You are on page 1of 29

Microeconomics 6th Edition Hubbard Solutions Manual

Microeconomics 6th Edition Hubbard Solutions


Manual

To download the complete and accurate content document, go to:


https://testbankbell.com/download/microeconomics-6th-edition-hubbard-solutions-ma
nual/

Visit TestBankBell.com to get complete for all chapters


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness
of Demand and Supply
Brief Chapter Summary and Learning Objectives
6.1 The Price Elasticity of Demand and Its Measurement (pages 184–190)
Define price elasticity of demand and understand how to measure it.

 Price elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of quantity demanded to a


change in price.

6.2 The Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand (pages 191–192)


List and explain the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.

 The key determinants of the price elasticity of demand for a good are: the availability of
close substitutes, the passage of time, whether the good is a luxury or a necessity, the
definition of the market, and the share of the good in the consumer’s budget.

6.3 The Relationship between Price Elasticity of Demand and Total Revenue
(pages 193–197)
Explain the relationship between the price elasticity of demand and total revenue.

 When demand is inelastic, price and total revenue move in the same direction. When
demand is elastic, price and total revenue move inversely.

6.4 Other Demand Elasticities (pages 197–199)


Define cross-price elasticity of demand and income elasticity of demand and understand
their determinants and how they are measured.

 The cross-price elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of the quantity


demanded of one good to a change in the price of another good; the income elasticity of
demand measures the responsiveness of the quantity demanded of a good to a change in
income.

6.5 Using Elasticity to Analyze the Disappearing Family Farm


(pages 200–202)
Use price elasticity and income elasticity to analyze economic issues.

 Elasticity can help us understand why the family farm has become an endangered species
and the effects of raising the federal government’s tax on gasoline.

6.6 The Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Measurement (pages 202–208)
Define price elasticity of supply and understand its determinants and how it is measured.

 The price elasticity of supply measures the responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a
change in price.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 131

Key Terms
Cross-price elasticity of demand, p. 197. The Perfectly inelastic demand, p. 189. The case
percentage change in quantity demanded of one where the quantity demanded is completely
good divided by the percentage change in the unresponsive to price, and the price elasticity
price of another good. of demand equals zero.

Elastic demand, p. 185. Demand is elastic when Price elasticity of demand, p. 184. The
the percentage change in the quantity demanded responsiveness of the quantity demanded to
is greater than the percentage change in price, so a change in price, measured by dividing the
the price elasticity is greater than 1 in absolute percentage change in the quantity demanded
value. of a product by the percentage change in the
product’s price.
Elasticity, p. 184. A measure of how much one
economic variable responds to changes in Price elasticity of supply, p. 202. The
another economic variable. responsiveness of the quantity supplied to
a change in price, measured by dividing the
Income elasticity of demand, p. 198. A percentage change in the quantity supplied
measure of the responsiveness of the quantity of a product by the percentage change in the
demanded to changes in income, measured by product’s price.
the percentage change in quantity demanded
divided by the percentage change in income. Total revenue, p. 193. The total amount of
funds a seller receives from selling of a good or
Inelastic demand, p. 185. Demand is inelastic service, calculated by multiplying price per unit
when the percentage change in quantity by the number of units sold.
demanded is less than the percentage change in
price, so the price elasticity is less than 1 in Unit-elastic demand, p. 185. Demand is unit
absolute value. elastic when the percentage change in quantity
demanded is equal to the percentage change in
Perfectly elastic demand, p. 189. The case price, so the price elasticity is equal to 1 in
where the quantity demanded is infinitely absolute value.
responsive to price and the price elasticity
of demand equals infinity.

Chapter Outline
Do People Respond to Changes in the Price of Gasoline?
In the summer of 2008, the average price of a gallon of gasoline was $4.00; by the end of the year it was
down to $1.50. The price rose to nearly $4.00 by 2011 before falling to below $2.00 at the beginning of
2015 and then rising again. Some people argue that consumers don’t vary the quantity of gas they buy as
the price fluctuates because the number of miles they drive is roughly constant. But actual consumer
behavior contradicts this. In December 2014, when the average price of gasoline was $2.50 per gallon,
U.S. consumers bought about 7 percent more gasoline than they did in April 2014, when the average price
of gasoline was $3.60 per gallon.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


132 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

The Price Elasticity of Demand and Its Measurement (pages 184–190)


6.1 Learning Objective: Define price elasticity of demand and understand how to measure it.

Elasticity is a measure of how much one economic variable responds to changes in another economic
variable. The price elasticity of demand is the responsiveness of the quantity demanded to a change in
price, measured by dividing the percentage change in the quantity demanded of a product by the
percentage change in the product’s price.

A. Measuring the Price Elasticity of Demand


The slope of the demand curve is not used to measure elasticity because the measurement of slope is
sensitive to the units chosen for quantity and price.

Percentage change in quantity demanded


Price elasticity of demand  .
Percentage change in price

The price elasticity of demand is always negative. Because we are usually interested in the relative size of
elasticities, we often compare their absolute values.

B. Elastic Demand and Inelastic Demand


Elastic demand refers to when the percentage change in quantity demanded is greater than the
percentage change in price, so the price elasticity is greater than 1 in absolute value.

Inelastic demand refers to when the percentage change in quantity demanded is less than the percentage
change in price, so the price elasticity is less than 1 in absolute value.

Unit-elastic demand refers to when the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the
percentage change in price, so the price elasticity is equal to 1 in absolute value.

C. An Example of Computing Price Elasticities


In calculating the price elasticity between two points on a demand curve, we run into a problem because
we get a different value for price increases than for price decreases.

D. The Midpoint Formula


We can use the midpoint formula to ensure that we have only one value for the price elasticity of demand
between the same two points on a demand curve. The midpoint formula uses the average of the initial and
final quantities and the average of the initial and final prices. If Q1 and P1 are the initial quantity and price
and Q2 and P2 are the final quantity and price, then the midpoint formula is:

(Q 2  Q1) ( P 2  P1)
Price elasticity of demand   .
 Q1  Q 2   P1  P 2 
   
 2   2 

E. When Demand Curves Intersect, the Flatter Curve Is More Elastic


When two demand curves intersect, the curve with the smaller slope (in absolute value) is more
elastic, and the one with the larger slope (in absolute value) is less elastic.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 133

F. Polar Cases of Perfectly Elastic and Perfectly Inelastic Demand


If a demand curve is a vertical line, then it is perfectly inelastic. Perfectly inelastic demand is the case
where the quantity demanded is completely unresponsive to price and the price elasticity of demand
equals zero. If a demand curve is a horizontal line, then it is perfectly elastic. Perfectly elastic demand is
the case where the quantity demanded is infinitely responsive to price, and the price elasticity of demand
equals infinity.

Teaching Tips
After illustrating a perfectly inelastic demand curve, ask your students to suggest examples. They may
mention cigarettes, gasoline, or other goods that have relatively inelastic, but not perfectly inelastic,
demands. Ask if the quantity demanded of the products they suggest would change if the price were not
only higher but lower as well. Even students who claim they would not buy less gasoline if the price rose
are unlikely to argue that they would not buy more gasoline at lower prices. This discussion will help
your students understand that very few products actually have perfectly inelastic demand curves. You
don’t need to spend much time discussing perfectly elastic demand. It should be sufficient to make a brief
reference to perfect competition, a topic covered in Chapter 12.

Extra Making
the Rewriting the Formula
Connection

Your understanding of elasticity (E) may be increased by rewriting the elasticity formula. To make this
explanation easier to follow, assume that we are interested in measuring the price elasticity of a linear
demand curve. The elasticity formula in the textbook is:

(Q 2  Q1) ( P 2  P1)
E  .
(Q1  Q 2) ( P1  P 2)
2 2

Both “2”s can be dropped from this equation. Recall that (Q2 − Q1) = ΔQ and (P2 − P1) = ΔP. Substituting,
we have:

Q P
E  .
(Q1  Q 2) ( P1  P 2)

Because the elasticity equation divides one fraction by another fraction you can rewrite this expression by
multiplying the numerator by the inverse, or reciprocal, of the denominator. The associative property of
multiplication allows us to divide ΔQ by ΔP and (P1 + P2) by (Q1 + Q2). Therefore:

Q P1  P 2
P  .
P Q1  Q 2

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


134 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Because the slope of a linear or straight line demand curve is constant and can be written as ΔP/ΔQ, the
elasticity formula can now be written as:
P1  P 2
E  (1/slope)  .
Q1  Q 2

Writing the elasticity formula this way makes it clear that the slope is not the same as the elasticity of a
demand curve. Along a linear demand curve, the slope will have a constant value but the elasticity will
not. The formula highlights this and also can be used to make another important point. Because the law of
demand tells us that high prices are associated with relatively low values of quantity demanded (and vice
versa), the absolute values for elasticity will be high at high prices (demand is elastic) and relatively low
at low prices (demand is inelastic). This result can easily be shown by substituting in actual price and
quantity values for a given demand curve into the rewritten formula and observing the change in the ratio
of (P1 + P2) to (Q1 + Q2) as price is decreased.

The Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand (pages 191–192)


6.2 Learning Objective: List and explain the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.
There are five key determinants of the price elasticity of demand.

A. Availability of Close Substitutes


The availability of substitutes is the most important determinant of the price elasticity of demand. In
general, if a product has more substitutes available, it will have a more elastic demand. If a product has
fewer substitutes available, it will have a less elastic demand.

B. Passage of Time
The more time that passes, the more elastic the demand for a product becomes.

C. Luxuries versus Necessities


The demand curve for a luxury is more elastic than the demand curve for a necessity.

D. Definition of the Market


The more narrowly we define a market, the more elastic demand will be.

E. Share of a Good in a Consumer’s Budget


In general, the demand for a good will be more elastic the larger the share of the good in the average
consumer’s budget.

F. Some Estimated Price Elasticities of Demand


It is important to remember that estimates of the price elasticity of different goods vary depending on the
data used and the time period over which the estimates were made.

Teaching Tips
It is useful to emphasize two points. First, each of the five determinants of the price elasticity of demand
should be considered separately from the others. A product that consumes a small part of a consumer’s
budget (this suggests demand would be relatively inelastic) may have several good substitutes (this
suggests demand would be relatively elastic). Second, changes in the market price of any product will
result in different values for price elasticity. Estimates of the price elasticity of demand use market prices
for products at a particular time. Different market prices from different timer periods would result in
different elasticity estimates.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 135

Extra Solved Problem 6.2


Recession Batters Fancy Restaurants as Consumers Trade Down
Among the victims of the 2007–2009 recession were luxury restaurants in New York, Chicago, and other
large cities. Rubicon, a top-rated San Francisco restaurant, closed in August 2008. The Blue Water Grill
in Chicago also closed. Other restaurants attempted to survive by offering discounts. High-end New York
restaurant Jean Georges slashed prices for three- and four-course meals. Other restaurants followed suit,
some offering three-course meals for less than $20; the London Grill in Philadelphia offered a lobster or
beef meal for $18.95. To avoid high labor costs, San Francisco’s Fifth Floor started an “Honor Bar”
where customers placed money in a box on the honor system and poured their own wine. An article
summarizing the woes of the restaurant industry commented:

Currently, consumers appear to be “trading down,” choosing lower-priced restaurants than they
used to. The National Restaurant Association projects sales, adjusted for inflation, will decline by
2.5% in full service restaurants in 2009, while it predicts quick service will grow by 0.4%.

Stephen Hanson, who closed several of his once-successful restaurants in New York and Chicago, has
had better luck with restaurants that offer less expensive meals. Mr. Hanson explained the success of his
big restaurants that earn a small profit from a large number of customers: “I’m in the volume business.”
By 2010, business at upscale and other restaurants began to recover as the recession ended.

Sources: Katy McLaughlin, “What’s Not Cooking,” Wall Street Journal, January 23, 2009, and Kevin P. Casey, “From fast food
to fine dining, business is up at restaurants,” USA Today, November 22, 2010.

a. What are the key determinants of the price elasticity of demand for meals served at high-end
restaurants?
b. Cite evidence that high restaurant prices resulted in a lower quantity demanded and a substitution
by consumers to lower-priced alternatives.

Solving the Problem


Step 1: Review the chapter material.
This problem is about the determinants of the price elasticity of demand, so you may want to
review the section “The Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand,” which begins on
page 191.

Step 2: What are the key determinants of the price elasticity of demand for meals served at
high-end restaurants?
The key determinants are the availability of close substitutes (for example, “quick service”
restaurants that serve less expensive meals) and the share of the restaurant meals in the
consumer’s budget.

Step 3: Cite evidence that high restaurant prices resulted in a lower quantity demanded
and a substitution by consumers to lower-priced alternatives.
High-end restaurants had their worst downturn in decades. San Francisco’s Rubicon and the
Blue Water Grill in Chicago closed in 2008. But sales at “quick service” restaurants
increased. Steven Hanson, owner of several restaurants, reported that he had greater success
with restaurants that charge lower prices.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


136 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

The Relationship between Price Elasticity of Demand and Total Revenue


6.3 (pages 193–197)
Learning Objective: Explain the relationship between the price elasticity of demand
and total revenue.

A firm is interested in price elasticity of demand for its products because it allows the firm to calculate
how changes in price will affect its total revenue. Total revenue is the total amount of funds a seller
receives from selling a good or service, calculated by multiplying price per unit by the number of units
sold. When demand is inelastic, price and total revenue move in the same direction: An increase in price
raises total revenue, and a decrease in price reduces total revenue. When demand is elastic, price and total
revenue move inversely: An increase in price reduces total revenue, and a decrease in price raises total
revenue. If demand is unit elastic a change in price is exactly offset by a proportional change in quantity
demanded, leaving revenue unaffected.

A. Elasticity and Revenue with a Linear Demand Curve


Along most demand curves, including linear demand curves, elasticity is not constant at every point.
When the price is high and the quantity demanded is low, demand is elastic. When the price is low and
the quantity demanded is high, demand is inelastic.

Extra Making
Determining the Price Elasticity of Demand through Market
the
Experiments
Connection

Firms usually have a good idea of the price elasticity of demand for products that have been on the market
for at least a few years. For new products, however, firms often experiment with different prices to
determine the price elasticity. For example, Apple introduced the first-generation iPhone in June 2007, at
a price of $599. But demand for the iPhone was more elastic than Apple had expected, and when sales
failed to reach Apple’s projections, the company cut the price to $399 just two months later. Similarly,
when 3D televisions were introduced into the U.S. market in early 2010, Sony and other manufacturers
believed that sales would be strong despite prices being several hundred dollars higher than for other
high-end ultra-thin televisions. Once again, though, demand turned out to be more elastic than expected,
and by December firms were cutting prices 40 percent or more in an effort to increase revenue.

Since electronic books (e-books) became popular after Amazon introduced the Kindle e-reader, firms
have experimented with different prices in trying to determine the relevant price elasticity. Amazon had
originally priced most best-selling e-books at $9.99, but when Apple introduced the iPad in 2010, Apple
negotiated contracts with publishers that raised prices for e-books. Amazon and Barnes & Noble
eventually signed similar contracts, and the prices for best selling e-books rose from $9.99 to $12.99 or
$14.99. Publishers hoped that a low price elasticity of demand for e-books would result in the price
increase leading to higher revenues. Many buyers, however, claimed that rather than pay higher prices,
they would go back to reading printed books. Joel Waldfogel, an economist at the University of
Pennsylvania, raised the possibility that the higher prices might lead some readers to illegally download
pirated e-books, in violation of the publishers’ copyrights. Although piracy has been a problem with
music and movies, it had not yet been a problem with books. Waldfogel argued that, “I would be scared to
death about a culture of piracy taking hold. I wouldn’t mess around with price increases.” Whether the
demand for e-books turns out to be elastic or inelastic may depend on how many readers consider printed
books or pirated e-books to be close substitutes for legally downloaded e-books.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 137

Source: Daisuke Wakabayashi and Miguel Bustillo, “TV Makers Can’t Hold Line on 3-D Prices,” Wall Street Journal, December
20, 2010; Motoko Rich and Brad Stone, “Cost of an e-Book Will Be Going Up,” New York Times, February 11, 2010; and Kate
Hafner and Brad Stone, “iPhone Owners Crying Foul Over Price Cut,” New York Times, September 7, 2007.

Question
A publisher was quoted as saying the following about the pricing of e-books: “We may introduce [an e-
book] at $14.95 for a year and then move the book to $9.99 when we would have put out the trade
paperback edition. I suspect you’re going to see a fair amount of experimentation.” Why would issuing a
paperback version of a book affect the price a publisher would charge for an e-book? Why would
publishers be experimenting with the prices of e-books?

Source: Motoko Rich and Brad Stone, “Cost of an e-Book Will Be Going Up,” New York Times, February 11, 2010.

Answer
The paperback edition is a reasonably good substitute for the e-book edition. Publishers are
experimenting with the prices of e-books because they are relatively new products, which makes
estimating price elasticity difficult.

Other Demand Elasticities (pages 197–199)


6.4 Learning Objective: Define cross-price elasticity of demand and income elasticity of
demand and understand their determinants and how they are measured.

In addition to price elasticity, two other demand elasticities are important: the cross-price elasticity of
demand and the income elasticity of demand.

A. Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand


The formula for the cross-price elasticity of demand is:

Percentage change in quantity demanded of one good


.
Percentage change in price of another good

The cross-price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the quantity demanded of one good
divided by the percentage change in the price of another good. An increase in the price of a substitute will
lead to an increase in quantity demanded, so the cross-price elasticity of demand will be positive.
An increase in the price of a complement will lead to a decrease in the quantity demanded, so the cross-
price elasticity of demand will be negative.

B. Income Elasticity of Demand


The income elasticity of demand of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity
demanded to changes in income, measured by the percentage change in the quantity demanded divided by
the percentage change in income:

Percentage change in quantity demanded


.
Percentage change in income

If the quantity demanded of a good increases as income increases, then the good is a normal good.
Normal goods are often further subdivided into luxuries and necessities. The income elasticity of demand
for a necessity is positive but less than 1. The income elasticity of demand for a luxury is greater than 1.
A good is inferior if the quantity demanded falls as income increases.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


138 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Teaching Tips
Many students confuse one type of elasticity with another. Ask your students to solve the following
problem. Assume that the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for good X is 2.5. Is good X a
normal good? (Answer: You cannot determine whether X is normal or inferior by knowing its price
elasticity. You need to know the income elasticity of demand for good X to answer this question).

Extra Solved Problem 6.4


A Subway Fare Increase and an Economic Boom Affect the Taxi Business
Assume that two separate events affect the market for taxi rides in New York City:

a. There is a 20 percent increase in New York subway fares. As a result, the price of a taxicab ride
increases by 5 percent.
b. An economic expansion causes a 5 percent increase in the incomes of tourists visiting New York
City. As a result, the price of a taxicab ride increases by 2 percent.

Describe the cross-price and income elasticity formulas and use the formulas to determine the values of
these elasticities for taxicab rides.

Solving the Problem


Step 1: Review the chapter material.
This problem is about the determinants of the cross-price elasticity and income elasticity of
demand, so you may want to review the section “Other Demand Elasticities,” which begins
on page 197.

Step 2: State the cross-price elasticity formula and determine the value of this elasticity for
taxicab rides.
The cross-price elasticity formula is:

Percentage change in quantity demanded of one good


.
Percentage change in price of another good

Because a 20 percent increase in subway fares raised the quantity demanded of taxi rides by
5 percent, the value of the cross-price elasticity is:

5 percent
 0.25.
20 percent

The elasticity is positive, so subway and taxi rides are substitutes.

Step 3: State the income elasticity formula and determine the value of this elasticity for
taxi rides.
The income elasticity is:

Percentage change in quantity demanded


.
Percentage change in income

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 139

Because a 5 percent increase in income led to a 2 percent increase in taxi rides, the value of
the income elasticity is:

2 percent
 0.4.
5 percent

The elasticity is positive but less than 1. Therefore, a taxi ride is a normal good and a
necessity.

Using Elasticity to Analyze the Disappearing Family Farm (pages 200–202)


6.5 Learning Objective: Use price elasticity and income elasticity to analyze economic issues.

From 1950 to 2015, the number of farms decreased from 5 million to about 2 million, and the number of
people who lived on farms fell from 23 million to fewer than 3 million. Rapid growth in farm output has
combined with low price and income elasticities to make family farming difficult in the United States. In
1950, the average U.S. wheat farmer harvested about 17 bushels from each acre. By 2015, the average
U.S. wheat farmer harvested 44 bushels per acre. This increase in wheat production resulted in a
substantial decline in prices because: (1) the demand for wheat is inelastic, and (2) the income elasticity
of demand for wheat is low.

Extra Solved Problem 6.5


Using Price Elasticity to Analyze Policy toward Illegal Drugs
An ongoing policy debate concerns whether to legalize the use of drugs such as marijuana and cocaine.
Some researchers estimate that legalizing cocaine would cause its price to fall by as much as 95 percent.
Proponents of legalization argue that legalizing drug use would lower crime rates by eliminating the main
reason for the murderous gang wars that plague many big cities and by reducing the incentive for drug
addicts to commit robberies and burglaries. Opponents of legalization argue that lower drug prices would
lead more people to use drugs.

a. Suppose the price elasticity of demand for cocaine is −2. If legalization causes the price of
cocaine to fall by 95 percent, what will be the percentage increase in the quantity of cocaine
demanded?
b. If the price elasticity is −0.02, what will be the percentage increase in the quantity demanded?
c. Discuss how the size of the price elasticity of demand for cocaine is relevant to the debate over its
legalization.

Solving the Problem


Step 1: Review the chapter material.
This problem deals with applications of the price elasticity of demand formula, so you may
want to review the section “Using Elasticity to Analyze the Disappearing Family Farm,”
which begins on page 200 of the textbook, and the section “Measuring the Price Elasticity of
Demand,” which begins on page 184.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


140 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Step 2: Answer part (a) using the formula for the price elasticity of demand.
Percentage change in quantity demanded
Price elasticity of demand  .
Percentage change in price
We can plug into this formula the values given for the price elasticity and the percentage
change in price:
Percentage change in quantity demanded
2  .
95%
Or rearranging:
Percentage change in quantity demanded = 2 × 95% = 190%

Step 3: Use the same method to answer part (b).


We only need to substitute 0.02 for 2 as the price elasticity of demand:
Percentage change in quantity demanded = 0.02 × 95% = 1.9%

Step 4: Answer part (c) by discussing how the size of the price elasticity of demand for
cocaine helps us to understand the effects of legalization.
Clearly, the higher the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for cocaine, the greater
the increase in cocaine use that would result from legalization. If the price elasticity is as high
as in part (a), legalization will lead to a large increase in use. If, however, the price elasticity
is as low as in part (b), legalization will lead to only a small increase in use.

Extra Credit: One estimate puts the price elasticity at −0.28, which suggests that even a large fall in the
price of cocaine might lead to only a moderate increase in cocaine use. However, even a moderate
increase in cocaine use would have costs. Some studies have shown that cocaine users are more likely to
commit crimes, to abuse their children, to have higher medical expenses, and to be less productive
workers. Moreover, many people object to the use of cocaine and other narcotics on moral grounds and
would oppose legalization even if it led to no increase in use. Ultimately, whether the use of cocaine and
other drugs should be legalized is a normative issue. Economics can contribute to the discussion but
cannot decide the issue.
Source for estimate of price elasticity of cocaine: Henry Saffer and Frank Chaloupka, “The Demand for Illicit Drugs,” Economic
Inquiry, Vol. 37, No. 3, July 1999, pp. 401–411.

The Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Measurement (pages 202–208)


6.6 Learning Objective: Define price elasticity of supply and understand its main
determinants and how it is measured.

To measure how much quantity supplied increases when price increases, we use the price elasticity of
supply.

A. Measuring the Price Elasticity of Supply


The price elasticity of supply is the responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a change in price,
measured by dividing the percentage change in the quantity supplied of a product by the percentage
change in the product’s price. We calculate the price elasticity of supply using percentage changes:
Percentage change in quantity supplied
.
Percentage change in price

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 141

Because of the law of supply, price elasticity of supply will be a positive number. If the price elasticity of
supply is less than 1, then supply is inelastic. If the price elasticity of supply is greater than 1, then supply
is elastic. If the price elasticity of supply is equal to 1, then supply is unit elastic.

B. Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Supply


Whether the supply curve is elastic or inelastic depends on the ability and willingness of firms to alter the
quantity they produce as price increases. The supply curve for most products will be inelastic if we
measure it over a short period of time, but increasingly elastic the longer the period of time over which we
measure it.

C. Polar Cases of Perfectly Elastic and Perfectly Inelastic Supply


It is possible for supply to fall into one of the polar cases of price elasticity. If a supply curve is a vertical
line, it is perfectly inelastic. If a supply curve is a horizontal line, it is perfectly elastic.

D. Using Price Elasticity of Supply to Predict Changes in Price


When demand increases, the amount that price increases depends on the price elasticity of supply. When
the supply is inelastic, a change in demand results in a larger increase in price than when the supply is
elastic.

Extra Solved Problem 6.6


The Supply of Taxi Medallions
In fall of 2015 New York City taxi medallions, some of which had sold for over $1 million each in 2013,
were worth about $650,000 apiece. The New York City Taxi and Limousine Commission limits the
number of medallions, which are required in order to legally operate a cab in New York City, to about
13,200. Because of the limit placed on the number of medallions, as demand for taxis and medallions rose
from 1980 to 2013, the price of a medallion increased by about 1,000 percent. The number of medallions
did not change from 2013 to 2015, but competition from Uber and other transportation alternatives was
responsible for most of the decline in the price of medallions.

Sources: Jared Mayer, “New York’s Taxi King Is Going Down,” the Federalist, October 26, 2015; Ilya Marritz, “NYC Taxi
Medallions Fetch ‘Unbelievable’ Returns,” National Public Radio, November 15, 2011; and “NYC Taxi Medallions Sell for $1.1
Million,” Economic Policy Journal, March 18, 2013.

a. What was the value of the price elasticity of supply of New York City taxi medallions between
1980 and 2015?
b. Describe some of the consequences of the New York City Taxi and Limousine Commission’s
decision to limit the quantity of taxi medallions.

Solving the Problem


Step 1: Review the chapter material.
This problem is about the determinants of the elasticity of supply, so you may want to review
the section “The Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Measurement,” which begins on page 202
of the textbook.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


142 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Step 2: What was the value of the price elasticity of supply of New York City taxi
medallions between 1980 and 2013?
The price elasticity of supply formula is:

Percentage change in quantity supplied


.
Percentage change in price

Because the quantity supplied of medallions did not change between 1980 and 2015, the
percentage change in the quantity supplied of medallions was zero, as was the price elasticity
of supply. The medallion supply curve was vertical at the quantity of about 13,200
medallions.

Step 3: Describe some of the consequences of the New York City Taxi and Limousine
Commission limiting the quantity of taxi medallions.
The high cost of medallions has limited the number of taxi cabs available for residents and
visitors to the city, which has raised the price of taxi rides. Another consequence is the high
number of unlicensed cabs that break the law by offering their services. Economist Paul
Krugman claims that a disproportionately high number of traffic accidents in New York City
are caused by unlicensed and unregulated taxi drivers. The limited the number of medallions
and taxis created an incentive for competitors such as Uber to offer its transportation services
in New York City.

Extra Economics in Your Life:


Can Knowledge of Elasticities Make You Rich?

Question: After studying the material in this chapter, you should understand why knowing the income
and price elasticities of their products is important to the owners and managers of firms. But what if you
are not a manager or owner? If, for example, you were interested in investing some of your hard-earned
savings in the stock market, how would knowing income and price elasticities help you?

Answer: The best advice for success in the stock market is still “buy low, sell high.” But what you
learned about elasticity also may be helpful, at least in a general way. Firms that sell products with high
income elasticities (for example, houses and automobiles) experience especially large fluctuations in sales
as the overall economy moves through the business cycle. Consumers are reluctant to buy expensive
products during a recession, especially if they must take out loans to do so. But sales of these same items
tend to increase rapidly when the economy moves into an expansion.

Source: Ben McClure, “The Ups and Downs of Investing in Cyclical Stocks,” www.investopedia.com. October 22, 2002.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 143

Solutions to End-of-Chapter Exercises

The Price Elasticity of Demand and Its Measurement


6.1 Learning Objective: Define price elasticity of demand and understand how to measure
it.

Review Questions
1.1 Price elasticity of demand = (percentage change in quantity demanded)/(percentage change in
price). The price elasticity of demand isn’t measured by the slope of the demand curve because
the slope depends on the units of measurement. The slope of the demand curve will change by a
factor of 100 if you use cents instead of dollars, for example. Another example: consider six-
packs of soda versus cans of soda. If the price drops by $1.00 per six-pack and the quantity
demanded increases by two six-packs, then that is the same thing as quantity demanded
increasing by 12 cans. So, you could calculate the slope either as −1/2 six-packs, or as −1/12
cans. In addition, using percentage changes in the elasticity formula allows for meaningful
comparisons of demand responsiveness between very different kinds of goods; for example,
breakfast cereal versus health care.

1.2 The price elasticity of demand =

Percentage change in quantity demanded 25%


  2.5
Percentage change in price 10%

The demand for Cheerios is elastic.

1.3 In calculating the percentage change in price and quantity, the midpoint formula divides the
change in price and change in quantity by the average of their starting and ending values.

(Q 2  Q1) ( P 2  P1)
Midpoint formula : 
 Q1  Q 2   P1  P 2 
   
 2   2 

Percentage changes can also be calculated by using the starting or ending value without
averaging, but, unlike the midpoint formula, these methods gives different results depending on
whether the starting or ending value is used.

1.4 A perfectly inelastic demand curve is a vertical line, as shown at the bottom of Table 6.1. Such a
good will have no substitutes; for example, a life-saving drug. Therefore, an increase in price
from $30 to $40 or decrease in price from $30 to $20 will have no effect on the quantity
demanded (Qd) of the good, which remains at 16.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


144 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Problems and Applications


1.5 If there is a 1.6 percent increase in gasoline consumption in response to a 32 percent decline in
price (holding everything else constant) the price elasticity of demand would be:

Percentage change in quantity demanded 1.6


   0.05
Percentage change in price  32

Because the price elasticity of demand is less than one (in absolute value) the demand for gasoline would
be price inelastic. The percentage change in quantity demanded is less than the percentage change in
price.

12,000,000  8,000,000
1.6 a.  4,000,000
$2.00  $3.00
12  8
b.  4 . This is a much smaller value than in (a).
$2.00  $3.00
c. We can calculate the price elasticity using the midpoint formula as follows:
12,000,000  8,000,000
Percentage change in quantity demanded =  100  40%
10,000,000
$2.00  $3.00
Percentage change in price =  100  40%
$2.50
40%
So, the price elasticity of demand =  1
40%
Notice that this value is significantly different from the values calculated in (a) and (b).

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 145

1.7 For D1:


60  30
Percentage change in quantity demanded = 100  66.7%
45
$2  $3
Percentage change in price =  100  40%
$2.5
66.7%
Elasticity =  1.7 
40.0%

For D2:
40  30
Percentage change in quantity demanded = 100  28.6%
35
$2  $3
Percentage change in price =  100  40%
$2.5
28.6%
Elasticity =  0.7
40.0%

1.8 Step 1: Calculate average quantity and average price:


1, 469  1,131
Average quantity =  1,300
2
$24,751  $29, 454
Average price =  $27,102.5
2

Step 2: Calculate percentage change in quantity demanded and percentage change price:
1,131  1,469
Percentage change in quantity demanded =  100  26%
1,300
$29, 454  $24,751
Percentage change in price =  100  17.4%
27,102.5

Step 3: Divide the percentage change in the quantity demanded by the percentage change in price
to arrive at the price elasticity for the demand curve:
26%
Price elasticity of demand =  1.5
17.4%
Demand for Pace University is therefore elastic.
Total tuition received in 2006 declined to $33,312,474 (= $29,454 × 1,131 students) from
$36,359,219 (= $24,751 × 1,469 students) in 2005.

1.9 Suppose Ford did cut the price by $1 from $440 to $439 and quantity demanded increased by
1,000 cars from 500,000 to 501,000. The midpoint price would be $439.50 and the midpoint
quantity would be 500,500. Then, the percentage change in quantity would equal:
(1,000/500,500) × 100 = 0.20%. The percentage change in price would equal: (–$1/$439.50)
× 100 = –0.23%. The price elasticity of demand is: 0.20%/–0.23% = –0.87. If Ford’s belief
about the responsiveness of the quantity demanded for Model Ts to a change in their price was
accurate, then the demand for Model Ts was price inelastic.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


146 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

1.10 At a higher price, quantity demanded will decrease, so the total revenue (price × quantity sold)
will still be less than the total cost. Only in the very unlikely case where the demand for the
magazine is perfectly inelastic would the publisher’s analysis be correct.

6.2 The Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand


Learning Objective: List and explain the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.

Review Questions
2.1 The most important determinant of the price elasticity of demand is usually the availability of
substitutes for the product. If there are close substitutes, elasticity will be high because people can
switch to buying another good as the product’s price rises. Other factors determining the price
elasticity of demand for a product include the passage of time, whether the good is a necessity or
a luxury, how narrowly the market for the good is defined, and the share of the good in the
consumer’s budget.

2.2 The demand for most agricultural goods is inelastic. Food is a necessity, and the demand for
necessities tends to be less elastic than the demand for luxuries.

Problems and Applications


2.3 Milk (a) and prescription medicine (d) are likely to be price inelastic due to the lack of
substitutes, but frozen cheese pizza (b) and cola (c) are likely to be price elastic because they have
good substitutes, though we would expect a more narrowly defined product, such as Coca-Cola,
to be more elastic than a broadly defined product such as cola.

2.4
Percentage change in quantity demanded  14
   0.42
Percentage change in price 33

Because the price elasticity of demand was less than one (in absolute value) the demand for bus
rides was price inelastic. The five determinants of the price elasticity are: (a) the availability of
substitutes, (b) the passage of time, (c) whether the good is a luxury or a necessity, (d) the
definition of the market, and (e) the share of the good in a consumer’s budget. For many people
who do not own their own automobiles, there are no good substitutes for bus transportation,
which is more of a necessity than a luxury. These are probably the most important reasons why
demand was price inelastic.

2.5 The more narrowly a market is defined, the more elastic demand will be, because more
substitutes are available. The price elasticity of Coca-Cola (or any specific brand of soda) will be
higher than for soda as a product because there are more substitutes available for a specific
product like Coca-Cola than there are for a product category like soda.

2.6 It usually takes consumers some time to adjust their buying habits when prices change. The more
time passes, the more elastic the demand for a product becomes. In the case of oil prices, a good
part of the demand is determined by the demand for gasoline. Consumers are slow to react to
changes in gasoline prices because doing so often involves buying new cars, moving closer (or
farther away) from work, and so on.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 147

2.7 a. We can’t know with certainty from the information given whether in this case demand will be
elastic or inelastic. We can say, though, that a family that has driven to Yellowstone with the
intention of vacationing there is probably not going to be very responsive to changes in the
admission price because that price would likely make up only a small fraction of the family’s
vacation budget. So, it seems likely that demand for entry from someone driving a car,
minivan, or motor home will be inelastic.
b. Once again, we can’t answer this question with certainty from the information given. As
noted in part (a), someone arriving for a vacation in a private vehicle is likely to have an
inelastic demand for entering the park. Someone who is entering by foot, bike, or on skis
likely lives in the area or is staying close to the park. These people may have access to
recreational opportunities outside of the park and so may choose not to enter the park if the
price is too high. They are likely to have a more elastic demand for entering the park. People
who arrive by motorcycle may be intending to vacation in the park, or they be from the local
area and just planning a short visit. They are likely to have a price elasticity of demand that
is between the two other groups. This ordering of the groups from highest price elasticity of
demand to lowest corresponds to the ordering of prices charged by the National Park Service.

The Relationship between Price Elasticity of Demand and Total Revenue


6.3 Learning Objective: Explain the relationship between the price elasticity of demand
and total revenue.

Review Questions
3.1 If demand is inelastic, an increase in price will increase revenue because the price will increase
proportionally more than the quantity sold will decrease.

3.2 If revenue increases when price falls, other things remaining equal, then demand must be elastic.

Problems and Applications


3.3 The sportswriter is assuming the price elasticity of demand for Indians’ tickets is inelastic. If the
demand for Indians’ tickets is inelastic, then a decrease in price will lead to a decrease in total
revenue.

3.4 a. The observation that an increase in ticket prices to the opera “backfired” means that total
revenue from ticket sales decreased following the price increase.
b. Assuming that there were no other reasons why ticket revenue fell (for example, because of bad
weather on the dates of the performances or a negative reaction by the public to the operas
performed in 2012), the decline in revenue means that demand for opera tickets was elastic.

3.5 Elasticity = (percentage change in quantity/percentage change in price). The article states that
consumption decreases by 3 to 5 percent in response to a 10 percent increase in price, so the
range of elasticity is: (−3%/10%) = −0.3 to (−5%/10%) = −0.5. The demand for cigarettes is
inelastic because the elasticity values computed are both less than 1 in absolute value. Because
demand is inelastic, if price increases, revenue will also increase.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


148 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

3.6 a. The Coca-Cola executive’s comment suggests that he believes the demand for Coca-Cola is
inelastic. If he believes that consumers don’t care at all about price, then he believes that the
demand for Coke is perfectly inelastic. It is unlikely that the executive believes that demand
is perfectly inelastic, because it’s implausible that however high the firm raised the price,
consumers would buy the same quantity of Coke.
b. If the executive was correct, then by raising the per ounce price of Coca-Cola, the firm’s
revenues should increase.
c. It may be that placing cans of Coke near checkout lines “within arm’s reach” results in more
impulse buying on the part of shoppers. If this is true, then it could make the demand for
Coke more price inelastic. If Coke is the only soda that is displayed near checkout lines, then
shoppers who decide to buy soda at that point in their shopping trip would have no “close”
substitutes for Coke.

3.7 a. We can calculate the price elasticity along D1 between points A and C as follows:
300  200
Percentage change in quantity demanded = 100  40.0%
250
$2.50  $3.00
Percentage change in price =  100  18.2%
$2.75
40.0%
So, the price elasticity of demand =  2.2
18.2%
Similarly, the price elasticity of demand along D2 between points A and B can be calculated
as follows:
225  200
Percentage change in quantity demanded = 100  11.8%
212.5
$2.50  $3.00
Percentage change in price =  100  18.2%
$2.75
11.8%
So, the price elasticity of demand =  0.65
18.2%
Because the quantity response is much larger for the same price change, demand curve D1 is
much more elastic.
b. Along D1, revenue increases from $3 × 200 = $600 to $2.50 × 300 = $750. Revenue rises by
$150 as the price is cut because this demand curve is elastic between these prices. Along D2,
revenue falls from $600 to $2.50 × 225 = $562.50. Revenue falls by $37.50 as the price is cut
because D2 is inelastic between these prices.

3.8 Manager 2 is wrong. Cutting the price will increase revenue if demand is price elastic. But notice
that Manager 1 is just as wrong to say “only” as Manager 2 was to say “never.” Manager 1 says
the only way to boost revenue is by cutting the price, but if demand is inelastic, then cutting the
price will decrease revenue, not increase it.

3.9 a. Because Coca-Cola’s revenue rose while it sold 1 percent less soda in North America, it
must have raised its prices. Lowering its prices would have resulted in its selling more soda,
not less, holding all other factors constant.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 149

b. Because Coke’s revenue increased following an increase in price, we know that the demand
for Coke is price inelastic, holding all other factors constant.

3.10 a. No. If the demand for the publisher’s books is inelastic, then an increase in price will increase
total revenue.
b. The author of the article is assuming the demand for the publisher’s books is elastic. If
demand for the books is elastic, an increase in price will decrease total revenue.

3.11 Assuming that there was not an increase in demand for the author’s book(s), then a decrease in
price that resulted in an increase in income, or revenue, implies that the demand for her books
was price elastic.

3.12 a. For the Route 22 bridge:


433,691  519,337
Percentage change in quantity demanded =  100  18.0%
476,514
$1.00  $0.50
Percentage change in price =  100  66.7%
$0.75
18.0%
Therefore, the price elasticity of demand =  0.27
66.7%
For the Interstate 78 bridge:
656,257  728,022
Percentage change in quantity demanded =  100  10.4%
692,139.5
Percentage change in price = 66.7%.
 10.4%
Therefore, the price elasticity of demand =  0.16
66.7%
b. Revenue in November was (519,337 + 728,022) × $0.50 = $623,679.50. In December total
revenue increased to (433,691 + 656,257) × $1 = $1,089,948. The increase occurred because
the demand at both bridges is price inelastic.

Other Demand Elasticities


6.4 Learning Objective: Define cross-price elasticity of demand and income elasticity of
demand and understand their determinants and how they are measured.

Review Questions
4.1 Cross-price elasticity of demand equals the percentage change in quantity demanded of one good
divided by the percentage change in the price of another good. If the cross-price elasticity is
negative, then the goods are complements; if it is positive, then they are substitutes.

4.2 Income elasticity of demand equals the percentage change in the quantity demanded divided by
the percentage change in income. If the income elasticity is greater than 0, then the good is
normal; if it is less than 0, then the good is inferior. Goods with income elasticities between 0 and
1 are often called necessities; goods with income elasticities greater than 1 are often called
luxuries.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


150 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Problems and Applications


4.3 a. Lettuce has the higher price elasticity because the percentage change in quantity demanded
following a price increase is much larger for lettuce than for bread.
b. Positive. As the price of lettuce rises, the quantity demanded of the other green vegetables
rises, so they are substitutes.

4.4 To find the cross-price elasticity, divide the percentage change in the quantity demanded of buns
by the percentage change in the price of hot dogs. At the initial price of buns ($1.20), the quantity
demanded rises from 10,000 to 12,000, which is the change in quantity demanded that should be
used.
12,000  10,000
Percentage change in the quantity demanded =  100  18.2%
11,000
$1.80  $2.20
Percentage change in the price of hot dogs =  100  20.0%
$2.00
18.2%
So, the cross-price elasticity =  0.91.
20.0%
Because the cross-price elasticity of demand is negative, we know these two goods are
complements.

4.5 (a) and (c) are substitutes, so the cross-price elasticities will be positive; (b) and (d) are
complements, so the cross-price elasticities will be negative.

4.6 a. On the basis of the information given, the cross-price elasticity of demand is negative
(everything else equal) because the percentage change in ridership on mass transit increased
(by 1 percent) at the same time that gasoline prices decreased (by 33 percent). If the cross-
price elasticity of demand between two products is negative the products are considered
complements.
b. Because during the same period–late 2014–unemployment was falling and more people used
private and public transportation to commute to work, it is likely that “everything else” was
not equal; in addition to the changes in the price of transportation there was a simultaneous
increase in the demand for transportation. So we cannot be sure of the value of the cross-price
elasticity of demand between gasoline and rides on mass transit, or even whether the value is
positive or negative.

4.7 (a) Bread, (b) Pepsi, (d) laptop computers, (c) Mercedes-Benz automobiles is the most likely
order. For normal goods that are considered necessities (such as food and clothing), their income
elasticity is positive and less than 1. For normal goods that are considered luxuries (such as laptop
computers and Mercedes-Benz automobiles), their income elasticity is positive and greater than 1.
The items are ranked from most necessary to most luxurious.

4.8 The more narrowly we define a market, the more price elastic demand will be. So if data for only
one brand of beer is used instead of multiple brands, demand for beer will likely be more elastic,
which may not be an accurate estimate of the price elasticity for beer as a product.

4.9 During recessions, falling consumer incomes can cause firms selling luxury goods (goods with an
income elasticity of demand greater than 1) to see their sales decrease the most. During
recessions, falling consumer incomes can cause firms selling inferior goods (goods with an
income elasticity of demand less than 1) to see their sales increase the most.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 151

6.5 Using Elasticity to Analyze the Disappearing Family Farm


Learning Objective: Use price elasticity and income elasticity to analyze economic issues.

Review Questions
5.1 Increasing productivity in agriculture has brought about lower prices for food products as, over
time, increases in supply have dramatically outpaced increases in demand. Because the price
elasticity of demand for food is low, lower prices have not caused a large increase in quantity
demanded. The increase in incomes over time has not increased the demand for food much
because the income elasticity for food is low. Farmers, therefore, need to sell larger and larger
quantities of food at lower and lower prices to earn the same revenue. As a result, small farms are
no longer as profitable as they once were, and many people have abandoned farming to pursue
other occupations.

Problems and Applications


5.2 a. (Percentage change in price) × (price elasticity of demand) = percentage change in quantity:
50% × −0.25 = −12.5%. So, the quantity of cigarettes demanded should decline 12.5% from
its current level of 360 billion per year. 12.5% of 360 billion is 45 billion.
b. Raising the tax on cigarettes is a more effective way to reduce smoking if the demand for
cigarettes is elastic. With elastic demand, an increase in price resulting from a tax increase
would result in a greater reduction in the quantity demanded of cigarettes than if the demand
were inelastic.

5.3 a. We can plug into the midpoint formula the values given for the price elasticity, the original
price of $3.00, and the new price of $3.70 (= $3.00 + $0.70):

Percentage change in quantity demanded


0.55 

$3.70  $3.00 
 $3.70  $3.00 
 
 2 

Rearranging and writing out the expression for the percentage change in quantity demanded:

Q2 140 billion
0.11 
 140  Q 
 2

 2 

Solving for the new quantity demanded:

Q2 = 125.4 billion gallons

Because the price elasticity of demand for gasoline is low (0.55), a 21 percent increase in
price of gasoline leads to only about a 10 percent decline in gasoline consumption per year.
b. The federal government would collect an amount equal to the tax per gallon multiplied by the
number of gallons sold: $1 per gallon × 125.40 billion gallons = $125.4 billion.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


152 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

c. The answers are similar to Solved Problem 6.5 on page 201. Even though demand for
gasoline is more elastic in the long run than in the short run, the elasticity is still relatively
low, so the decline in the quantity of gasoline demanded is relatively small, and the
government collects a relatively large amount of tax revenue.

5.4 For the government policy to be effective, the demand for bribes must be elastic. The more elastic
the demand curve, the more effective the policy will be. On the graph, the burden of corruption
before the policy is enacted is represented by the area 0Q1AP1. The burden of corruption after the
policy is enacted is represented by the area 0Q2BP2. In effect, this problem is applying the result
that a price increase will result in an increase in revenue if demand is inelastic but a decrease in
revenue if demand is elastic.
Price of S2
bribes
Burden of
corruption
after policy
S1

B Burden of
P2 corruption
before policy

A
P1

Demand

0 Q2 Q1 Quantity of bribes

5.5 His reasoning is correct: Because the demand for kumquats is elastic, a price increase resulting from
the implementation of a price floor will decrease the revenue received by kumquat producers.

5.6 Imposing a price ceiling causes the market quantity to decline from Q1 to Q2 and the price to
decline from P1 to PC. We measure the loss of efficiency by the deadweight loss. When demand is
elastic D2), the deadweight loss in the figure is A. When demand is inelastic (D1), the deadweight
loss is A + B. Therefore, the loss of economic efficiency from a price ceiling is greater when
demand is price inelastic.
Price

Supply
B

P1
A

Price ceiling
PC
Elastic
D2
Inelastic

Demand, D1

0 Q2 Q1 Quantity

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 153

The Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Measurement


6.6 Learning Objective: Define price elasticity of supply and understand its main
determinants and how it is measured.

Review Questions
6.1 The price elasticity of supply = (percentage change in quantity supplied)/(percentage change in
price). In this case, the elasticity of supply = 9%/10% = 0.9. The dividing point between elastic
and inelastic is 1.0, so the price elasticity of supply for frozen pizzas is inelastic.
6.2 The main determinant of the price elasticity of supply is time. The longer the time period, the
more firms are able to adjust the quantity they supply to a change in price. So, we would expect
that as the time period increases, the price elasticity of supply will increase. An exception to this
rule is products that require use of a resource that is in fixed supply, such as wine from a
particular region in France.

Problems and Applications


6.3 Regardless of the number of tickets sold for these games, the quantity supplied of tickets–tickets
offered for sale—was 49,170 for each game. Assuming that the number of seats does not change
throughout the 2015 season the supply of tickets would be perfectly inelastic.
6.4 a. The limitation on the number of taxi medallions implies that the supply of medallions is
perfectly inelastic.
b. The supply of Uber rides is more elastic than the supply of taxis, since the number of Uber
rides varies as the demand for rides varies.
6.5 A small increase in the supply of oil would lead to a large decline in price if the demand for oil is
relatively inelastic.
6.6 a. The following graph shows that when demand is very inelastic (demand curves D1 and D2),
an increase in demand from D1 to D2 results in an increase in the price of oil from $40 to
$110. If demand is more elastic (demand curves D3 and D4), then a shift in demand from D3
to D4 results in a much smaller increase in price—from $40 only to P1.
Price Supply
(dollars
per
barrel)

$110

P1

40

D4
D1 D3 D2
0 85 89 Quantity
(millions of barrels
per day)

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


154 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

b. The graph below shows that an increase in the supply of oil from S1 to S2 will result in a
smaller change in price when demand is relatively elastic (D2) than when demand is relatively
inelastic (D1). With the more inelastic demand curve (D1), the equilibrium price falls from
$110 to $47. With the more elastic demand curve (D2), the price only falls from $110 to P1.
Price S1 S2
(dollars
per
barrel)

$110

P1

47 D2

D1

0 85 89 Quantity
(millions of barrels
per day)

6.7 To find the price elasticity of supply, divide the percentage change in quantity supplied by
percentage change in price. In panel (a), the percentage change in quantity supplied =
1, 400  1, 200 $4  $2
 100  15.4% , and the percentage change in price =  100  66.7% . So,
1,300 $3
15.4%
the price elasticity of supply =  0.23. In panel (b), the percentage change in quantity
66.7%
2,100  1,200
supplied =  100  54.5% , and the percentage change in price =
1,650
$2.50  $2.00 54.5%
 100  22.2%. So, the price elasticity of supply =  2.45.
$2.25 22.2%

6.8 Because it can take years to attract skilled construction workers back to the area or to train new
workers, it is likely that the supply of housing in Denver will be considerably more elastic in the
long run than in the short run. The following graph illustrates this point by comparing the market
for housing in the short run (S2014), when supply is relatively inelastic, and for a longer time
period (S 2018), when supply is more elastic. The graph shows that, holding other factors constant,
an increase in demand from D1 to D2 increases the price of housing from P1 to P2 when supply is
inelastic in the short run, but only from P1 to P3 when supply is more elastic in the long run. The
price increase will be lower the longer the period of time the market has to adjust to a given
increase in demand.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply 155

Price
S2014

S2018
P2
P3

P1

D2

D1

Quantity of
houses in Denver

6.9 a. The increase in demand for roses on Valentine’s Day causes the price to increase from $1 to
$2.

b. Based on this information, we don’t know much about the price elasticity of demand for
roses. The demand curve has shifted, so the rise in the quantity of roses demanded is not
caused by the rise in their price—and we can’t calculate the price elasticity of demand. We
have a movement along the supply curve, so we can calculate the price elasticity of supply for
roses.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.


Microeconomics 6th Edition Hubbard Solutions Manual

156 CHAPTER 6 | Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

The price elasticity of supply elasticity = (percentage change in quantity supplied)/(percentage


change in price). So, using the midpoint formula:
30,000  8,000
Percentage change in the quantity supplied = 100  115.8%
19,000
$2.00  $1.00
Percentage change in the price = 100  66.7%
$1.50
115.8%
Therefore, the price elasticity of supply =  1.74.
66.7%
The fact that the elasticity doesn’t have a negative sign is a reminder that with an upward-
sloping supply curve, increases in price to lead to increases in the quantity supplied, so the
price elasticity of supply must be positive. The supply of roses is price elastic given the
elasticity is greater than one.

6.10 a. Price elasticity of supply is the percentage change in the quantity supplied divided by the
percentage change in price. In this case, the percentage change in supply is always zero,
because the quantity supplied by the university does not change in response to changes in
demand, so the price elasticity of supply is 0.
b. As shown in the following graph, when the demand curve for basketball tickets shifts from
D1 to D2, the equilibrium price increases from $15 to $20, but there is no change in the
equilibrium quantity.

Price S
(dollars
per ticket)

$20

15

D2
D1

15,000 Quantity
(tickets per game)

c. One determinant of price elasticity of supply is the period of time. Over a longer period of
time, supply is more price elastic. So, although the supply curve for basketball tickets is
perfectly inelastic in the short run, it is possible that over time State University could build a
larger basketball arena with more seats to accommodate more fans.

Copyright © 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.

Visit TestBankBell.com to get complete for all chapters

You might also like