively 0.62 for the log of R&D contracts,
the level of maturity of the technology transfer market in Spain, 0.44 for licensing income, 0.45 for the number of spin-offs, 0.58 for
slowly diversifying from an initial focus on R&D contracts and pro- the number of R&D contracts and 0.50 for the number of licensing
tection of intellectual property rights to late support for the creation contracts.
of spin-offs. Table 5 shows that the baseline results on R&D contracts are
From column (4) onwards, we include in addition to TTO char- overall robust after adding the stock of patents to control for
acteristics the science park dummy, and find that universities with unobserved heterogeneity. Adding the pre-sample stock to the
a science park have a higher rate of spin-off creation. This result regressions does not change the size and significance of the results,
is robust across alternative specifications and suggests that sci- except for the conflict of interest dummy that is no longer signifi-
ence parks stimulate universities spin-off creation. Our findings cant. The pre-sample patent stock is positive and significant in all
may suggest that the “incubating role” of university science parks income equations, and positive and significant in one out of eight
increases the rate of creation of new firms through a reduction in specifications using the number of R&D contracts.
start-up costs. Table 6 shows that the baseline results are also robust when
Regarding the effects of university policies on the number of controlling for university unobserved heterogeneity using the
spin-offs, we find that a university regulation on spin-offs has a pre-sample patent stock. The pre-sample patent stock is highly sig-
significant and positive effect on the number of spin-offs created nificant and positive, as reported in the bottom of Table 6 and the
(column 5 of Table 4). Such regulations generally allow for academic results are in line with the baseline results. To conclude, Table 7
scientists’ leave to start a new firm. This result suggests that in the reports the robustness checks for the spin-off equation. The base-
Spanish case, universities that grant academic leaves to start a new line results are robust when controlling for unobserved university
firm generate more spin-offs. The positive and significant effect heterogeneity using pre-sample information on patent counts. The
of the conflict of interest dummy in column 6 of Table 4 further pre-sample patent stock is highly significant and positive across
supports the important role of universities’ internal regulations on all specifications, suggesting that the pre-sample information cap-
the creation of spin-offs. Universities with a conflict of interest rule tures some of the unobserved heterogeneity. Overall, the variables
generate more spin-offs than universities without such rules. This of interest remain significant and with the expected signs, except
suggests that appropriate internal rules regulating the participation for the effect of science parks on spin-off creation, which is less
of researchers in external activities are important for university robust. The coefficient on the science park dummy is positive, but
performance in terms of spin-off creation. only significant at 10% in some specifications in Table 7.
Two further interesting results emerge regarding the effect
of university policies on spin-off activity. First, a university pro-
gramme for the creation of firms has a positive and statistically 7. Concluding remarks
significant effect on the number of spin-offs, as reported in column
9 of Table 4. The second finding is that universities that facilitate This paper contributes to the understanding of the role of policy
researchers’ access to risk capital have a higher rate of creation of measures on university technology transfer performance. Based on
spin-offs. The positive and significant coefficient on the risk cap- university data for Spain it provides new evidence suggesting that
ital dummy in column 10 of Table 4 confirms the importance of university internal technology transfer policies and the nature and
universities venture capital funds to secure funding for the initial type of technology transfer intermediaries are important factors
development phase of spin-offs. influencing the performance of universities.
Finally, regarding the impact of the university characteristics The results show that university rules on conflicts of interest
on the rate of creation of spin-offs, university size, ownership and between academic teaching responsibilities and external activities
the technical orientation of the university have a significant pos- have a positive and significant impact on university performance
itive effect on the number of spin-offs, but only in some of the in R&D contracts, licenses or spin-off creation. The results fur-
specifications. ther show that universities’ royalty sharing policy strongly affects
A. Caldera, O. Debande / Research Policy 39 (2010) 1160–1173 1173

licensing income. Granting a higher share of licensing royalties Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Van Reenen, J., 1999. Market shares, market value and inno-
to the inventor stimulates licensing activities. Furthermore, uni- vation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. Review of Economic Studies 66,
529–554.
versities allowing academic scientists to take leaves to create a Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Windmeijer, F., 2002. Individual effects and dynamic feed-
new firm generate more spin-offs. This suggests that creating more back in count data models. Journal of Econometrics 108, 113–131.
certainty for the appropriation of research results matters for uni- Chapple, W., Lockett, A., Siegel, D.S., Wright, M., 2005. Assessing the relative per-
formance of university technology transfer offices in the U.K.: parametric and
versity performance. Designing the right incentives and sharing non-parametric evidence. Research Policy 34 (3), 369–384.
the risk optimally between parties involved in the valorisation of Chukumba, C.O., Jensen, R.A., 2005. University Invention, Entrepreneurship, and
research is a key component of an efficient technology transfer Start-Ups. NBER Working Paper No. W11475.
Conti, A., Gaulé, P., 2008. The CEMI Survey of Technology Transfer Offices. Ecole
strategy. Polytechnique Fédérale de Laussane.
We find further evidence that the presence of a science park has Conti, A., Gaulé, P., 2009. Are the US Outperforming Europe in University Technology
a positive effect on the commercialisation of university research. Licensing? A New Perspective on the European Paradox. CEMI Working Paper,
Ecole Polytechnique Fédérale de Laussane.
This result suggests that the local concentration of high-tech firms
COTEC, 2003. Nuevos Mecanismos de Transferencia de Tecnologa: Debilidades y
has a positive effect on university research valorisation. Science Oportunidades del Sistema Español de Transferencia de Tecnologa. Fundación
parks play an incubating role reducing the costs associated with COTEC para la Innovación Tecnológica, Madrid.
converting scientific findings into marketable products or pro- Coupé, T., 2003. Science is golden: academic R&D and university patents. Journal of
Technology Transfer 28 (1), 31–46.
cesses. However, we find mixed evidence regarding the impact Debackere, K., Veugelers, R., 2005. The role of academic technology transfer orga-
of TTO characteristics on university performance. TTO size has nizations in improving industry science links. Research Policy 34 (April(3)),
a positive effect on R&D contract activity and on the number 321–342.
Di Gregorio, D., Shane, S., 2003. Why do some universities generate more start-ups
of licenses and spin-offs created, but it does not affect licensing than others? Research Policy 32, 209–227.
income. Furthermore, we find that TTO experience only affects European Commission, 2004. Improving Institutions for the Transfer of Technology
R&D contract activity and that TTO specialisation only appears to from Science to Enterprise. Best Project ITTE 1.11/2002. DG Enterprise, European
Commission.
influence the number of R&D contracts generated, but not other European Commission, 2008. Commission Recommendation on the Management
outcomes. of Intellectual Property in Knowledge Transfer Activities and Code of Practice
Although in terms of public policy our analysis does not lead for Universities and other Public Organizations. Brussels, 10.4.2008, C(2008)
1329.
to specific recommendations, the result on the relative contribu- Friedman, J., Silberman, J., 2003. University technology transfer: do incentives,
tion of TTO versus science park might question an approach based management and location matter? Journal of Technology Transfer 28, 17–
on the ‘multiplication’ of TTO structures in most universities. The 30.
Fundacion CYD, 2003, 2005, 2007. Informe CYD. Barcelona, Spain.
potential complementarity between TTO and science parks should
González-Albo Manglano, B., Zulueta Garca, M.A., 2007. Normativas sobre Patentes
be investigated since top performing universities in terms of tech- en las Universidades Españolas. Ci. Inf., Braslia, v. 36, no. 1, 69–78.
nology transfer outcomes have both a large TTO structure and a Hausman, J., Hall, B., Griliches, Z., 1984. Econometric models for count data
science park. A better understanding of the respective role of the and an application to the patents–R&D relationship. Econometrica 52, 909–
938.
TTO and science parks needs to be developed in literature. Jensen, R., Thursby, M., 2001. Proofs and prototypes for sale: the licensing of univer-
sity inventions. American Economic Review 91 (1), 240–259.
Acknowledgments Jensen, R., Thursby, J., Thursby, M., 2003. Disclosure and licensing of university inven-
tions: the best we can do with the S**T we get to work with. International Journal
of Industrial Organization 21, 1271–1300.
The paper benefited from very constructive and useful com- Lach, S., Schankerman, M., 2004. Royalty sharing and technology licensing in
ments and suggestions from two anonymous referees. We are universities. Journal of the European Economic Association 2 (2–3), 252–
264.
also grateful to Mark Schankerman for detailed comments and Lach, S., Schankerman, M., 2008. Incentives and inventions in universities. The Rand
suggestions on previous versions of the paper. We also thank Journal of Economics 39 (2), 403–433.
Jordi Cami, Andreu Mas-Colell, Jacques Mairesse, André Sapir, Ziga Macho-Stadler, I., Martnez-Giralt, X., Pérez-Castrillo, D., 1996. The role of informa-
tion in licensing contract design. Research Policy 25, 43–57.
Zarnic and participants at the Economics of Technology Policy Macho-Stadler, I., Pérez-Castrillo, D., Veugelers, R., 2007. Licensing of university
Conference at Monteverita, the 34th Conference of the European innovations: the case of a technology transfer office. International Journal of
Association for Research in Industrial Economics (EARIE) and the Industrial Organization 25, 483–510.
Mansfield, E., 1998. Academic research and industrial innovation: an update of
10th European Workshop on Efficiency and Productivity Analysis empirical findings. Research Policy 26, 773–776.
(EWEPA X) for useful comments and discussions. We also thank Moya-Anegón, F., Corera Alvarez, E., Gomez-Crisostomo, M.R., Gonzalez-Molina, A.,
the RedOTRI for the access to their data and in particular to Con- Muñoz-Fernández, F., Vargas Quesada, B., 2007. Indicadores Bibliométricos de la
Actividad Cientfica Española, Fundación Española para la Ciencia y la Tecnologa,
stantino Martinez-Cavero, the manager of the RedOTRI network,
Ministerio de Educación y Ciencia.
for his willingness to talk to us about his technology transfer expe- RedOTRI, 2000–2006. Encuesta RedOTRI de Universidades. RedOTRI de Universi-
rience. Aida Caldera thanks Fundación Ramón Areces for financial dades.
support. Sapsalis, E., Van Looy, B., Van Pottelsberghe, B., Debackere, K., Callaert, J., 2006.
Antecedents of Patenting Activity of European Universities. Working Papers CEB
05-005.RS, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Solvay Business School, Centre Emile
References Bernheim (CEB).
Siegel, D.S., Waldman, D., Link, A., 2003. Assessing the impact of organizational prac-
Adams, J., Griliches, Z., 1998. Research Productivity in a System of Universities. tices on the relative productivity of university technology transfer offices: an
Annales D’Economie et de Statistique, No. 49/50. explanatory study. Research Policy 32 (1), 27–48.
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., Stein J., 2005. Academic Freedom, Private-Sector Focus Siegel, D.S., Veugelers, R., Wright, M., 2007. Technology transfer offices and com-
and the Process of Innovation. NBER Working Paper 11542. mercialization of university intellectual property: performance and policy
Agrawal, A., Cockburn, I., 2003. The anchor tenant hypothesis: exploring the role of implications. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 23 (4), 640–660.
large, local, R&D intensive firms in regional innovation systems. International Thursby, J.G., Kemp, S., 2002. Growth and productive efficiency of university intel-
Journal of Industrial Organization 21, 1227–1253. lectual property. Research Policy 31 (1), 109–124.
APTE, 2006. Memoria APTE 2006. Asociación de Parques Cientficos y Tecnológicos Thursby, J.G., Thursby, M.C., 2002. Who is selling the ivory tower? Sources of growth
de España, Madrid. in university licensing. Management Science 48, 90–104.
Belenzon, S., Schankerman, M., 2009. University knowledge transfer: private own- Van Biesebroeck, J., 2007. Robustness of productivity estimates. Journal of Industrial
ership, incentives, and local development objectives. Journal of Law and Economics 55 (September(3)) 529–569.
Economics 52 (1), 111–144.

You might also like