You are on page 1of 67

MICRO ECON 6: Principles of

Microeconomics - eBook PDF


Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://ebooksecure.com/download/micro-econ-6-principles-of-microeconomics-ebook
-pdf/
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
YOUR
FEED-
BACK
YOUR
BOOKOur research never ends. Continual feedback from you ensures
that we keep up with your changing needs.

www.cengagebrain.com

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Inside Front Cover (8.5”)


Inside Back Cover (8.5")
YOUR
FEED-
BACK
YOUR
BOOKOur research never ends. Continual feedback from you ensures
that we keep up with your changing needs.

www.cengagebrain.com

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
micro

ECON Principles of Microeconomics


6

william a. M c Eachern
University of Connecticut

Australia • Brazil • Mexico • Singapore • United Kingdom • United States

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
This is an electronic version of the print textbook. Due to electronic rights restrictions,
some third party content may be suppressed. Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed
content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. The publisher reserves the right
to remove content from this title at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. For
valuable information on pricing, previous editions, changes to current editions, and alternate
formats, please visit www.cengage.com/highered to search by ISBN#, author, title, or keyword for
materials in your areas of interest.

Important Notice: Media content referenced within the product description or the product
text may not be available in the eBook version.

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Micro ECON6 © 2019, 2017 Cengage Learning, Inc.
Will McEachern Unless otherwise noted, all content is © Cengage.

ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. No part of this work covered by the copyright herein
Senior Vice President, Higher Ed Product, may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, except as
­Content, and Market Development: Erin Joyner permitted by U.S. copyright law, without the prior written permission of the
Product Manager: Chris Rader copyright owner.

Content/Media Developer: Sarah Keeling

Product Assistant: Denisse Zavala-Rosales For product information and technology assistance, contact us at
Cengage Customer & Sales Support, 1-800-354-9706 or
Marketing Manager: John Carey
support.cengage.com.

Marketing Coordinator: Audrey Jacobs


For permission to use material from this text or product,
Content Project Manager: Darrell E. Frye submit all requests online at www.cengage.com/permissions.

Sr. Art Director: Bethany Bourgeois

Internal Designer: Lou Ann


Library of Congress Control Number: 2017959260
Thesing/Thesing Design

Cover Designer: Lisa Kuhn, Curio Press, Student Edition ISBN: 978-1-337-40806-6
LLC / Bethany Bourgeois Student Edition with MindTap ISBN: 978-1-337-40805-9

Cover Image: Shutterstock.com/Carlos Castilla,


Maria Kazanova/Shutterstock.com Cengage
20 Channel Center Street
Intellectual Property Analyst: Diane Garrity Boston, MA 02210

Intellectual Property Project Manager: USA

Sarah Shainwald
Cengage is a leading provider of customized learning solutions with
Production Service: SPi Global employees residing in nearly 40 different countries and sales in more
than 125 countries around the world. Find your local representative at
www.cengage.com.

Cengage products are represented in Canada by


Nelson Education, Ltd.

To learn more about Cengage platforms and services, visit


www.cengage.com.

To register or access your online learning solution or purchase materials


for your course, visit www.cengagebrain.com.

Printed in the United States of America


Print Number: 01 Print Year: 2017

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
M cE ac h e r n

ECONMICRO
6 Brief
Contents
Part 1 Introduction to Economics
1 The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 2
2 Economic Tools and ­Economic Systems 24
3 Economic Decision Makers 40
4 Demand, Supply, and Markets 56

Part 2 Introduction to the Market System


5 Elasticity of Demand and Supply 74
6 Consumer Choice and Demand 92
7 Production and Cost in the Firm 104

Part 3 Market Structure and Pricing


8 Perfect Competition 120
9 Monopoly 142
10 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly 160

Part 4 Resource Markets


11 Resource Markets 180
12 Labor Markets and Labor Unions 196
13 Capital, Interest, ­Entrepreneurship,
and Corporate Finance 216
14 Transaction Costs, ­Asymmetric Information,
and Behavioral Economics 234

Part 5 Market Failure and Public Policy


15 Economic Regulation and Antitrust Policy 252
Shutterstock.com/Carlos Castilla, Maria Kazanova/Shutterstock.com

16 Public Goods and Public Choice 268


17 Externalities and the Environment 284
18 Poverty and Redistribution 304

Part 6 International Economics


19 International Trade 324
20 International Finance 344
21 Economic Development 360

Index 380

BRIEF CONTENTS iii


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Contents
2-4 Economic Systems 34
Part 1 2-5 Final Word 37

Introduction to economics 3 Economic Decision Makers 40


3-1 The Household 41
3-2 The Firm 43
3-3 The Government 47

© Cartoon Network /Everett Collection


3-4 The Rest of the World 53
3-5 Final Word 54

4 Demand, Supply, and Markets 56


4-1 Demand 57
4-2 What Shifts a Demand Curve? 60
4-3 Supply 62

1 The Art and Science of Economic


Analysis 2
4-4 What Shifts a Supply Curve? 63
4-5 Demand and Supply Create a Market 65
4-6 Changes in Equilibrium Price
1-1 The Economic Problem: Scarce Resources, ­ and Quantity 67
Unlimited Wants 3 4-7 Disequilibrium 70
1-2 The Art of Economic Analysis 7 4-8 Final Word 71
1-3 The Science of Economic Analysis 10
1-4 Some Pitfalls of Faulty ­Economic
Analysis 13
1-5 If Economists Are So Smart, Why Aren’t
Part 2
They Rich? 14
1-6 Final Word 15
Introduction to the
A1-1 Understanding Graphs 18 Market System
2 Economic Tools and E­ conomic
Systems 24
Archive Photos/Getty Images

2-1 Choice and Opportunity Cost 25


2-2 Comparative Advantage, ­Specialization,
and Exchange 27
2-3 The Economy’s Production
Possibilities 30

iv CONTENTS

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
5 Elasticity of Demand and Supply 74 8 Perfect Competition 120
5-1 Price Elasticity of Demand 75 8-1 An Introduction to Perfect
5-2 Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand 80 Competition 121

5-3 Price Elasticity of Supply 83 8-2 Short-Run Profit Maximization 123

5-4 Other Elasticity Measures 86 8-3 Short-Run Loss Minimization 126

5-5 Final Word 88 8-4 Short-Run Supply Curves 129

A5-1 Price Elasticity and Tax Incidence 90 8-5 Perfect Competition in


the Long Run 132

6 Consumer Choice and Demand 92 8-6 Long-Run Industry Supply


Curve 135
6-1 Utility Analysis 93 8-7 Perfect Competition
and Efficiency 137
6-2 Measuring Utility 95
8-8 Final Word 139
6-3 Applications of ­Utility Analysis 99

9 Monopoly 142
6-4 Final Word 102

7 Production and Cost in the Firm 104 9-1


9-2
Barriers to Entry 143
Revenue for a Monopolist 145
7-1 Cost and Profit 105
7-2 Production in the Short Run 107 9-3 Profit Maximization and Cost Minimization
for a Monopolist 147
7-3 Costs in the Short Run 109
9-4 Perfect Competition and Monopoly
7-4 Costs in the Long Run 113 Compared 152
7-5 Final Word 117 9-5 Problems with Deadweight Loss
Estimates 154

Part 3
9-6 Price Discrimination 155
9-7 Final Word 158

Market Structure 10 Mandonopolistic Competition


and Pricing Oligopoly 160
10-1 Monopolistic Competition 161
10-2 Oligopoly 167
10-3 Three Approaches to
Oligopoly 169
10-4 Comparison of Oligopoly and Perfect
iStockphoto.com/Alle12

Competition 176
10-5 Final Word 177

CONTENTS v
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
13-6 Corporate Finance 228
Part 4 13-7 Final Word 232

Resource Markets 14 Information,


Transaction Costs, ­Asymmetric
and Behavioral
Economics 234
14-1 The Firm’s Rationale and Scope of Operation 235
14-2 Market Behavior with ­Imperfect Information 240
Richard Cavalleri/Shutterstock.com

14-3 Asymmetric Information in Product Markets 242


14-4 Asymmetric Information in Labor Markets 246
14-5 Behavioral Economics 247
14-6 Final Word 249

Part 5
11 Resource Markets 180 Market Failure and
11-1 The Once-Over 181
11-2 Demand and Supply of Resources 182
Public Policy
11-3 Temporary and Permanent Resource
Price Differences 184
11-4 Opportunity Cost and Economic
Zhao jian kang/Shutterstock.com

Rent 185
11-5 A Closer Look at Resource Demand 188
11-6 Final Word 193

12 LUnions
abor Markets and Labor
196
12-1 Labor Supply 197
12-2 Why Wages Differ 202 15 Eand
conomic Regulation
Antitrust Policy 252
12-3 Unions and Collective Bargaining 205
12- 4 Union Wages and Employment 207 15-1 Types of Government Regulation 253
12-5 Final Word 213 15-2 Regulating a Natural Monopoly 254
15-3 Alternative Theories of Economic Regulation 256

13 and
Capital, Interest, E­ ntrepreneurship,
Corporate Finance 216
15-4 Antitrust Law and Enforcement 258
15-5 Competitive Trends in the U.S. Economy 264
15-6 Final Word 266
13-1 The Role of Time in ­Production

16 PChoice
and Consumption 217
13-2 The Market for Loanable Funds 221 ublic Goods and Public
13-3 Why Interest Rates Differ 222 268
13-4 Present Value and Discounting 224 16-1 Public Goods 269
13-5 Entrepreneurship 226 16-2 Public Choice in ­Representative Democracy 272

vi CONTENTS

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
19
16-3 Exploiting Government ­versus Avoiding
Government 277 International Trade 324
16-4 Bureaucracy and ­Representative Democracy 279 19-1 The Gains from Trade 325
16-5 Final Word 281 19-2 Trade Restrictions and Welfare Loss 332

17
19-3 Efforts to Reduce Trade Barriers 336
Externalities and the 19-4 Arguments for Trade Restrictions 338
Environment 284 19-5 Final Word 341
17-1 Externalities and the ­Common-Pool Problem 285
17-2 Optimal Level of Pollution 287
17-3 Environmental Protection 293
20 International Finance 344
20-1 Balance of Payments 345
17-4 Positive Externalities 298
20-2 Foreign Exchange Rates and Markets 350
17-5 Final Word 299
20-3 Other Factors Influencing Foreign Exchange
Markets 353
18 Poverty and Redistribution 304 20-4 International Monetary System 355
20-5 Final Word 357
18-1 The Distribution of ­Household Income 305

21
18-2 Redistribution Programs 310
18-3 Who Are the Poor 315 Economic Development 360
18-4 Some Unintended ­Consequences of Income 21-1 Worlds Apart 361
­Assistance 318
21-2 Productivity: Key to Development 366
18-5 Welfare Reforms 319
21-3 International Trade and Development 372
18-6 Final Word 321
21-4 Foreign Aid and Economic Development 374
21-5 Final Word 378

Part 6 Index 380

International Economics
iStockphoto.com/Rafael Ramirez

CONTENTS vii
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Part 1

1 The Art and Science


of Economic Analysis
© Cartoon Network /Everett Collection

LEARNING OUTCOMES After finishing this chapter


After studying this chapter, you will be able to…
go to PAGE 16 for STUDY TOOLS
1-1 Explain the economic problem of scarce resources and unlimited wants Topics discussed in Chapter 1 include
1-2 Describe the forces that shape economic choices
• The economic problem
• The scientific method
1-3 Explain the relationship between economic theory and economic reality • Marginal analysis
• Normative versus positive analysis
1-4 Identify some pitfalls of economic analysis
• Rational self-interest
1-5 Describe several reasons to study economics • Some pitfalls of economic thinking

2 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
▸▸ Why are comic strip and TV characters like those ▸▸ Why is a good theory like a closet organizer?
in Adventure Time, The Simpsons, and Family Guy ▸▸ What’s the big idea with economics?
­missing a finger on each hand?
Finally, how can it be said that in economics “what goes
▸▸ Which college majors pay the most? around comes around”? These and other questions are
▸▸ In what way are people who pound on vending answered in this chapter, which ­introduces the art and
machines r­ elying on theory? ­science of economic analysis.

Y
ou have been reading and hearing about or off campus, take a course in accounting or
economic issues for years—unemployment, one in history, get married or stay single, pack
inflation, poverty, recessions, federal defi- a lunch or buy a sandwich. You already know
cits, college tuition, airfares, stock prices, com- much more about economics than you realize.
puter prices, smartphone prices, and gas prices. You bring to the subject a rich personal experi-
When explanations of such issues go into any ence, an experience that will be tapped through-
depth, your eyes may glaze over and you may out the book to reinforce your understanding of
tune out, the same way you do when a weather the basic ideas.
forecaster tries to explain high-pressure fronts
colliding with moisture carried in from the coast.
What many people fail to realize is that
economics is livelier than the dry accounts
offered by the news media. Economics is about
“ Why are comic strip and TV
characters like those in Adventure
­

making choices, and you make economic choices Time, The Simpsons, and Family Guy
every day—choices about whether to get a part-
time job or focus on your studies, live in a dorm
missing a finger on each hand?

1-1  THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM: unlimited wants exists to a greater or lesser extent for
each of the 7.5 billion people on earth. Everybody—
SCARCE RESOURCES, ­ cab driver, farmer, brain surgeon, dictator, shepherd,
student, politician—faces the problem. For example, a
UNLIMITED WANTS cab driver uses time and other scarce resources, such
as the taxi, knowledge of the city, driving skills, and
Would you like a new car, a nicer home, a smarter phone, gasoline, to earn income. That income, in turn, buys
tastier meals, more free time, a more interesting social housing, groceries, clothing, trips to Disney World, and
life, more spending money, more leisure, more sleep? thousands of other goods and services that help satisfy
Who wouldn’t? But even if you can satisfy some of these some of the driver’s unlimited wants. ­Economics exam-
desires, others keep popping up. The problem is that ines how people use their scarce resources to satisfy
although your wants, or desires, are virtually unlimited, their unlimited wants. Let’s pick apart the definition,
the resources available to satisfy these wants are scarce. b eginning with resources,
­
A resource is scarce when it is not freely available—that then goods and services, and
is, when its price exceeds zero. Because resources are finally focus on the heart economics The study of
how people use their scarce
scarce, you must choose from among your many wants, of the matter—economic
resources to satisfy their
and whenever you choose, you must forgo satisfying choice, which results from unlimited wants
some other wants. The problem of scarce resources but scarcity.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 3


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
such as bodies of water, trees, oil reserves, minerals,
1-1a Resources and even animals. Natural resources can be divided
Resources are the inputs, or factors of production, used into renewable resources and exhaustible resources. A
to produce the goods and services that people want. Goods renewable resource can be drawn on indefinitely if used
and services are scarce because resources are scarce. conservatively. Thus, timber is a renewable resource if
Resources sort into four broad categories: labor, capital, felled trees are replaced to regrow a steady supply. The
natural resources, and entrepreneurial ability. Labor is air and rivers are renewable resources if they are allowed
human effort, both physical and mental. Labor includes sufficient time to cleanse themselves of any pollutants.
the effort of the cab driver More generally, biological resources like fish, game, live-
resources The inputs, or and the brain surgeon. Labor stock, forests, rivers, groundwater, grasslands, and soil are
factors of production, used to itself comes from a more renewable if managed properly. An exhaustible resource—
produce the goods and services fundamental resource: time. such as oil or coal—does not renew itself and so is avail-
that people want; consist of
labor, capital, natural resources,
Without time we can accom- able in a limited amount. Once burned, each barrel of
and entrepreneurial ability plish nothing. We allocate our oil or ton of coal is gone forever. The world’s oil and coal
time to alternative uses: We deposits are exhaustible.
labor The physical and men-
tal effort used to produce goods can sell our time as labor, or A special kind of human skill called e
­ ntrepreneurial
and services we can spend our time doing ability is the talent required to dream up a new prod-
other things, like sleeping, eat- uct or find a better way to produce an existing one,
capital The buildings,
­equipment, and human skills ing, studying, playing sports, organize production, and assume the risk of profit or
used to produce goods and going online, attending class, loss. This special skill comes from an entrepreneur. An
services watching TV, or just relaxing ­entrepreneur is a profit-seeking decision maker who
natural resources All with friends. starts with an idea, organizes an enterprise to bring that
gifts of nature used to produce Capital includes all idea to life, and then assumes the risk of operation. An
goods and services; includes human creations used to entrepreneur pays resource owners for the opportunity
renewable and exhaustible
produce goods and services. to employ their resources in the firm. Every firm in the
resources
Economists often distinguish world today, such as Ford, Microsoft, Google, and Face-
entrepreneurial between physical capital book, began as an idea in the mind of an entrepreneur.
­ability The imagination
and human capital. Physical Resource owners are paid wages for their labor,
required to develop a new prod-
uct or process, the skill needed capital consists of factories, interest for the use of their capital, and rent for the
to organize production, and the tools, machines, computers, use of their natural resources. Entrepreneurial ability is
willingness to take the risk of buildings, airports, high- rewarded by profit, which equals the revenue from items
profit or loss
ways, and other human cre- sold minus the cost of the resources employed to make
entrepreneur A profit- ations used to produce goods those items. Sometimes the entrepreneur suffers a loss.
seeking decision maker who and services. Physical capi- Resource earnings are usually based on the time these
starts with an idea, organizes an
tal includes the cab driver’s resources are employed. Resource payments therefore
enterprise to bring that idea to
life, and assumes the risk of the taxi, the surgeon’s scalpel, have a time dimension, as in a wage of $10 per hour,
operation and the building where your interest of 6 percent per year, rent of $600 per month, or
wages Payment to resource economics class meets (or, profit of $10,000 per year.
owners for their labor if you are taking this course
online, your computer and
interest Payment to
online connectors). Human
1-1b Goods and Services
resource owners for the use of
their capital capital consists of the knowl- Resources are combined in a variety of ways to produce
edge and skill people acquire goods and services. A farmer, a tractor, 50 acres of land,
rent Payment to resource
owners for the use of their natu- to increase their productiv- seeds, and fertilizer combine to grow the good: corn.
ral resources ity, such as the cab driver’s One hundred musicians, musical instruments, chairs, a
knowledge of city streets, conductor, a musical score, and a music hall combine
profit Reward for entrepre-
neurial ability; sales revenue the surgeon’s knowledge of to produce the service: Beethoven’s Fifth Symphony.
minus resource cost human anatomy, and your Corn is a good because it is something you can see,
knowledge of economics. feel, and touch; it requires scarce resources to produce;
good A tangible product
used to satisfy human wants Natural resources and it satisfies human wants. The book you are now
include all gifts of nature, holding, the chair you are sitting in, the clothes you are

4 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
clean seawater have become scarce. Goods and

© laola/Shutterstock.com; © Colia/Shutterstock.com; © Utekhina Anna/Shutterstock.com; © james


weston/Shutterstock.com; © Elena Elisseeva/Shutterstock.com; © zimmytws/Shutterstock.com
services that are truly free are not the subject of
economics. Without scarcity, there would be no
economic problem and no need for prices.
Sometimes we mistakenly think of certain
goods as free because they involve no appar-
ent cost to us. Napkins seem to be free at Star-
bucks. Nobody stops you from taking a fistful.
Supplying napkins, however, costs the company
millions each year and prices reflect that cost.
Some restaurants make special efforts to keep
napkin use down— such as packing them tightly
into the dispenser or making you ask for them.
Moreover, Starbucks recently reduced the
thickness of its napkins.
You may have heard the expression “There
is no such thing as a free lunch.” There is no free
lunch because all goods and services involve a
cost to someone. The lunch may seem free to
you, but it draws scarce resources away from
Scarcity means you must choose among options. the production of other goods and services, and
whoever provides a free lunch often expects
wearing, and your next meal are all goods. The perfor- something in return. A Russian proverb makes
mance of the Fifth Symphony is a service because it is a similar point but with a bit more bite: “The only place
intangible, yet it uses scarce resources to satisfy human you find free cheese is in a mousetrap.” Albert Einstein
wants. Lectures, movies, concerts, phone service, wire- once observed, “Sometimes one pays the most for things
less connections, yoga lessons, dry cleaning, and hair- one gets for nothing.”
cuts are all services.
Because goods and services are produced using Economic Decision
1-1c
scarce resources, they are themselves scarce. A good
or service is scarce if the amount people desire exceeds
Makers and Markets
the amount available at a zero price. Because we cannot There are four types of decision makers in the economy:
have all the goods and services we would like, we must households, firms, governments, and the rest of the
continually choose among them. We must choose among world. Their interaction determines how an economy’s
more pleasant living quarters, better meals, nicer clothes, resources are allocated. Households play the starring
more reliable transportation, faster computers, smarter role. As consumers, households demand the goods and
phones, and so on. Making choices in a world of scarcity services produced. As resource owners, households sup-
means we must pass up some goods and services. But not ply labor, capital, natural resources, and entrepreneurial
everything is scarce. In fact, some things we would prefer ability to firms, governments, and the rest of the world.
to have less of. For example, we would prefer to have Firms, governments, and the rest of the world demand
less garbage, less spam email, fewer telemarketing calls, the resources that households supply and then use these
and less pollution. Things we want none of even at a zero resources to supply the goods and services that house-
price are called bads, the opposite of goods. holds demand. The rest of
A few goods and services seem free because the the world includes foreign
amount available at a zero price exceeds the amount households, foreign firms, service An activity, or intan-
gible product, used to satisfy
­people want. For example, air and seawater often seem and foreign governments
human wants
free because we can breathe all the air we want and have that supply resources and
all the seawater we can haul away. Yet, despite the old say- products to U.S. demand- scarcity Occurs when the
amount people desire exceeds
ing “The best things in life are free,” most goods and ser- ers and demand resources
the amount available at a zero
vices are scarce, not free, and even those that appear to be and products from U.S. price
free come with strings attached. For example, clean air and suppliers.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 5


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Markets are the means
by which buyers and sellers Exhibit 1.1
carry out exchange at mutu- The Simple Circular-Flow Model for Households and Firms
ally agreeable terms. By Households earn income by supplying resources to resource markets, as shown in
bringing together the two the lower portion of the model. Firms demand these resources to produce goods and
­services, which they supply to product markets, as shown in the upper portion of the
sides of exchange, markets model. Households spend their income to demand these goods and services. This
determine price, quantity, ­spending flows through product markets as revenue to firms.
and quality. Markets are
often physical places, such
as supermarkets, depart-
ment stores, shopping malls,
yard sales, flea markets, and Product
markets
swap meets. But markets Go
o
also include other mecha- ts ds
uc Re
ve

an
nisms by which buyers and nu

o
Pr

d
e e

se
sellers communicate, such

rv
tu

ice
di
as classified ads, radio and en

s
Exp

television ads, telephones,


bulletin boards, online sites,
and face-to-face bargaining.
These market mechanisms
provide information about
the quantity, quality, and Households Firms

price of products offered for

t
ro fi
Lab entre

sale. Goods and services are

,p
or,

nt
bought and sold in ­product
ca pren

re
pit

t,
co

es
In

markets. Resources are er


al, eur

m nt
,i

es
tu e
na

bought and sold in resource s


ge

rc
ia ral u
l a re Wa so
markets. The most impor- bil so Re
ity urc
tant resource market is the es, Resource
markets
labor, or job, market. Think
about your own experience
looking for a job, and you’ll
already have some idea of
that market.

model focuses on the primary interaction in a market


­economy—that between households and firms. Exhibit 1.1
market A set of arrange-
ments by which buyers and
1-1dA Simple shows households on the left and firms on the right;
sellers carry out exchange at Circular-Flow please take a look.
mutually agreeable terms Households supply labor, capital, natural resources,
Model and entrepreneurial ability to firms through resource mar-
product market A
market in which a good or Now that you have learned a kets, shown in the lower portion of the exhibit. In return,
service is bought and sold bit about economic decision households demand goods and services from firms through
resource market A makers and markets, consider product markets, shown on the upper portion of the exhibit.
market in which a resource is how all these interact. Such Viewed from the business end, firms demand labor, capital,
bought and sold a picture is conveyed by the natural resources, and entrepreneurial ability from house-
circular-flow model A circular-flow model, which holds through resource markets, and firms supply goods
diagram that traces the describes the flow of resources, and services to households through product markets.
flow of resources, products, products, income, and revenue The flows of resources and products are supported
income, and revenue among
economic decision makers
among economic decision mak- by the flows of income and expenditure—that is, by the
ers. The simple circular-flow flow of money. So let’s add money. The demand and
6 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
supply of resources come together in resource m
­ arkets to 1-2a Rational Self-Interest
determine what firms pay for resources. These resource
prices—wages, interest, rent, and profit—flow as income A key economic assumption is that individuals, in mak-
to households. The demand and supply of products ing choices, rationally select what they perceive to be in
come together in product markets to determine what their best interests. By rational, economists mean sim-
households pay for goods and services. These expen- ply that people try to make the best choices they can,
ditures on goods and services flow as revenue to firms. given the available time and information. People may not
Resources and products flow in one direction—in this know with certainty which alternative will turn out to be
case, ­counterclockwise—and the corresponding pay- the best. They simply select the alternatives they expect
ments flow in the other direction—clockwise. What goes will yield the most satisfaction and happiness. In general,
around comes around. Take a little time now to trace the rational ­self-interest means that each individual tries
logic of the circular flows. to maximize the expected benefit achieved with a given
cost or to minimize the expected cost of achieving a given
benefit. Thus, economists begin with the assumption that

1-2 THE ART OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS people look out for their self-
interest. For example, a phy- rational self-interest
sician who owns a pharmacy Each individual tries to
An economy results as millions of individuals attempt to prescribes 8 percent more ­maximize the expected benefit
satisfy their unlimited wants. Because their choices lie at achieved with a given cost or to
drugs on average than a phy-
minimize the expected cost of
the heart of the economic problem—coping with scarce sician who does not own a achieving a given benefit
resources but unlimited wants—these choices deserve a pharmacy.1
closer look. Learning about the forces that shape eco-
nomic choices is the first step toward understanding the 1. Brian Chen, Paul Gertler, and Chuh-Yuh Yang, “Moral Hazard and Econo-
mies of Scope in Physician Ownership of Complementary Medical Services,”
art of economic analysis. NBER Working Paper 19622 (November 2013).

TEN-yard Penalty for Biased Rankings


As one more example of self-interest, the USA Today weekly football poll asks coaches to list the top 25 teams in the country. ­Economists
who study the rankings found that coaches distort their selections to favor their own teams and their own conferences.
Moreover, to make their own records look better, coaches inflate the rankings of teams they have beaten.

Jeff Schultes/Shutterstock.com

Source: Matthew Kotchen and Matthew Potoski, “Conflicts of Interest Distort Public Evaluations: Evidence from the Top 25 Ballots of NCAA Football
Coaches,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 107 (November 2014): 51–63.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 7


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Rational self-interest should not be viewed as blind and guidance counselors. You likely used school cata-
materialism, pure selfishness, or greed. For most of us, logs, college guides, and websites. You may have even
self-interest often includes the welfare of our family, our visited some campuses to meet the admissions staff
friends, and perhaps the poor of the world. Even so, our and anyone else willing to talk. The decision took time
concern for others is influenced by our personal cost of and money, and it probably involved aggravation and
that concern. We may readily volunteer to drive a friend anxiety.
to the airport on Saturday afternoon but are less likely Because information is costly to acquire, we are
to offer a ride if the flight leaves at 6:00 a.m. When we often willing to pay others to gather and digest it for
donate clothes to an organization such as Goodwill Indus- us. College guidebooks, stock analysts, travel agents,
tries, they are more likely to be old and worn than brand real estate brokers, career counselors, restaurant crit-
new. People tend to give more to charities when their ics, movie reviewers, specialized websites, and Con-
contributions are tax deductible and when contributions sumer Reports magazine attest to our willingness to
garner social approval in the community (as when con- pay for information that improves our choices. As we’ll
tributor names are made public or when big donors get see next, rational decision makers continue to acquire
buildings named after them).2 TV stations are more likely information as long as the additional benefit expected
to donate airtime for public-service announcements dur- from that information exceeds the additional cost of
ing the dead of night than during prime time (which is gathering it.
why 80 percent of such announcements air between 11:00
p.m. and 7:00 a.m.). 1-2cEconomic Analysis
The notion of self-interest does not rule out concern
for others; it simply means that concern for others is Is Marginal Analysis
influenced by the same economic forces that affect other Economic choice usually involves some adjustment to
economic choices. The lower the personal cost of help- the existing situation, or status quo. Amazon.com must
ing others, the more help we offer. We don’t like to think decide whether to add a new line of products. The
that our behavior reflects our self-interest, but it usually school superintendent must decide whether to hire
does. As Jane Austen wrote in Pride and Prejudice, “I another teacher. Your favorite jeans are on sale, and
have been a selfish being all my life, in practice, though you must decide whether to buy another pair. You are
not in principle.” wondering whether to register for an extra course next

1-2bChoice Requires Time


and Information
Rational choice takes time and requires information,
but time and information are themselves scarce and
therefore valuable. If you have any doubts about the
MSPhotographic/Shutterstock.com

time and information needed to make choices, talk to


someone who recently purchased a home, a car, or a
personal computer. Talk to a corporate official trying
to decide whether to introduce a new product, sell
online, build a new factory, or buy another firm. Or
think back to your own experience in choosing a col-
lege. You probably talked to friends, relatives, teachers,
When deciding whether to order dessert, ask
yourself, “is the marginal benefit higher than the
2. Dean Karlan and Margaret McConnell, “Hey Look at Me: The Effect of
Giving Circles on Giving,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization marginal cost?”
(forthcoming).

8 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
term. You just finished lunch and are deciding whether the choices of various decision makers. Microeconomics
to order dessert. explains how price and quantity are determined in indi-
Economic choice is based on a comparison of the vidual markets—the market for breakfast cereal, sports
expected marginal benefit and the expected marginal equipment, or used cars, for instance.
cost of the action under consideration. Marginal means You have probably given little thought to what influ-
incremental, additional, or extra. Marginal refers to a ences your own economic choices. You have likely given
change in an economic variable, a change in the status even less thought to how your choices link up with those
quo. A rational decision maker changes the status quo if made by millions of others in the U.S. economy to deter-
the expected marginal benefit from the change exceeds mine economy-wide measures such as total production,
the expected marginal cost. For example, Amazon.com employment, and economic growth. ­Macroeconomics
compares the marginal benefit expected from adding a studies the performance of the economy as a whole.
new line of products (the additional sales revenue) with Whereas microeconomics studies the individual pieces of
the marginal cost (the additional cost of the resources the economic puzzle, as reflected in particular markets,
required). Likewise, you compare the marginal benefit macroeconomics puts all the pieces together to focus on
you expect from eating dessert (the additional pleasure or the big picture. Macroeconomics sees the forest, not the
satisfaction) with its marginal cost (the additional money, trees; the beach, not the grains of sand; and the Rose
time, and calories). Bowl parade float, not the individual flowers that shape
Typically, the change under consideration is small, and color that float.
but a marginal choice can involve a major economic The national economy usually grows over time,
adjustment, as in the decision to quit school and find a but along the way it sometimes stumbles, experiencing
job. For a firm, a marginal choice might mean building a recessions in economic activity, as reflected by a decline
plant in Mexico or even filing for bankruptcy. By focus- in production, employment, and other aggregate mea-
ing on the effect of a marginal adjustment to the status sures. Economic fluctuations are the rise and fall of
quo, the economist is able to cut the analysis of economic economic activity relative to the long-term growth trend
choice down to a manageable size. Rather than confront of the economy. These fluctuations, or business cycles,
a bewildering economic reality head-on, the economist vary in length and intensity, but they usually involve the
begins with a marginal choice to see how this choice entire nation and often other nations too. For exam-
affects a particular market and shapes the economic sys- ple, the U.S. economy now
tem as a whole. Incidentally, to the noneconomist, mar- produces more than four marginal Incremental,
ginal usually means relatively inferior, as in “a movie of times as much as it did in ­additional, or extra; used
marginal quality.” Forget that meaning for this course and 1960, despite experiencing to describe a change in an
instead think of marginal as meaning incremental, addi- eight recessions since then, ­ economic variable

tional, or extra. including the Great Reces- microeconomics The


sion of 2007–2009. study of the economic behavior
1-2dMicroeconomics in particular markets, such as
that for computers or unskilled
TO REVIEW: The art of eco-
and Macroeconomics nomic analysis focuses on
labor

macroeconomics The
Although you have made thousands of economic how people use their scarce
study of the economic ­behavior
choices, you probably seldom think about your own resources in an attempt to of entire economies, as
economic behavior. For example, why are you reading satisfy their unlimited wants. ­measured, for example, by total
this book right now rather than doing something else? Rational self-interest guides ­production and employment
­Microeconomics is the study of your economic behavior individual choice. Choice economic fluctuations
and the economic behavior of others who make choices requires time and informa- The rise and fall of economic
about such matters as how much to study and how much tion and involves a compari- activity relative to the long-term
growth trend of the economy;
to party, how much to borrow and how much to save, son of the expected marginal
also called business cycles
what to buy and what to sell. Microeconomics examines benefit and the expected
individual economic choices and how markets coordinate marginal cost of alternative

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 9


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
actions. Microeconomics looks at the individual pieces
of the economic puzzle; macroeconomics fits the pieces
together to form the big picture.

1-3 THE SCIENCE OF ECONOMIC


ANALYSIS
Economists use scientific analysis to develop theories,
or models, that help explain economic behavior. An
­economic theory, or economic model, is a simplifi-
cation of economic reality that is used to make predic-
tions about cause and effect in the real world. A theory,
or model, such as the circular-flow model, captures the
important elements of the problem under study but need
not spell out every detail and interrelation. In fact, add-
ing more details may make a theory more unwieldy and,
therefore, less useful. For example, a wristwatch is a model
that tells time, but a watch festooned with extra features
is harder to read at a glance and is therefore less useful
as a time-telling model. The world is so complex that we
must simplify it to make sense of things. Store mannequins
© iStock.com/Pinopic

simplify the human form (some even lack arms and heads).
Comic strips and cartoons simplify a character’s anatomy—
leaving out fingers (in the case of Adventure Time, The
Simpsons, and Family Guy) or a mouth (in the case of Dil-
bert), for instance. You might think of ­economic theory as a A good theory can act like a closet organizer for
stripped-down, or streamlined, version of ­economic reality. your mind, helping you understand a messy and
A good theory helps us understand a messy and confusing world.
­confusing world. Lacking a theory of how things work,
our thinking can become cluttered with facts, one piled
on another, as in a messy closet. You could think of a good
theory as a closet organizer for the mind. A good theory understood. Someone who pounds on the Pepsi machine
offers a helpful guide to sorting, saving, and understand- that just ate a quarter has a crude theory about how that
ing information. machine works. One version of that theory might be, “The
quarter drops through a series of whatchamacallits, but
1-3a The Role of Theory sometimes it gets stuck. If I pound on the machine, then I
can free up the quarter and send it on its way.” Evidently,
Most people don’t understand the role of theory. Perhaps this theory is widespread enough that people continue to
you have heard, “Oh, that’s fine in theory, but in practice pound on machines that fail to perform (a real problem
it’s another matter.” The implication is that the theory in for the vending machine industry and one reason newer
question provides little aid in practical matters. People who machines are fronted with glass). Yet, if you were to ask
say this fail to realize that they are merely substituting their these mad pounders to explain their “theory” about how the
own theory for a theory they machine works, they would look at you as if you were crazy.
economic theory, or either do not believe or do not
­economic model, A understand. They are really say-
simplification of reality used ing, “I have my own theory that
1-3b The Scientific Method
to make predictions about
works better.” To study economic problems, economists employ a pro-
cause and effect in the real
world All of us employ theories, cess called the scientific method, which consists of four
however poorly defined or steps, as outlined in Exhibit 1.2.

10 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
be, “What is the relationship between
Exhibit 1.2 the price of Pepsi and the quantity of
The Scientific Method: Step-by-Step Pepsi purchased?” In this case, the rel-
The steps of the scientific method are designed to develop and test evant variables are price and quantity. A
hypotheses about how the world works. The objective is a theory that variable is a measure that can take on
predicts outcomes more accurately than the best alternative theory.
A hypothesis is rejected if it does not predict as accurately as the best different values at different times. The
alternative. A rejected hypothesis can be modified or reworked in light variables of concern become the ele-
of the test results. ments of the theory, so they must be
selected with care.

1. Identify the question and define relevant variables


Step Two: Specify
Assumptions
The second step is to specify the
2. Specify assumptions
assumptions under which the theory
is to apply. One major category of
assumptions is the other-things-
3. Formulate a hypothesis constant assumption—in Latin, the
ceteris paribus assumption. The idea is
Modify
to identify the variables of interest and
approach
4. Test the hypothesis
then focus exclusively on the relation-
ships among them, assuming that noth-
or ing else important changes—that other
Reject the hypothesis
Use the hypothesis until things remain constant. Again, suppose
a better one shows up
we are interested in how the price
of Pepsi influences the amount pur-
chased. To isolate the relation between
these two variables, we assume that
there are no changes in other relevant variables such
as consumer income, the average daytime tempera-
Step One: Identify the Question ture, or the price of Coke.
and Define Relevant Variables We also make assumptions about how people
The scientific method begins with curiosity: Someone behave; these are called b ­ ehavioral assumptions. The
wants to answer a question. Thus, the first step is to primary behavioral assumption is rational self-interest.
identify the economic question and define the variables Earlier we assumed that each decision maker pursues
relevant to a solution. For example, the question might self-interest rationally and
makes choices accordingly. variable A measure, such a
Rationality implies that each better one shows up as price or
consumer buys the products quantity, that can take on differ-
ent values at different times
expected to maximize his
or her level of satisfaction. other-things-constant
Rationality also implies that assumption The assump-
tion, when focusing on the
Radu Bercan/Shutterstock.com

each firm supplies the prod- relation among key economic


ucts expected to maximize variables, that other variables
the firm’s profit. These kinds remain unchanged; in Latin,
of assumptions are called ceteris paribus
behavioral assumptions behavioral assumptions
because they specify how we An assumption that describes
expect economic decision the expected behavior of
If the price of your favorite soft drink rose, would ­economic decision makers—
you buy less of it?
makers to behave—what what motivates them
makes them tick, so to speak.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 11


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Step Three: Formulate a Hypothesis but they must be subject to verification or refutation by
reference to the facts. Theories are expressed as positive
The third step in the scientific method is to formulate
statements such as “If the price of Pepsi increases, then
a hypothesis, which is a theory about how key vari-
the quantity demanded decreases.”
ables relate to each other. For example, one hypothesis
Most of the disagreement among economists
holds that if the price of Pepsi goes up, other things
involves normative debates—such as the appropriate
constant, then the quantity purchased declines. The
role of ­government—rather than statements of posi-
hypothesis becomes a prediction of what happens to
tive analysis. To be sure, many theoretical issues remain
the quantity purchased if the price increases. The pur-
unresolved, but economists generally agree on most fun-
pose of this hypothesis, like that of any theory, is to
damental theoretical principles—that is, about positive
help make predictions about cause and effect in the
economic analysis. For example while all economists
real world.
agree on the positive idea that people buy less as prices
Step Four: Test the Hypothesis rise, they may not agree on normative questions such
as, “is the distribution of income in the United States
In the fourth step, by comparing its predictions with
too unequal?”
evidence, we test the validity of a hypothesis. To test a
Normative statements, or value judgments, have a
hypothesis, we must focus on the variables in question,
place in a policy debate such as the proper role of gov-
while carefully controlling for other effects assumed
ernment, provided that statements of opinion are distin-
not to change. The test leads us to either (1) reject the
guished from statements of fact. In such policy debates,
hypothesis, or theory, if it predicts worse than the best
you are entitled to your own opinion, but you are not
alternative theory or (2) use the hypothesis, or theory,
entitled to your own facts.
until a better one comes along. If we reject the hypothe-
sis, we can try to go back and modify our approach in light
of the results. Please spend a moment now reviewing the 1-3d Economists Tell Stories
steps of the scientific method in Exhibit 1.2. Despite economists’ reliance on the scientific method
for developing and evaluating theories, economic analy-
1-3cNormative Versus sis is as much art as science. Formulating a question,
isolating the key variables, specifying the assumptions,
Positive proposing a theory to answer the question, and devis-
Economists usually try to explain how the economy ing a way to test the predictions all involve more than
works. Sometimes they concern themselves not with how simply an understanding of economics and the scientific
the economy does work but how it should work. Com- method. Carrying out these steps requires good intuition
pare these two statements: “The U.S. unemployment and the imagination of a storyteller. Economists explain
rate is 5.6 percent,” and “The U.S. unemployment rate their theories by telling stories about how they think the
should be lower.” The first, called a positive ­economic economy works. To tell a compelling story, an economist
­statement, is an assertion about economic reality that can relies on case studies, anecdotes, parables, the personal
be supported or rejected by reference to the facts. Posi- experience of the listener, and supporting data. Through-
tive economics, like physics or out this book, you’ll hear stories that bring you closer to
hypothesis A theory biology, attempts to understand the ideas under consideration. These stories, such as the
about how key variables one about the Pepsi machine, breathe life into economic
relate
the world around us as it is. The
second, called a n ­ ormative theory and help you personalize abstract ideas.
positive economic economic ­statement, reflects
statement A ­statement
that can be proved or an opinion. Moreover, an opin- Predicting Average
1-3e
ion is merely that—it cannot
­disproved by reference to
facts be shown to be true or false by
Behavior
normative economic reference to the facts. Positive The goal of economic theory is to predict the impact of
statement A statement statements concern what is; economic events on economic choices and, in turn, the
that reflects an opinion, normative statements concern effect of these choices on particular markets or on the
which cannot be proved or
what, in someone’s opinion, economy as a whole. Does this mean that economists try
disproved by reference to
the facts should be. Positive statements to predict the behavior of particular consumers or pro-
need not necessarily be true, ducers? Not necessarily, because a specific individual

12 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
may behave in an unpredictable way. But the unpredict- Can we conclude that physicians cause cancer? No. To
able actions of numerous individuals tend to cancel one assume that event A caused event B simply because the
another out, so the average behavior of groups can be pre- two are associated in time is to commit the association-
dicted more accurately. For example, if the federal gov- is-­causation fallacy, a common error. The fact that
ernment cuts personal income taxes, certain households one event precedes another or that the two events occur
might save the entire tax cut. On average, however, house- simultaneously does not necessarily mean that one causes
hold spending would increase. Likewise, if Burger King the other. Remember: Association is not necessarily
cuts the price of Whoppers, the manager can better pre- causation.
dict how much sales will increase than how a specific cus-
tomer coming through the door will respond. The random The Fallacy of Composition
actions of individuals tend to offset one another, so the
Perhaps you have been to a rock concert where every-
average behavior of a large group can be predicted more
one stands to get a better view. At some concerts, most
accurately than the behavior of a particular individual.
people even stand on their chairs. But even stand-
Consequently, economists tend to focus on the average,
ing on chairs does not improve your view if others do
or typical, behavior of people in groups—for example,
the same, unless you are quite tall. Likewise, arriving
as average taxpayers or average Whopper consumers—
early to buy concert tickets does not work if many
rather than on the behavior of a specific individual.
have the same idea. Earning a college degree to get
a better job does not work as well if everyone earns a

1-4 SOME PITFALLS OF FAULTY college degree. These are examples of the fallacy of
­composition, which is an erroneous belief that what is
­ECONOMIC ANALYSIS true for the individual, or the part, is also true for the
group, or the whole.
Economic analysis, like other forms of scientific inquiry, is
subject to common mistakes in reasoning that can lead to The Mistake of Ignoring
faulty conclusions. Here are three sources of confusion. the ­Secondary Effects
In many cities, public officials have imposed rent con-
The Fallacy That A
­ ssociation trols on apartments. The primary effect of this policy,
Is Causation the effect that policy makers focus on, is to keep rents
In the past two decades, the number of physicians spe- from rising. Over time, however, fewer new apart-
cializing in cancer treatment increased sharply. At the ments get built because renting them becomes less
same time, the incidence of some cancers increased. profitable. Moreover, existing rental units deteriorate
because owners have plenty of customers anyway.
Thus, the quantity and quality of housing may decline
as a result of what appears to be a reasonable mea-
sure to keep rents from
rising. The mistake was association-is-­causation
to ignore the secondary fallacy The incorrect idea
effects, or the unintended that if two ­variables are associ-
ated in time, one must necessar-
consequences, of the
ily cause the other
policy. Economic actions
have secondary effects that fallacy of ­composition
Anna Omelchenko/Fotolia LLC

The incorrect belief that


often turn out to be more what is true for the individual,
important than the primary or part, must necessarily
effects. Secondary effects be true for the group, or
may develop more slowly the whole
and may not be immedi- secondary effects ­
ately obvious, but good Unintended consequences of
Standing at a concert can help you see better . . . economic actions that may
economic analysis tries to
unless everyone else stands up too! This is an develop slowly over time as
example of the fallacy of composition.
anticipate them and take people react to events
them into account.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 13


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
1-5 IF ECONOMIST ARE SO SMART,
WHY AREN’T THEY RICH?
Why aren’t economists rich? Well, some are, earning over
$25,000 per appearance on the lecture circuit. Others top

Robert Nickelsberg/Alamy Stock Photo


$2 million a year as consultants and expert witnesses.3
Economists have been appointed to federal cabinet
posts, as secretaries of commerce, defense, labor, state,
and treasury, for example, and to head the U.S. Federal
Reserve System. Economics is the only social science
and the only business discipline for which the prestigious
Nobel Prize is awarded, and pronouncements by econ-
omists are reported in the media daily. A 2015 journal
article argued that “the superiority of economists” gives As more people get college degrees, the advantage
them considerable influence over economic policy.4 And it gives you in the labor market gets smaller. (Don’t
The Economist, a widely respected news weekly from worry, it’s still worth it.)
London, has argued that economic ideas have influenced
policy “to a degree that would make other social scientists
drool.”5
The economics profession thrives because its models appearance, and, yes, luck. Even so, economics is one
usually do a better job of making economic sense out of of the higher paying majors (for those with just a bach-
a confusing world than do alternative approaches. But elor’s degree). A recent study by Georgetown University
not all economists are wealthy, nor is personal wealth the found that economics and business economics were the
goal of the discipline. In a similar vein, not all doctors only two non-STEM (science, technology, engineering,
are healthy (some even smoke), not all carpenters live math) majors among the top 25 earning majors (for work-
in perfectly built homes, not all marriage counselors are ers ages 25–29).6 Exhibit 1.3 shows median annual pay for
happily married, and not all child psychologists have well- a variety of college majors both with 0–5 years experience
adjusted children. Still, those who study economics do and with 10–20 years experience (for workers with only
reap financial rewards. a bachelor’s degree). As can be seen there, those with
Earlier in the chapter, you learned that economic degrees in economics see significant growth in earnings
choice involves comparing the expected marginal ben- as their careers progress.
efit and the expected marginal cost. Surveys show that A number of world leaders majored in economics,
students go to college because they believe a college including four of the last eight U.S. presidents; former
diploma is the ticket to better jobs and higher pay. Put Prime Minister Stephen Harper of Canada; billionaire and
another way, for nearly two-thirds of U.S. high school former president of Chile, Sebastian Pinera (who earned
graduates, the expected marginal benefit of college a Ph.D. in economics from Harvard); Turkey’s first female
apparently exceeds the expected marginal cost. The cost prime minister, Tansu Ciller (who earned a Ph.D. in eco-
of college will be discussed in the next chapter; the focus nomics from the University of Connecticut); Italy’s former
here is on the benefits of college, particularly expected prime minister, Mario Monti (who earned a Ph.D. in eco-
earnings. nomics from Yale); Greece’s former prime minister, Lucas
Among college graduates, all kinds of factors affect Papademos (who earned a Ph.D. in economics from MIT);
earnings, such as general ability, effort, occupation, col- U.S. Supreme Court justices Stephen Breyer and Anthony
lege attended, college major, highest degree earned, Kennedy; and former justice Sandra Day O’Connor.

3. As reported by George Anders, “An Economist’s Courtroom Bonanza,”


Wall Street Journal, 19 March 2007.
6. The Economic Value of College Majors, Anthony P. Carnevale, Ban Cheah,
4. Marion Fourcade, Etienne Ollion, and Yann Algan, "The Superiority of
and Andrew R. Hanson. Georgetown University Center on Education and the
Economists," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29 (Winter 2015): 89–114.
Workforce. McCourt School of Public Policy. 2015 https://cew.georgetown
5. “The Puzzling Failure of Economics,” The Economist, 23 August 1997, p. 11. .edu/cew-reports/valueofcollegemajors/

14 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Exhibit 1.3
Median Annual Pay by College Major (with Bachelor’s Degree Only)

Computer Engineering
Electrical Engineering
Mechanical Engineering
Computer Science
Civil Engineering Nursing
Economics
Finance
Mathematics
Accounting
Chemistry
Marketing & Management
Political Science
Agriculture
Biology
History
English
Sociology
Psychology 0–5 Years' Experience
Criminal Justice 10–20 Years' Experience
Elementary Education

0 20 40 60 80 100 120
Thousands of Dollars
Sources: Median pay data for 2015 were found at https://www.payscale.com/best-colleges/degrees.asp. For a survey of
­e mployment opportunities,go to the U.S. Labor Department’s Occupational Outlook Handbook at https://www.bls.gov/oco/.

Other notable economics majors include former Hewlett-­ whole story, and economic factors are not always the most
Packard president (and billionaire) Meg Whitman, former important. But economic considerations have important
head of Microsoft (and billionaire) Steve Ballmer, CNN and predictable effects on individual choices, and these
founder (and billionaire) Ted Turner, financial guru (and choices affect the way we live.
billionaire) Warren Buffett, Walmart founder (and bil- Yes, economics is a challenging discipline, but it is
lionaire) Sam Walton, and (non-billionaire) Scott Adams, also an exciting and rewarding one. The good news is
creator of Dilbert, the mouthless wonder. that you already know a lot about economics. To use this
knowledge, however, you must cultivate the art and sci-
ence of economic analysis. You must be able to simplify

1-6 FINAL WORD the world to formulate questions, isolate the relevant
variables, and then tell a persuasive story about how these
variables relate.
This textbook describes how economic factors affect indi- An economic relation can be expressed in words, rep-
vidual choices and how all these choices come together resented as a table of quantities, described by a mathemat-
to shape the economic system. Economics is not the ical equation, or illustrated as a graph. The appendix to this

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 15


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
chapter introduces graphs. You may find a detailed reading The next chapter introduces key tools of economic
of this appendix unnecessary. If you are already familiar analysis. Subsequent chapters use these tools to explore
with relations among variables, slopes, tangents, and the economic problems and to explain economic behavior
like, you can probably just browse. But if you have little that may otherwise seem puzzling. You must walk before
recent experience with graphs, you might benefit from a you can run; however, and in the next chapter, you will
more careful reading with pencil and paper in hand. take your first wobbly steps.

STUDY
TOOLS 1
READY TO STUDY? IN THE BOOK, YOU CAN:
◻ Work the problems at the end of the chapter.
◻ Rip out the chapter review card for a handy summary of the chapter and key terms.

ONLINE AT CENGAGEBRAIN.COM YOU CAN:


◻ Take notes while you read and study the chapter.
◻ Quiz yourself on key concepts.
◻ Prepare for tests with chapter flash cards as well as flash cards that you create.
◻ Watch videos to explore economics further.

16 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 1 PROBLEMS
Your instructor can access the answers to these problems online at https://cengagebrain.com.

1-1 Explain the economic problem of 1-4 Identify some pitfalls


scarce resources and unlimited wants of economic analysis
1. (Definition of Economics) What determines whether or 7. (Pitfalls of Economic Analysis) Review the discussion of
not a resource is scarce? Why is the concept of scarcity pitfalls in economic thinking in this chapter. Then identify
important to the definition of economics? the fallacy, or mistake in thinking, in each of the following
statements:
1-2 Describe the forces that a. Raising taxes always increases government revenues.
shape economic choices b. Whenever there is a recession, imports decrease.
2. (Rational Self-Interest) Discuss the impact of rational self- Therefore, to stop a recession, we should increase
interest on each of the following decisions: imports.
a. Whether to attend college full time or enter the work- c. Raising the tariff on imported steel helps the U.S. steel
force full time industry. Therefore, the entire economy is helped.
b. Whether to buy a new textbook or a used one d. Gold sells for about $1,200 per ounce. Therefore, the
c. Whether to attend a local college or an out-of-town U.S. government could sell all the gold in Fort Knox at
college $1,200 per ounce to reduce the national debt.
3. (Rational Self-Interest) If behavior is governed by rational 8. (Association Versus Causation) Suppose I observe that
self-interest, why do people make charitable contribu- communities with lots of doctors tend to have relatively
tions of time and money? high rates of illness. I conclude that doctors cause illness.
4. (Marginal Analysis) The owner of a small pizzeria is decid- What’s wrong with this reasoning?
ing whether to increase the radius of delivery area by one
mile. What considerations must be taken into account if
1-5 Describe several ­reasons
such a decision is to increase profitability? to study economics
5. (Time and Information) It is often costly to obtain the 9. (Studying Economics) According to the text, economics
information necessary to make good decisions. yet your majors on average make more money than most other
own interests can be best served by rationally weigh- majors and have more job opportunities. Are these the
ing all options available to you. This requires informed primary motivations one might have for studying econom-
decision making. does this mean that making uninformed ics? What are your motivations for studying economics?
decisions is irrational? How do you determine how much
information is the right amount?
1-3 Explain the relationship between
economic theory and economic reality
6. (Role of Theory) What good is economic theory if it can’t
predict the behavior of a specific individual?

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 17


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
APPENDIX

A1-1 UNDERSTANDING GRAPHS Exhibit A-1


Basics of a Graph
Take out a pencil and a blank piece of paper. Go ahead. Any point on a graph represents a combination of values of
Put a point in the middle of the paper. This is your point two variables. Here, point a represents the combination of
5 units of variable x (measured on the horizontal axis) and
of departure, called the origin. With your pencil at the
15 units of variable y (measured on the vertical axis). Point b
origin, draw a straight line off to the right. This line is represents 10 units of x and 5 units of y.
called the horizontal axis. The value of the variable x
measured along the horizontal axis increases as you move y
to the right of the origin. Now mark off this line from 0
to 20, in increments of 5 units each. Returning to the 20
origin, draw another line, this one straight north. This
line is called the vertical axis. The value of the variable

Vertical axis
15 a
y measured along the vertical axis increases as you move
north of the origin. Mark off this line from 0 to 20, in
increments of 5 units each. 10
Within the space framed by the two axes, you can
plot possible combinations of the variables measured 5 b
along each axis. Each point identifies a value measured
along the horizontal, or x, axis and a value measured along
0
the vertical, or y, axis. For example, place point a in your
Origin 5 10 15 20 x
graph to reflect the combination where x equals 5 units
Horizontal axis
and y equals 15 units. Likewise, place point b in your
graph to reflect 10 units of x and 5 units of y. Now com-
pare your results with points shown in Exhibit A-1.
A graph is a picture showing how variables relate,
and a picture can be worth a thousand words. Take a look the year, the price of a product
origin on a graph
at Exhibit A-2, which shows the U.S. annual unemploy- and the quantity demanded, or ­depicting two-dimensional
ment rate since 1900. The year is measured along the the price of production and the space, the zero point
horizontal axis and the unemployment rate is measured quantity supplied. Because we
horizontal axis line on
as a percentage along the vertical axis. Exhibit A-2 is a focus on just two variables at a graph that begins at the
time-series graph, which shows the value of a variable, in a time, we usually assume that origin and goes to the right
this case the percent of the labor force unemployed, over other relevant variables remain and left; sometimes called
time. If you had to describe the information presented in constant. the x axis
Exhibit A-2, the explanation could take many words. The One variable often depends vertical axis line on
picture shows not only how one year compares to the next on another. The time it takes a graph that begins at the
origin and goes up and
but also how one decade compares to another and how you to drive home depends on
down; sometimes called
the unemployment rate trends over time. The sharply your average speed. Your weight the y axis
higher unemployment rate during the Great Depression depends on how much you eat.
graph a picture showing
of the 1930s is unmistakable. Graphs convey information The amount of Pepsi you buy how variables relate in two-
in a compact and efficient way. depends on the price. A func- dimensional space; one vari-
This appendix shows how graphs express a variety tional relation exists between able is measured along the
of possible relations among variables. Most graphs of two variables when the value horizontal axis and the other
along the vertical axis
interest in this book reflect the relationship between two of one variable depends on the
economic variables, such as the unemployment rate and value of another variable.

18 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Exhibit A-2
U.S. Unemployment Rate Since 1900
A time-series graph depicts the behavior of some economic variable over time. Shown here are U.S. unemployment rates since 1900.
Unemployment rate (percent)

25

20

15

10

1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
Year

Source: Historical Statistics of the United States, 1970; and Economic Report of the President, January 2017.

The value of the dependent variable depends on


the value of the independent variable. The task of Exhibit A-3
the economist is to isolate economic relations and deter- Schedule Relating Distance Traveled to Hours
mine the direction of causality, if any. Recall that one of Driven
the pitfalls of economic thinking is the erroneous belief
that association is causation. We cannot conclude that, Hours Driven per Day Distance Traveled per Day (miles)
simply because two events relate in time, one causes the a 1 50
other. There may be no relation between the two events. b 2 100
c 3 150
A1-1a Drawing Graphs d 4 200
e 5 250
Let’s begin with a simple relation. Suppose you are plan-
ning to drive across the country and want to figure out how
far you will travel each day. You plan to average 50 miles
per hour. Possible combinations of driving time and dis-
tance traveled per day appear in Exhibit A-3. One column independent variable. Combinations of hours driven and
lists the hours driven per distance traveled are shown as a, b, c, d, and e. Each com-
dependent ­variable day, and the next column bination is represented by a point in Exhibit A-4. For exam-
a variable whose value lists the number of miles ple, point a shows that if you drive for 1 hour, you travel
depends on that of the traveled per day, assum- 50 miles. Point b indicates that if you drive for 2 hours,
­independent variable
ing an average speed of 50 you travel 100 miles. By connecting the points, or possible
independent miles per hour. The distance combinations, we create a line running upward and to the
­variable a variable traveled, the dependent vari- right. This makes sense because, the longer you drive, the
whose value determines that
of the dependent variable able, depends on the num- farther you travel. Assumed constant along this line is your
ber of hours driven, the average speed of 50 miles per hour.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 19


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Each of the four panels in Exhibit A-5 indicates a
Exhibit A-4 vertical change, given a 10-unit increase in the horizontal
Graph Relating Distance Traveled to Hours Driven variable. In panel (a), the vertical distance increases by
Points a through e depict different combinations of hours 5 units when the horizontal distance increases by 10 units.
driven per day and the corresponding distances traveled. The slope of the line is therefore 5/10, or 0.5. Notice that
Connecting these points creates a graph.
the slope in this case is a positive number because the
relation between the two variables is positive, or direct.
Distance traveled per day (miles)

This slope indicates that for every 1-unit increase in the


250 horizontal variable, the vertical variable increases by
e
0.5 units. The slope, incidentally, does not imply causal-
200 d ity; the increase in the horizontal variable does not nec-
essarily cause the increase in the vertical variable. The
150 c slope simply measures the relation between an increase
in the horizontal variable and the associated change in
100 b the vertical variable.
In panel (b) of Exhibit A-5, the vertical distance
50 a
declines by 7 units when the horizontal distance increases
by 10 units, so the slope equals –7/10, or –0.7. The slope
in this case is a negative number because the two vari-
0 1 2 3 4 5
Hours driven per day ables have a negative, or inverse, relation. In panel (c),
the vertical variable remains unchanged as the horizontal
variable increases by 10, so the slope equals 0/10, or 0.
Types of relations between variables include the These two variables are not related. Finally, in panel (d),
following: the vertical variable can take on any value, although the
horizontal variable remains unchanged. Again, the two
1. As one variable increases, the other increases—as variables are not related. In this case, any change in the
in Exhibit A-4; this is called a positive, or direct, vertical measure, for example, a 10-unit change, is divided
relation between the variables. by 0, because the horizontal value does not change. Any
2. As one variable increases, the other decreases; this change divided by 0 is mathematically undefined, but as
is called a negative, or inverse, relation. the line tilts toward vertical, its slope gets incredibly large.
3. As one variable increases, the other remains For practical purposes, we will assume that the slope of
unchanged; the two variables are said to be inde- this line is not undefined but infinitely large.
pendent, or unrelated.
A1-1cThe Slope, Units
One of the advantages of graphs is that they easily convey
the relation between variables. We do not need to exam-
of Measurement,
ine the particular combinations of numbers; we need only and ­Marginal positive relation (direct
relation) occurs when two
focus on the shape of the curve. Analysis variables increase or decrease
together; the two variables
A1-1b The Slope of a Straight The mathematical value of the move in the same direction
slope depends on the units
Line measured on the graph. For negative ­relation
example, suppose copper tubing inverse (relation) occurs
A more precise way to describe the shape of a curve is when two variables move in
to measure its slope. The slope of a line indicates how costs $1 a foot. Graphs depict- opposite directions; when one
much the vertical variable changes for a given increase ing the relation between total increases, the other decreases
in the horizontal variable. Specifically, the slope between cost and quantity purchased are slope of a line a ­measure
any two points along any straight line is the vertical shown in Exhibit A-6. In panel of how much the vertical
change between these two points divided by the hori- (a), the total cost increases by $1 variable changes for a given
zontal increase, or for each 1-foot increase in the increase in the horizontal
variable; the vertical change
amount of tubing purchased.
between two points divided
Change in the vertical distance Thus, the slope equals 1/1, or 1.
Slope 5 by the horizontal increase
Increase in the horizontal distance If the cost per foot remains the
20 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Exhibit A-5
Alternative Slopes for Straight Lines
The slope of a line indicates how much the vertically measured variable changes for a given increase in the variable measured
along the horizontal axis. Panel (a) shows a positive relation between two variables; the slope is 0.5, a positive number. Panel
(b) depicts a negative, or inverse, relation. When the x variable increases, the y variable decreases; the slope is 20.7, a nega-
tive number. Panels (c) and (d) represent situations in which two variables are unrelated. In panel (c), the y variable always
takes on the same value; the slope is 0. In panel (d), the x variable always takes on the same value; the slope is mathematically
­undefined but we simplify by assuming the slope is infinite.

(a) Positive relation (b) Negative relation


y y

20 5 20 7
Slope = 10 = 0.5 Slope = – = –0.7
10
15
5
10 10
10
–7
3
10

0 10 20 x 0 10 20 x

(c) No relation: zero slope (d) No relation: assumed infinite slope


y y

10
20 20 Slope = 0 = `
0
Slope = 10 = 0 10

10 10
10

0 10 20 x 0 10 x

same but units are measured not in feet but in yards, output, measured along the horizontal axis. For example,
the relation between total cost and quantity purchased is in panel (a) of Exhibit A-6, the marginal cost of another
as depicted in panel (b). Now total cost increases by $3 foot of copper tubing is $1, which also equals the slope
for each 1-yard increase in output, so the slope equals of the line. In panel (b), the marginal cost of another
3/1, or 3. Because different units are used to measure yard of tubing is $3, which again is the slope of that line.
the copper tubing, the two panels reflect different slopes, Because of its applicability to marginal analysis, the slope
even though the cost is $1 per foot in each panel. Keep has special relevance in economics.
in mind that the slope depends in part on the units of
measurement. A1-1d The Slopes of Curved
Economic analysis usually involves marginal analy-
sis, such as the marginal cost of one more unit of output.
Lines
The slope is a convenient device for measuring marginal The slope of a straight line is the same everywhere along
effects because it reflects the change in total cost, mea- the line, but the slope of a curved line differs along the
sured along the vertical axis, for each 1-unit change in curve, as shown in Exhibit A-7. To find the slope of a
CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 21
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Exhibit A-6
Slope Depends on the Unit of Measure
The value of the slope depends on the units of measure. In panel (a), output is measured in feet of copper
­tubing; in panel (b), output is measured in yards. Although the cost is $1 per foot in each panel, the slope is
­different in the two panels because copper tubing is measured using different units.

(a) Measured in feet (b) Measured in yards


Total Total
cost cost

$6 $6
1
5
3
1
1 3
Slope = = 1 3 Slope = =3
1 1
1

0 5 6 0 1 2
Feet of copper tubing Yards of copper tubing

increases from 0 to 10, the vertical value drops along A


Exhibit A-7 from 40 to 0. Thus, the vertical change divided by the
Slopes at Different Points on a Curved Line horizontal change equals –40/10, or –4, which is the slope
The slope of a curved line varies from point to point. At of the curve at point a. This slope is negative because
a given point, such as a or b, the slope of the curve is the vertical value decreases as the horizontal value
equal to the slope of the straight line that is tangent to
increases. Line B, a line tangent to the curve at point b,
the curve at the point.
has the slope –10/30, or –0.33. As you can see, the curve
y depicted in Exhibit A-7 gets flatter as the horizontal vari-
able increases, so the value of its slope approaches zero.
40 A Other curves, of course, will reflect different slopes
as well as different changes in the slope along the curve.
Downward-sloping curves have negative slopes, and
30
upward-sloping curves, positive slopes. Sometimes
curves, such as those in Exhibit A-8, are more complex,
20 a
having both positive and negative ranges, depending on
the horizontal value. In the hill-shaped curve, for small
10 B
values of x, there is a positive relation between x and y, so
b
the slope is positive. As the value of x increases, however,
0 the slope declines and eventually becomes negative. We
10 20 30 40 x can divide the curve into two segments: (1) the segment
between the origin and point a, where the slope is posi-
tive; and (2) the segment of the curve to the right of
point a, where the slope is negative. The slope of the
curve at point a is 0. The U-shaped curve in Exhibit A-8
curved line at a particular point, draw a straight line that represents the opposite
just touches the curve at that point but does not cut or relation: x and y are nega- tangent a straight line that
cross the curve. Such a line is called a tangent to the tively related until point b is touches a curve at a point but
reached; thereafter, they are does not cut or cross the curve;
curve at that point. The slope of the tangent gives the
used to measure the slope of a
slope of the curve at that point. Look at line A, which is positively related. The slope curve at a point
tangent to the curve at point a. As the horizontal value equals 0 at point b.
22 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Exhibit A-8 Exhibit A-9
Curves with Both Positive and Negative Slopes Shift of Line Relating Distance Traveled
Some curves have both positive and negative slopes. The to Hours Driven
hill-shaped curve (in red) has a positive slope to the left of Line T appeared originally in Exhibit A-5 to show the rela-
point a, a slope of 0 at point a, and a negative slope to the tion between hours driven and distance traveled per day,
right of that point. The U-shaped curve (in blue) starts off assuming an average speed of 50 miles per hour. If the
with a negative slope, has a slope of 0 at point b, and has a speed averages only 40 miles per hour, the entire relation
positive slope to the right of that point. shifts to the right to T9, indicating that any given distance
traveled requires more driving time. For example, 200 miles
y traveled takes 4 hours at 50 miles per hour but 5 hours at
40 miles per hour. This figure shows how a change in
assumptions, in this case, the average speed, can shift the
a entire relationship between two variables.

Distance traveled per day (miles)


250 T’
b
d
200 f

0 x 150

100

A1-1e Line Shifts 50

Let’s go back to the example of your cross-country trip,


where we were trying to determine how many miles you
0 1 2 3 4 5
would travel per day. Recall that we measured hours driven
Hours driven per day
per day on the horizontal axis and miles traveled per day on
the vertical axis, assuming an average speed of 50 miles per
hour. That same relation is shown as line T in Exhibit A-8.
What happens if the average speed is 40 miles per hour?
The entire relation between hours driven and distance trav- 40 miles per hour (as shown by point f on curve T9). Thus,
eled would change, as shown by the shift to the right of line a change in the assumption about average speed changes
T to T9. With a slower average speed, any distance traveled the relationship between the two variables observed. This
per day now requires more driving time. For example, 200 changed relationship is expressed by a shift of the line that
miles traveled requires 4 hours of driving when the average shows how the two variables relate.
speed is 50 miles per hour (as shown by point d on curve That ends our once-over of graphs. Return to this
T), but 200 miles takes 5 hours when your speed averages appendix when you need a review.

CHAPTER 1: The Art and Science of Economic Analysis 23


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
2 Economic Tools and
­Economic Systems
Gary Bryan/Stone1/Getty Images

LEARNING OUTCOMES After finishing this chapter


After studying this chapter, you will be able to…
go to PAGE 37 for STUDY TOOLS
2-1 Describe the relationship between choice and opportunity cost Topics discussed in Chapter 2 include
• Opportunity cost
2-2 Explain how comparative advantage, specialization, and exchange affect economic outcomes
(output) • Comparative advantage
• Specialization
2-3 Outline how economies function as production systems • Division of labor
• Production possibilities frontier
2-4 Describe different economic systems and the decision-making rules that define them
• Economic systems
• Three economic questions
• Capitalism, command systems, and in between

24 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
▸▸ Why are you reading this book right now rather ▸▸ Why is there no point crying over spilled milk?
Q uthan
e sdoing
t i osomething
ns else? ▸▸ Why does common ownership often lead to
▸▸ What is college costing you? ­common neglect?
▸▸ Why will you eventually major in one subject rather ▸▸ These and other questions are addressed in this
than continue to take courses in various subjects? chapter, which introduces some tools of economic
▸▸ Why is fast food so fast? analysis—some tools of the trade.

C
hapter 1 introduced the idea that scarcity that different economies must answer—questions
forces us to make choices, but the chap- about what goods and services to produce, how to
ter said little about how to make economic produce them, and for whom to produce them.
choices. This chapter develops a framework for
evaluating economic alternatives. First, we con-

“Why is there
sider the cost involved in selecting one alternative
over others. Next, we develop tools to explore the
no point crying over
choices available to individuals and to the econ-
omy as a whole. Finally, we examine the questions
spilled milk?

2-1 CHOICE AND OPPORTUNITY COST other possible alternative. You are reading this chapter
right now because you have nothing better to do. In fact,
you are attending college for the same reason: College
Think about a choice you just made: the decision to begin
appears more attractive than your best alternative.
reading this chapter right now rather than use your time to
study for another course, play sports, watch TV, play video
games, go online, get some sleep, hang with friends, or do 2-1b Opportunity Cost
something else. Suppose it’s late and your best alternative Is Subjective
to reading right now is getting some sleep. The cost of
reading is passing up the opportunity of sleep. Because of Like beauty, opportunity cost is in the eye of the beholder.
scarcity, whenever you make a choice, you must pass up It is subjective. Only the individual making the choice can
another opportunity; you must incur an opportunity cost. identify the most attractive alternative. But the chooser
seldom knows the actual value of what was passed up
because that alternative is “the road not taken.” If you
2-1a Opportunity Cost give up an evening of pizza and conversation with friends
What do we mean when we talk about the cost of some- to work on a research paper, you will never know exactly
thing? Isn’t it what we must give up—must forgo—to get what you gave up. You know only what you expected. Evi-
that thing? The opportunity cost of the chosen item or dently, you expected the benefit of working on that paper
activity is the value of the best alternative that is forgone. to exceed the benefit of the best alternative. (Incidentally,
You can think of opportunity cost as the opportunity lost. focusing on the best alternative forgone makes all other
Sometimes opportunity cost can be measured in terms of alternatives irrelevant.)
money, although, as we shall see, money is usually only
part of opportunity cost.
Calculating Opportunity Cost
How many times have you heard people say they Requires Time and Information
did something because they “had nothing better to do”? Economists assume that
They actually mean they had nothing else going on. Yet, people rationally choose the opportunity cost The
value of the best alternative for-
according to the idea of opportunity cost, people always most valued alternative. This
gone when an item or activity
do what they do because they have nothing better to do. does not mean you exhaus- is chosen
The choice selected seems, at the time, preferable to any tively assess the value of all

CHAPTER 2: Economic Tools and Economic Systems 25


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
possibilities. You assess alternatives as long as the expected
marginal benefit of gathering more information about Goods or (Sunday) Services?
your options exceeds the expected marginal cost (even if Even religious practices are subject to opportunity cost. For
you are not aware of making such conscious calculations). example, about half the U.S. population attends religious services
In other words, you do the best you can for yourself. at least once a month. In some states, so-called blue laws prohibit
retail activity on Sunday. Some states have repealed these laws in
Because learning about alternatives is costly and time recent years, thus raising the opportunity cost of church attendance.
consuming, some choices are based on limited or even wrong Researchers have found that when a state repeals its blue laws, reli-
information. Indeed, some choices may turn out badly (you gious attendance declines, as do church donations. These results do
not seem to be linked to any decline in religiosity before the repeal.
went for a picnic but it rained; the movie that cost $10 stunk;
your new shoes pinched; your new exercise equipment gets
no exercise; the stock you bought tanked). Regret about lost
opportunities is captured in the common expression “coulda,
woulda, shoulda.” At the time you made the selection, how-
ever, you believed you were making the best use of all your
scarce resources, including the time required to gather and

Bob Daemmrich/Alamy Stock Photo


evaluate information about your choices.

Time: The Ultimate Constraint


The Sultan of Brunei is among the richest people on
Earth, worth billions based on huge oil revenues that
flow into his tiny country. He and his royal family (which
has ruled since 1405) live in a palace with 1,788 rooms,
Source: Jonathan Gruber and Daniel Hungerman, “The Church vs. the Mall:
including 257 bathrooms and a throne room the size of a What Happens When Religion Faces Increased Secular Competition?”
football field. The family owns hundreds of cars, includ- Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123 (May 2008): 831–862.

ing dozens of Rolls-Royces; he can drive any of these or


pilot one of his seven planes, including the 747 with gold-
plated furniture. Supported by such wealth, the Sultan
would appear to have overcome the economic problem alternatives—perhaps ahead of reorganizing your closet
of scarcity. Yet, though he can buy just about anything but behind doing your laundry.
he wants, he lacks the time to enjoy all his stuff. If he Opportunity cost is subjective, but in some cases,
pursues one activity, he cannot at the same time do some- money paid for goods and services is a reasonable approx-
thing else. Each activity involves an opportunity cost. imation. For example, the opportunity cost of the new
Consequently, the Sultan must choose from among the smartphone you bought is the benefit from spending that
competing uses of his scarcest resource, time. Although $300 on the best forgone alternative. The money mea-
your alternatives are less exotic, you too face a time con- sure may leave out some important elements, however,
straint, especially as the college term winds down. particularly the value of the time involved. For example,
watching the latest hit movie costs you not only the $10
Opportunity Cost Varies With
admission price but also the time needed to get there,
Circumstance watch the movie, and return home.
Opportunity cost depends on your alternatives. This is
why you are more likely to study on a Tuesday night than
on a Saturday night. The opportunity cost of studying
2-1c Sunk Cost and Choice
is lower on a Tuesday night, because your alternatives Suppose you have just finished grocery shopping and are
are less attractive than on a Saturday night when more is wheeling your cart toward the checkout counters. How do
going on. Suppose you go to a movie on Saturday night. you decide which line to join? Easy. You pick the one with
Your opportunity cost is the the shortest expected wait. Suppose that line has barely
sunk cost A cost that has value of your best alternative moved for 10 minutes, when you notice that a cashier has
already been incurred, can- forgone, which might be attend- opened a new one and invites you to check out. Do you
not be recovered, and thus
ing a college game. For some of switch to the open cashier, or do you think, “Since I’ve
is irrelevant for present and
future economic decisions you, studying on Saturday night already spent 10 minutes in this line, I’m staying put”?
may rank well down the list of The 10 minutes you waited represents a sunk cost,

26 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
which is a cost that has already been incurred and can-
not be recovered, regardless of what you do next. You
should ignore sunk costs in making economic choices.
Hence, you should switch lines. Economic decision mak-

YAKOBCHUK VIACHESL AV/Shutterstock.com


ers should consider only those costs that are affected by
the choice. Sunk costs have already been incurred and are
not affected by the choice, so they are irrelevant. Like-
wise, you should walk out on a bad movie, even if you
spent $10 to get in. Your $10 is gone, and sitting through
that stinker only makes you worse off. The irrelevance
of sunk costs is underscored by proverbs such as “Don’t
throw good money after bad,” “Let bygones be bygones,”
“That’s water over the dam,” and “There’s no point crying
over spilled milk.” The milk has already spilled, so what- When deciding how to divide up tasks, compara-
ever you do now cannot change that. Or, as Shakespeare’s tive advantage is more important than absolute
advantage.
Lady Macbeth put it, “Things without all remedy should
be without regard: what’s done is done.” In other words,
forget about it.
Now that you have some idea about opportunity cost, 2-2aThe Law of
let’s see how it helps solve the economic problem. ­Comparative Advantage
Before long, you each realize that total output would
increase if you did all the typing and your roommate did all
2-2  COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, the ironing. In the hour available for these tasks, you type

­SPECIALIZATION, AND both papers and your roommate irons 12 shirts. As a result
of specialization, total output increases by nine shirts! You
EXCHANGE strike a deal to exchange your typing for your roommate’s
ironing, so you each end up with a typed paper and six
ironed shirts. Thus, each of you is better off as a result of
Suppose you live in a dormitory (and also either go to col-
specialization and exchange. By specializing in the task that
lege in the 1950s or are a very dedicated hipster). You and
you each do better, you rely on the law of comparative
your roommate have such tight schedules that you each
advantage, which states that the individual with the lower
can spare only about an hour a week for mundane tasks
opportunity cost of producing a particular output should
like ironing shirts and typing papers (granted, in reality
specialize in that output. You face a lower opportunity cost
you may not iron shirts or type papers, but this example
of typing than does your roommate, because in the time it
will help you understand some important principles).
takes to type a paper, you could iron 3 shirts whereas your
Each of you must turn in a typed three-page paper every
roommate could iron 12 shirts. Moreover, if you face a
week, and you each prefer ironed shirts when you have
lower opportunity cost of typing, your roommate must face
the time. Let’s say it takes you a half hour to type a hand-
a lower opportunity cost of ironing (try working that out).
written paper. Your roommate is from the hunt-and-peck
school and takes about an hour. But your roommate is a
talented ironer and can iron a shirt in 5 minutes flat (or 2-2bAbsolute ­Advantage
should that be, iron it flat in 5 minutes?). You take twice Versus ­Comparative
as long, or 10 minutes, to iron a shirt.
During the hour set aside each week for typing and
Advantage
ironing, typing takes priority. If you each do your own The gains from specializa-
typing and ironing, you type your paper in a half hour tion and exchange so far are law of comparative
and iron three shirts in the remaining half hour. Your ­obvious. A more interesting advantage The individual,
roommate spends the entire hour typing the paper, leav- case arises if you are faster firm, region, or country with the
lowest opportunity cost of pro-
ing no time for ironing. Thus, if you each do your own at both tasks. Suppose the
ducing a particular good should
tasks, the combined output is two typed papers and three example changes only in specialize in that good
ironed shirts. one respect: Your roommate

CHAPTER 2: Economic Tools and Economic Systems 27


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
takes 12 minutes to iron a shirt compared with your Comparative advantage is the better guide to who should
10 minutes. You now have an absolute advantage in both do what.
tasks, meaning each task takes you less time than it does The law of comparative advantage applies not only
your roommate. More generally, having an ­absolute to individuals but also to firms, regions of a country, and
advantage means making something using fewer entire nations. Individuals, firms, regions, or countries
resources than other producers require. with the lowest opportunity cost of producing a particular
Does your absolute advantage in both activities mean good should specialize in producing that good. Because of
specialization is no longer a good idea? Recall that the law such factors as climate, workforce skills, natural resources,
of comparative advantage states that the individual with and capital stock, certain parts of the country and certain
the lower opportunity cost of producing a particular good parts of the world have a comparative advantage in pro-
should specialize in that good. You still take 30 minutes to ducing particular goods. From Washington State apples
type a paper and 10 minutes to iron a shirt, so your oppor- to Florida oranges, from software in India to hardware in
tunity cost of typing the paper remains at three ironed Taiwan—resources are allocated most efficiently across
shirts. Your roommate takes an hour to type a paper and the country and around the world when production and
12 minutes to iron a shirt, so your roommate could iron trade conform to the law of comparative advantage.
five shirts in the time it takes to type a paper. Because
your opportunity cost of typing is lower than your room-
mate’s, you still have a comparative advantage in typing. 2-2cSpecialization
Consequently, your roommate must have a comparative
advantage in ironing (again, try working this out to your
and Exchange
satisfaction). Therefore, you should do all the typing and In the previous example, you and your roommate special-
your roommate, all the ironing. Although you have an ized and then exchanged output. No money was involved.
absolute advantage in both tasks, your comparative In other words, you engaged in barter, where products
advantage calls for specializing in the task for which are traded directly for other products. Barter works best
you have the lower opportunity cost—in this case, typing. in simple economies with little specialization and few
If neither of you specialized, you could type one traded goods. But for economies with greater specializa-
paper and iron three shirts. Your roommate could still tion, money facilitates exchange. Money—coins, bills,
type just the one paper. Your combined checks, and debit cards—is a medium
output would be two papers and three of exchange because it is the one thing
shirts. If you each specialized accord- that everyone accepts in return for
ing to comparative advantage, in an
“The degree of special- goods and services.
hour you could type both papers and ization is limited by the Because of specialization and
your roommate could iron five shirts. comparative advantage, most people
Thus, specialization increases total out-
extent of the market.” consume little of what they produce
put by two ironed shirts. Even though and produce little of what they con-
you are better at both tasks than your sume. Each individual specializes,
roommate, you are comparatively better at typing. Put then exchanges that product for money, which in turn is
another way, your roommate, although worse at both exchanged for other products. Did you make anything you
tasks, is not quite as bad at iron- are wearing? Probably not. Think about the degree of spe-
absolute advantage ing as at typing. cialization that went into your cotton shirt. A farmer in a
The ability to make some- Don’t think that this is just warm climate grew the cotton and sold it to someone who
thing using fewer resources common sense. Common sense spun it into thread, who sold it to someone who wove it into
than other producers use
would lead you to do your own fabric, who sold it to someone who sewed the shirt, who
comparative advan- ironing and typing because you sold it to a wholesaler, who sold it to a retailer, who sold it
tage The ability to make are better at both. Absolute to you. Many specialists in the chain of production created
something at a lower
­opportunity cost than other
advantage focuses on who uses that shirt. Exhibit 2.1 traces these steps. Specialization and
producers face the fewest resources, but com- exchange create more interdependence in an economy.
parative advantage focuses on Evidence of specialization is all around us. Shops
barter The direct
exchange of one product what else those resources could at the mall specialize in products ranging from luggage
for another without using produce—that is, on the oppor- to lingerie, and restaurants range from subs to sushi.
money tunity cost of those resources. Without moving a muscle, you can observe the division

28 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
one you could make yourself? Why is
Exhibit 2.1 fast food so fast? McDonald’s takes
Specialization in the Production of Cotton Shirts advantage of the gains resulting from
the division of labor. Each worker,
rather than preparing an entire meal,
specializes in separate tasks. This divi-
sion of labor allows the group to pro-
duce much more.
How is this increase in produc-
tivity possible? First, the manager
can assign tasks according to indi-
vidual preferences and abilities—that
is, according to the law of compara-
tive advantage. The worker with the
friendly smile and pleasant personality
can handle the customers up front; the
one with the strong back but few social
graces can handle the heavy lifting out
back. Second, a worker who performs
the same task again and again gets better at
of labor within a single industry by watching the cred- it (experience is a good teacher). The worker filling orders
its roll at the end of a movie. The credits list scores of at the drive-through, for example, learns to deal with spe-
­specialists—from gaffer (lighting electrician) to assistant cial problems that arise. As another example, consider the
location scout. The production of movies and TV shows experience gained by someone screening bags at airport
often requires hundreds of specialists. security. Experience helps the screener distinguish the
Some specialties may seem odd. For example, harmful from the harmless. Third, specialization means
professional mourners in Taiwan are hired by grieving no time is lost moving from one task to another. Finally,
families to scream, wail, and otherwise demonstrate the and perhaps most importantly, the specialization of
deep grief befitting a proper funeral. The sharp degree labor allows for the introduction of more sophisticated
of specialization is perhaps most obvious online, where production techniques—techniques that would not make
the pool of potential customers is so vast that individual sense on a smaller scale. For example, McDonald’s large
sites become finely focused. For example, you can find shake machine would be impractical in the home. Spe-
sites specializing in musical bowls, tongue studs, toe cialized machines make each worker more productive.
rings, brass knuckles, mouth harps, ferret toys, and cat To summarize: The specialization of labor (a) takes
bandanas—just to name a few of the hundreds of thou- advantage of individual preferences and natural abilities,
sands of specialty sites. You won’t find such precise spe- (b) allows workers to develop more experience at a par-
cialization at the mall. Adam Smith (1723–1790), who ticular task, (c) reduces the need to shift among different
is considered the father of economics, said the degree tasks, and (d) permits the introduction of labor-saving
of specialization is limited by the extent of the market. machinery. Specialization and the division of labor occur
Online sellers draw on the broadest customer base in the not only among individuals but also among firms, regions,
world to find a market niche. and, indeed, entire countries. The cotton shirt mentioned
earlier might involve growing cotton in one country, turn-
ing it into cloth in another, making the shirt in a third, and
2-2dDivision of Labor and selling it in a fourth.
We should also acknowl-
Gains from Specialization edge the downside of special- division of labor Break-
ing down the production of a
Picture a visit to McDonald’s: “Let’s see, I’ll have a Big ization. Doing the same thing good into separate tasks
Mac, an order of fries, and a chocolate shake.” In minutes all day can become tedious.
your order is ready. It would take you much longer to make Consider, for example, the specialization of labor
Focusing work effort on a par-
a homemade version of this meal. Why is the McDonald’s assembly line worker whose ticular product or a single task
meal faster, cheaper, and—for some people—tastier than sole task is to tighten a

CHAPTER 2: Economic Tools and Economic Systems 29


Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
kinds of ways to produce millions of different goods and
services. This section steps back from the immense com-
plexity of the real economy to develop another simple
model, which explores the economy’s production options.

2-3a Efficiency and the


­Production Possibilities
Frontier or PPF
© istockphoto.com/EllenMoran

To get an idea of how well the economy works, you


need some perspective; you need a place to stand. Let’s
develop a model to get some idea of how much an econ-
omy can produce with the resources available. What are
the economy’s production capabilities? Here are the
model’s assumptions:
Division of labor puts the “fast” in “fast food.” 1. To simplify matters, output is limited to just two
broad classes of products: consumer goods (which
are purchased by households for consumption) and
capital goods (which are used in the production of
particular bolt. Such a monotonous job could drive other goods). However, any two goods can be used
that worker bonkers or lead to repetitive motion injury. for this exercise. If you like, replace “consumer
Thus, the gains from dividing production into individual goods” with pizza and “capital goods” with robots.
tasks must be weighed against any problems caused by 2. The focus is on production during a given period—
assigning workers to repetitive, tedious, and potentially in this case, a year.
harmful jobs. Fortunately, today many routine tasks, par-
3. The economy’s resources are fixed in both quantity
ticularly on assembly lines, can be turned over to robots.
and quality during that period.
4. Society’s knowledge about how these resources
combine to produce output—that is, the available
2-3 THE ECONOMY’S PRODUCTION technology and know-how—does not change during
POSSIBILITIES the year.
5. Also assumed fixed during the period are the “rules
of the game” that facilitate production and ex-
The focus, up to this point, has been on how individuals
change. These include such things as the legal sys-
choose to use their scarce resources to satisfy their unlim-
tem, property rights, tax laws, patent laws, and the
ited wants or, more specifically,
manners, customs, and conventions of the market.
production possibili- how they specialize based on
ties frontier (PPF) A
comparative advantage. This The point of these simplifying assumptions is to freeze in
curve showing alternative
combinations of goods emphasis on the individual time the economy’s resources, technology and knowhow,
that can be produced when has been appropriate because and rules of the game so we can focus on the economy’s
available resources are used the economy is shaped by the production options. Otherwise, the production possibili-
efficiently; a boundary line
choices of individual decision ties of the economy would be a moving target.
between inefficient and
unattainable combinations makers, whether they are con- Given the resources, technology and know-how, and
sumers, producers, or public rules of the game available in the economy, the ­production
efficiency The condition officials. Just as resources are possibilities frontier, or PPF, identifies possible combina-
that exists when there is no
way resources can be real- scarce for the individual, they tions of the two types of goods that can be produced when
located to increase the pro- are also scarce for the economy available resources are employed efficiently. Resources are
duction of one good without as a whole (no fallacy of com- employed efficiently when there is no change that could
decreasing the production
position here). An economy has increase the production of one good without decreasing the
of another; getting the most
from available resources millions of different resources production of the other good. E ­ fficiency involves getting
that can be combined in all the most from available resources.
30 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
point along the PPF between C and E, such as
Exhibit 2.2 D, yields both more consumer goods and more
The Economy’s Production Possibilities Frontier capital goods than I. Hence, combination I is
If the economy uses its available resources and its technology and inefficient. By using resources more efficiently,
know-how efficiently to produce consumer goods and capital goods, the economy can produce more of at least one
that economy is on its production possibilities frontier, AF. The PPF
is bowed out to reflect the law of increasing opportunity cost; the good without reducing the production of the
economy must sacrifice more and more units of consumer goods to other good. Points outside the PPF, such as U in
produce each additional increment of capital goods. Note that more Exhibit 2.2, identify unattainable combinations,
consumer goods must be given up in moving from E to F than in mov-
ing from A to B, although in each case the gain in capital goods is 10
given the availability of resources, technology
million units. Points inside the PPF, such as I, represent inefficient use and know-how, and rules of the game. Thus, the
of resources. Points outside the PPF, such as U, represent unattainable PPF not only shows efficient combinations of pro-
combinations.
duction but also serves as the boundary between
inefficient combinations inside the frontier and
unattainable combinations outside the frontier.
Consumer goods (millions of units per year)

50
48
A
B 2-3c The Shape
43 C
U
of the PPF
40
Unattainable
Any movement along the PPF involves producing
34 D less of one good to produce more of the other.
30 Movements down along the curve indicate that
Inefficient
the opportunity cost of more capital goods is fewer
I
20 E consumer goods. For example, moving from point
A to point B increases capital production from
10 none to 10 million units but reduces consumer
units from 50 million to 48 million. Increasing cap-
F ital goods by 10 million reduces consumer goods
0
only a little. Capital production initially employs
10 20 30 40 50
resources (such as heavy machinery used to build
Capital goods (millions of units per year) factories) that produce few consumer goods but
are quite productive in making capital.
As shown by the dashed lines in Exhibit 2.2,
each additional 10 million units of capital produced
The economy’s PPF for consumer goods and capital reduce consumer goods by successively larger amounts.
goods is shown by the curve AF in Exhibit 2.2. Point A The resources used to produce more capital are increas-
identifies the amount produced per year if all the economy’s ingly better suited to producing consumer goods. The
resources are used efficiently to produce consumer goods. opportunity cost of making more capital goods increases,
Point F identifies the amount produced per year if all the because not all resources in the economy are perfectly
economy’s resources are used efficiently to produce capital adaptable to the production of both types of goods. The
goods. Points along the curve between A and F identify pos- shape of the production possibilities frontier reflects the
sible combinations of the two goods that can be produced law of increasing opportunity cost. If the economy
when all the economy’s resources are used efficiently. uses resources efficiently, the law of increasing opportu-
nity cost states that each additional increment of one good
2-3bInefficient and requires the economy to sacrifice successively larger and
larger increments of the other good.
­Unattainable Production The PPF derives its
Points inside the PPF, such as I in Exhibit 2.2, identify bowed-out shape from the law of increasing
combinations that do not employ resources efficiently. law of increasing opportunity opportunity cost To pro-
duce more of one good, a suc-
Note that C yields more consumer goods and no fewer cost. For example, whereas
cessively larger amount of the
capital goods than I. Moreover, E yields more capital the first 10 million units of other good must be sacrificed
goods and no fewer consumer goods than I. Indeed, any capital have an opportunity
CHAPTER 2: Economic Tools and Economic Systems 31
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
cost of only 2 million consumer units, the final 10 ­million
units of capital—that is, the increase from E to F—have
an opportunity cost of 20 million consumer units. Notice
that the slope of the PPF shows the opportunity cost of
an increment of capital. As the economy moves down the
curve, the curve becomes steeper, reflecting the higher
opportunity cost of capital goods in terms of forgone

Angela Harburn/Shutterstock.com
consumer goods. The law of increasing opportunity cost
also applies when moving from capital goods to consumer
goods. Incidentally, if resources were perfectly adaptable
to the production of both consumer goods and capital
goods, the PPF would be a straight line, reflecting a con-
stant opportunity cost along the PPF.

Disasters can cause an inward shift or retraction


2-3dWhat Can Shift of the PPF.

the PPF?
Any production possibilities frontier assumes the economy’s
resources, technology and know-how, and rules of the game consumer goods axis, as shown in panel (c). Panel (d)
are fixed during the period under consideration. Over time, shows the effect of an increase in a resource such as con-
however, the PPF may shift if resources, technology, and struction equipment that is suited only to capital goods.
know-how, or the rules of the game change. Economic
growth is an expansion in the economy’s production pos- Increases in the Capital Stock
sibilities as reflected by an outward shift of the PPF. An economy’s PPF depends in part on the stock of human
and physical capital. The more capital an economy pro-
Changes in Resource Availability duces in one period, the more output can be produced in
If people decide to work longer hours, the PPF shifts the next period. Thus, producing more capital goods during
outward, as shown in panel (a) of Exhibit 2.3. An increase this period (e.g., more machines in the case of physical capi-
in the size or health of the labor force, an increase in the tal or more education in the case of human capital) shifts
skills of the labor force, or an increase in the availability the economy’s PPF outward in the next period.
of other resources, such as new oil discoveries, also shifts
the PPF outward. In contrast, a decrease of resources Technological Change and More
shifts the PPF inward, as depicted in panel (b). For Know-How
example, in 1990 Iraq invaded Kuwait, setting oil fields A technological discovery that employs resources more
ablaze and destroying much of Kuwait’s physical capi- efficiently could shift the economy’s PPF outward.
tal. In West Africa, the encroaching sands of the Sahara Some discoveries enhance the production of both con-
destroy thousands of square miles of farmland each year. sumer goods and capital goods, as shown in panel (a) of
And in northwest China, a rising tide of wind-blown sand Exhibit 2.3. For example, the Internet has increased each
has claimed grasslands, lakes, and forests, and swallowed firm’s ability to find available resources. A technological
entire villages, forcing tens of thousands of people to flee. discovery that benefits consumer goods only, such as
The new PPFs in panels (a) and (b) appear to be paral- more disease-resistant crops, is reflected by a rotation
lel to the original ones, indicating that the resources that outward of the PPF along the consumer goods axis, as
changed could produce both capital goods and consumer shown in panel (c). Note that point F remains unchanged
goods. For example, an increase because the breakthrough does not affect the production
in electrical power can enhance of capital goods. Panel (d) shows a technological advance
economic growth An
increase in the economy’s the production of both, as shown in the production of capital goods, such as better software
ability to produce goods and in panel (a). If a resource such as for designing heavy machinery. But even for a given level
services; reflected by an out- farmland benefits just consumer of technology and a given number of workers, output can
ward shift of the economy’s
goods, then increased availability increase over time with more know-how. For example,
production possibilities
frontier or productivity of that resource researchers have documented that steel production dou-
shifts the PPF more along the bled at a mini-mill even though the technology did not
32 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Exhibit 2.3
Shifts of the Economy’s Production Possibilities Frontier
When the resources available to an economy change, the PPF shifts. If more resources become available,
if technology and know-how improve, or if the rules of the game create greater stability, the PPF shifts
outward, as in panel (a), indicating that more output can be produced. A decrease in available resources or
an upheaval in the rules causes the PPF to shift inward, as in panel (b). Panel (c) shows a change affecting
consumer goods. More consumer goods can now be produced at any given level of capital goods. Panel (d)
shows a change affecting capital goods.

(a) Increase in available resources, (b) Decrease in available resources


better technology, more know-how, or or greater uncertainty in the rules
improvement in the rules of the game of the game

A'
A A
Consumer goods

Consumer goods
A''

F F' F '' F
Capital goods Capital goods

(c) Change in resources, technology, know-how, (d) Change in resources, technology,


or rules that benefits consumer goods know-how, or rules that benefits capital goods

A'

A
Consumer goods

Consumer goods

F F F'
Capital goods Capital goods

change nor did the number of workers. Through experi- underpinnings that encourage people to pursue pro-
mentation, workers developed more know-how.1 ductive activity. A more stable political environment
and more reliable property rights increase the incen-
Improvements in the Rules of the Game tive to work and to invest, and thus help the economy
The rules of the game are the formal and informal grow. For example, people have more incentive to work
institutions that support the economy—the laws, cus- if taxes claim less of their paychecks. People have more
toms, manners, conventions, and other institutional incentive to invest if they are confident that their invest-
ment will not be appropriated by government, stolen by
1. Igal Hendel and Yossi Spiegel, “Small Steps for Workers, a Giant Leap for thieves, destroyed by civil unrest, or blown up by ter-
Productivity.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 6 February
2014: 73–90. rorists. Greater certainty and stability in the rules of the
CHAPTER 2: Economic Tools and Economic Systems 33
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
game shift the economy’s PPF outward. On the other efficiently and how the economy selects the most pre-
hand, greater uncertainty about the rules of the game ferred combination depends on the decision-making
reduces the economy’s productive capacity, as reflected rules employed. But regardless of how decisions are
by an inward shift of the PPF. For example, during the made, each economy must answer three fundamental
Great Recession of 2007–2009, trust in U.S. institutions questions.
such as banks, newspapers, Congress, and big corpora-
tions declined and this reduced the economy’s productive
ability.2 2-4aThree Questions Every
Economic System Must
2-3eWhat We Learn from Answer
the PPF What goods and services are to be produced? How are
The PPF demonstrates several ideas introduced so they to be produced? And for whom are they to be pro-
far. The first is efficiency: The PPF describes efficient duced? An economic system is the set of mechanisms
combinations of output, given the economy’s resources, and institutions that resolve the what, how, and for whom
technology and know-how, and rules of the game. The questions. Some criteria used to distinguish among eco-
second idea is scarcity: Given the resources, technol- nomic systems are (1) who owns the resources, (2) what
ogy and know-how, and rules of the game, the economy decision-making process is used to allocate resources
can produce only so much output per period. The PPF and products, and (3) what types of incentives guide eco-
slopes downward, because more of one good means less nomic decision makers.
of the other good, thus demonstrating opportunity cost.
The PPF’s bowed-out shape reflects the law of increasing What Goods and Services
opportunity cost, which arises because some resources Are to Be Produced?
are not perfectly adaptable to the production of each type Most of us take for granted the incredible number of
of good. Moreover, a shift outward in the PPF reflects choices that go into deciding what gets produced—
economic growth. everything from which new kitchen appliances are intro-
Finally, because society must somehow select a duced and which roads get built, to which of the 10,000
specific combination of output—a single point—along movie scripts purchased by U.S. studios each year get to
the PPF, the PPF also underscores the need for choice. be among the 650 or so movies made. Although different
Selecting a particular combination determines not economies resolve these and millions of other questions
only the consumer goods available in this period, but using different decision-making rules and mechanisms,
also the capital stock available in the next period. One all economies must somehow make such choices.
thing the PPF does not tell us is which combination
to choose. The PPF tells us only about the costs, not How Are Goods and Services
the benefits, of the two goods. To make a selection, to Be Produced?
we need to know about both costs and benefits. How The economic system must determine how output gets
society goes about choosing a particular combination produced. Which resources should be used, and how
depends on the nature of the economic system, as you should they be combined to make stuff? How much labor
will see next. should be used and at what skill levels? What kinds of
machines should be used? What new technology should
be incorporated into the latest video games? Should the
2-4 ECONOMIC SYSTEMS office complex be built in the city or closer to the inter-
state highway? Millions of individual decisions determine
which resources are employed and how these resources
Each point along the economy’s production possi-
are combined.
bilities frontier is an efficient combination of outputs.
Whether the economy produces For Whom Are Goods and Services
economic system The
set of mechanisms and to Be Produced?
institutions that resolve the 2. Betsey Stevenson and Justin
Wolfers, “Trust in Public Institutions Who will actually consume the goods and services pro-
what, how, and for whom Over the Business Cycle,” American
questions duced? The economic system must determine how to allo-
Economic Review, 101 (May 2011):
281–287. cate the fruits of production among the population. Should
34 PART ONE: Introduction to Economics

Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
everyone receive equal shares? Should the weak and the harnesses the pursuit of self-interest to direct resources
sick get more? Should it be “first come, first served,” so that where they earn the greatest reward. According to Smith,
those willing to wait in line get more? Should goods be allo- although each individual pursues his or her self-interest,
cated according to height? Weight? Religion? Age? Gender? the “invisible hand” of market forces promotes the general
Race? Looks? Strength? Political connections? Lottery? welfare. Capitalism is sometimes called laissez-faire; trans-
Majority rule? The value of resources supplied? The ques- lated from the French, this phrase means “to let do,” or to
tion “For whom are goods and services to be produced?” is let people do as they choose without government interven-
often referred to as the distribution question. tion. Thus, under capitalism, voluntary choices based on
Although the three economic questions were dis- rational self-interest are made in unrestricted markets to
cussed separately, they are closely related. The answer to answer the questions what, how, and for whom.
one depends on the answers to the others. For example, As we will see in later chapters, pure capitalism has
an economy that distributes goods and services uniformly its flaws. The most notable market failures are these:
to everyone will, no doubt, answer the what-will-be-­
1. No central authority protects property rights,
produced question differently than an economy that
enforces contracts, and otherwise ensures that the
somehow allows more personal choice. As we have seen,
rules of the game are followed.
laws about resource ownership and the role of govern-
ment determine the “rules of the game”—the set of con- 2. People with no resources to sell could starve.
ditions that shape individual incentives and constraints. 3. Some producers may try to monopolize markets by
Along a spectrum ranging from the freest to the most regi- eliminating the competition.
mented types of economic systems, pure capitalism would 4. The production or consumption of some goods
be at one end and the pure command system at the other. involves side effects that can harm or benefit people
not involved in the market transaction.
2-4b Pure Capitalism 5. Firms have no incentive to produce the so-called
public goods, such as national defense, because pri-
Under pure capitalism, there is no government. The rules
vate firms cannot prevent nonpayers from enjoying
of the game include the private ownership of resources and
the benefits of public goods.
the market distribution of products. Owners have property
rights to the use of their resources and are therefore free 6. Market economies experience economic fluctua-
to supply those resources to the highest bidder. Private tions, which are alternating periods of expansions
property rights allow individual owners to use resources and recessions in their level of economic activity,
or to charge others for their use. Any income from sup- especially in employment and production.
plying labor, capital, natural resources, or entrepreneurial Because of these limitations, countries have modified
ability goes to the individual resource owners. Producers pure capitalism to allow some role for government. Even
are free to make and sell whatever they think will be profit- Adam Smith believed government should play a role.
able. Consumers are free to buy whatever goods they can The United States is among the most market-oriented
afford. All this voluntary buying and selling is coordinated ­economies in the world today.
by unrestricted markets, where buyers and sellers make
their intentions known. Market prices guide resources to
their most productive use and channel goods and services 2-4cPure
to the consumers who value them the most. Command pure capitalism An eco-
nomic system characterized
Under pure capitalism, markets answer the what,
how, and for whom questions. That’s why capitalism is
System by the private ownership of
resources and the use of prices
also referred to as a market system. Markets transmit In a pure command sys- to coordinate economic activity
information about relative scarcity, provide individual tem, resources are directed in unregulated markets
incentives, and distribute income among resource sup- and production is coordi- private property rights
pliers. No individual or small group coordinates these nated not by market forces An owner’s right to use, rent, or
activities. Rather, it is the voluntary choices of many buy- but by the “command,” or sell resources or property
ers and sellers responding only to their individual incen- central plan, of government. pure command system
tives and constraints that direct resources and products In theory at least, instead An economic system character-
ized by the public ownership
to those who value them the most. of private property, there is
of resources and centralized
According to Adam Smith, market forces allocate public, or communal, owner- planning
resources as if by an “invisible hand”—an unseen force that ship of property. That’s why
CHAPTER 2: Economic Tools and Economic Systems 35
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-203
Copyright 2019 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s).
Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
The Project Gutenberg eBook of L'apparition : roman
This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States
and most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no
restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it
under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included with this
ebook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the
United States, you will have to check the laws of the country where
you are located before using this eBook.

Title: L'apparition : roman

Author: Lucie Delarue-Mardrus

Release date: September 15, 2023 [eBook #71658]

Language: French

Original publication: Paris: Ferenczi, 1921

Credits: Laurent Vogel, Chuck Greif and the Online Distributed


Proofreading Team at https://www.pgdp.net (This file was
produced from images generously made available by The
Internet Archive)

*** START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK


L'APPARITION : ROMAN ***
TABLE DES CHAPITRES

L’Apparition
Tous droits de traduction et reproduction réservés pour tous pays.
Copiright by J. Ferenczi, 1921.

LUCIE DELARUE-MARDRUS

L’Apparition
ROMAN

PARIS
J. FERENCZI, EDITEUR
9, RUE ANTOINE-CHANTIN (XIVᵉ)

L’APPARITION
I

LA RENCONTRE DANS LE PARC

Laurent Carmin entr’ouvrit la porte de la salle à manger et vit sa mère en


discussion avec un de ses fermiers.
Maître Casimir voulait des réparations locatives. Mᵐᵉ Carmin répondait
qu’il n’y avait pas urgence. Laurent referma la porte.
De telles démarches se renouvelaient, au château, de la part des
herbagers; mais ils repartaient presque toujours sans obtenir satisfaction, car
Mᵐᵉ Carmin était Normande comme eux, et bien plus forte qu’eux.
On l’admire pour cela dans le pays, et aussi pour ses biens, qui sont
nombreux, espacés les uns des autres, des grands et des petits, fermes et
manoirs, pressoirs, herbages et bois-taillis.
—A qui cela appartient-il?
Réponse presque toujours la même:
—Est à Mâme Carmin.
Il y a de ces marquises de Carabas en Normandie, car les traditions de
l’ancien temps n’y ont guère souffert du renversement des rois.
Le château, ancien et restauré, noble et charmant, s’entourait d’un parc
mal entretenu par économie. L’église du village, située presque dans ce
parc, avait l’air d’une dépendance. Il était, au milieu de la grande pelouse,
une pièce d’eau sur laquelle naviguaient deux cygnes. Un saule pleureur se
mirait.
Allées profondes, fourrés épais, clairières, une étendue qui semblait
n’avoir de limites que les horizons bleus et mauves, venait s’achever au
pied du perron, quatre marches et leur belle rampe de pierre. Et tout cela,
qui écrasait l’humble village, c’était bien la seigneurie d’autrefois,
orgueilleuse, isolée au milieu de champs à l’infini, très loin des villes.
Au-dedans, un meuble disparate faisait se côtoyer la camelote moderne
avec de précieuses choses. Le grand salon montrait des housses, un lustre
de cristal, une pendule Restauration sous globe, des stores de soie
bouillonnés, quelques portraits de famille. Le feu de bois de l’immense
cheminée y répandait un charme en hiver; la lumière verte des arbres y
jetait, l’été, sa mélancolie campagnarde.
En bas, il y avait encore, trop grande, claire, la cuisine et sa dinanderie
du vieux temps, la salle à manger brune et sombre, tapissée de verdures
admirables, la salle d’étude avec son tableau noir, la salle de billard toujours
fermée, un petit salon et ses fauteuils de tapisserie criarde, le vestibule et les
couloirs à vitraux polychromes, sans compter la seconde cuisine, la
buanderie, l’office et la lingerie. En haut, les chambres sentaient la cretonne
et le pitchpin; mais certaines avaient mobilier d’acajou, ciels de lit et
rideaux à fleurs, qui furent le décor des grand’mères.
Mᵐᵉ Carmin de Bonnevie, méticuleusement, continuait là-dedans
l’existence sans histoire des siens. Etre veuve de bonne heure, pour une
femme comme elle, c’est se faire, à trente ans, dévote, comme sous Louis
XIV, ce qui veut dire être habillée de noir et vouée à la piété, choses qui
n’empêchent en rien de veiller âprement sur l’argent.
Nerveuse et sèche, ses cheveux noirs, lisses, chignon sans grâce, son
teint jaune de vieille fille, ses yeux bruns, assez beaux, chargés d’austérité,
rien, ni ses habitudes d’ordre et d’épargne, ni son habillement, ni le genre
de petits chapeaux étriqués, monopole de la province, qu’elle perchait sur sa
tête pour aller à la messe, rien en elle n’indiquait qu’elle eût une passion
dans la vie.
Elle en avait une, cependant. C’est la seule qu’on juge légitime chez les
femmes. Elle a pourtant la violence et toute l’animalité des autres. Mᵐᵉ de
Bonnevie aimait son fils, secrètement, on peut dire, ne voulant rien montrer
à ce garçon, ni aux autres, de sa faiblesse cachée. Etant chef de famille
depuis plus de cinq ans, elle tâchait de l’élever dignement, afin d’en faire un
homme selon son goût, un vrai successeur des hobereaux qui l’avaient
engendré, un vrai Carmin de Bonnevie, gentilhomme-fermier qui soigne ses
terres, accomplit ses devoirs religieux, chasse au fusil, joue au billard, fonde
une famille de deux enfants au plus, et meurt, après une existence si bien
remplie, convenablement, comme il a vécu.

Laurent acheva de refermer tout doucement la porte qu’il avait


entr’ouverte. Il avait vu ce qu’il voulait voir.
C’était un garçon de douze ans à peu près, droit sur ses reins, bien fait,
tourbillonnant. Ses joues rondes, son nez parfaitement enfantin, ses cheveux
noirs, paquet de boucles sur le front, lui conservaient, à cet âge, sa
physionomie de petit bébé tout brun; et rien n’était puéril comme sa voix
trop haute, cette voix qui chantait le dimanche à l’église, angéliquement.
Mais le charmant enfant de chœur, parmi ces traits encore indécis, possédait
le regard le plus audacieux, une paire d’eux gris sombre, enfoncés et larges,
étincelants et rapprochés; sa bouche épaisse, d’un rouge violent, accusait
encore l’énergie formidable de son petit menton; et, cachée sous les
boucles, la forme bien particulière de son front montrait deux bosses
arrondies, vraies petites cornes de faune, prêtes à percer la peau tendue et
lisse.
Depuis sa naissance, presque, la maman luttait contre lui.
Il avait commencé par enfoncer ses quatre dents, à dix mois, dans le sein
de sa nourrice, au point que cette femme n’avait plus voulu de lui. Dès ses
premiers pas, ses caprices, destructions, cris, trépignements, coups à ceux
qui le portaient, s’étaient multipliés jusqu’à remplir tout le grand château de
sa petite présence atroce. De sept à dix ans, se roulant par terre au moindre
mot, crachant à la figure des gens ou leur jetant les objets à la tête, mordant
comme un petit fauve, injuriant et taquinant tout le monde, ses férocités
avaient bouleversé la famille et la domesticité. Et maintenant qu’il sortait de
la première enfance, on ne savait pas trop où s’exerçaient ses ravages,
puisqu’il disparaissait dans le parc à la moindre occasion, pour le
soulagement général, du reste.
Malgré tout cela, pourtant, on l’aimait. Il était si sain et si beau! Son rire
était si frais! Cette enfance turbulente était la vie même du grand château
mélancolique.
Cependant, offrant à Dieu la peine inouïe qu’elle se donnait pour élever
ce mauvais sujet, la mère, malgré tout son orgueil d’avoir un fils, regrettait
parfois, sans oser se l’avouer à elle-même, qu’il ne fût pas plutôt une fille.
Mais la mauvaise foi maternelle reprenait vite la parole:
—Il est trop bien portant, c’est tout. Il deviendra plus traitable avec
l’âge... Tous les garçons, c’est connu, sont difficiles à élever... Son père
avait mauvaise tête aussi, mais bon cœur.

Il courait, son canif au poing. Son canif était le seul instrument d’étude
qu’il aimât. L’ouvrir et le fermer le distrayait quand, le mardi et le samedi,
l’instituteur de l’école venait lui donner sa leçon, ou bien pendant qu’au
presbytère M. le curé, seul à seul, chaque mardi, l’interrogeait sur le
catéchisme et le latin.
Ce canif, il l’avait détourné de ses destinées ennuyeuses pour en faire un
joujou passionnant. Tailler des crayons, quelle bêtise! Mais fabriquer des
arcs et des flèches dans le sous-bois, poignarder les pêches et les poires des
espaliers quand François a le dos tourné, couper en quatre les vers de terre,
amputer les grenouilles, et, lorsqu’il faut rester à la maison, taillader
clandestinement le bord des meubles du salon, lancer la lame dans la
planche à repasser, pour l’épouvante de Maria quand elle est à la lingerie,
ou bien hacher furieusement les beaux légumes de Clémentine à ses
fourneaux, voilà l’emploi vrai d’un canif...
Son néfaste jouet dans la main, il bondit de toute son âme, ivre de cette
récréation illicite qu’il vient de s’octroyer.
—Quand maman va revenir à la salle d’études...
Il rit. Il rit d’être dehors pendant qu’il fait si beau, rit d’avoir, avant de
les quitter, donné des coups de pied dans ses livres et ses cahiers jetés par
terre, rit du bon tour qu’il joue à tout le monde en se sauvant dans le parc,
alors qu’on le croit à son pupitre, apprenant ses déclinaisons.
En passant comme le vent devant la plate-bande inculte où le mois de
juin triomphe:
—Rosa la rose!... crie-t-il à pleins poumons.
Sa voix aiguë a déchiré l’air, cri d’hirondelle. Le voilà déjà loin. Ses
jambes nues de petit garçon musclé l’emportent, tout son corps dessine des
lignes dansantes sous le jersey du costume marin qu’il porte.
Le voilà dans la pépinière où sont rassemblées les essences rares.
Brusque, il s’arrête, obéissant à son désir soudain. Vite, ouvrons le cher
canif. D’un seul coup, la lame, vigoureusement maniée, s’enfonce dans
l’écorce tendre du premier petit arbre. Il l’arrache et recommence.
—Tiens!... Voilà pour toi!... Tiens!... Voilà encore pour toi!
Une fureur joyeuse l’anime. Il voudrait que l’arbre se défendît. Il
voudrait se battre.
—C’est toi, Laurent?... Qu’est-ce que tu fais là?
Il s’est retourné. L’oncle Jacques est là, qui le regarde.
L’oncle Jacques est le frère de maman. Il s’appelle comme elle: Carmin
de Bonnevie. Car papa et maman étaient cousins. L’oncle habite depuis
toujours un petit pavillon dans le parc. Laurent sait comme on le considère
à la maison. Il est célibataire et riche. Parrain et tuteur de Laurent, dont il a
choisi le nom sans qu’on devine pourquoi (puisque les aînés de Bonnevie se
sont toujours appelés Jean), il est aussi l’oncle à l’héritage. Débile, avec sa
figure fripée et fade, ses yeux myopes, ses cheveux grisonnants, c’est un
original inoffensif qui vit tout seul dans son pavillon, faisant lui-même son
ménage par peur qu’on ne dérange ses papiers, souffrant à peine que la fille
de cuisine lui prépare ses maigres repas. On ne le voit guère au château que
le dimanche, jour où maman l’invite à déjeuner ou à dîner.
Il a des idées à lui. Il porte toujours dans sa poche une barbe de plume
dont il se chatouille le dedans du nez, au moins trois fois par jour, pour se
faire éternuer, parce que cela évite les rhumatismes. Il fait un peu
d’aquarelle et de modelage. Mais sa vraie marotte, ce sont les livres, parmi
lesquels il vit, c’est l’on ne sait quels essais historiques qu’il écrit. Il croit
avoir, au cours de ses recherches, retrouvé par hasard les traces de la
famille, dont l’origine remonterait à la fin du XIVᵉ siècle. Il est en
correspondance avec des savants, des bibliophiles, des libraires. Et l’argent
qu’il dépense pour ses documents est une des exaspérations de sa sœur.

Grand, voûté, crasseux, mal habillé, l’air d’un pauvre, l’oncle Jacques
considérait son neveu.
—Qu’est-ce que tu fais là?...
Il avait, comme eux tous, un rien d’accent normand, cette manière très
atténuée que, chez nous, les gens distingués ont de chanter comme les
paysans, ce qui, du reste, n’est pas sans charme.
Le petit Laurent releva son menton volontaire. Ses yeux pleins d’éclats
regardèrent de bas en haut le grand type sans méchanceté qui ne le
gronderait pas.
—Ben, tu vois bien, répondit-il, je massacre les arbres...
Un rêve couva dans les yeux doux de l’oncle. Depuis longtemps, il
soupirait aussi, lui, comme sa sœur, au sujet de l’enfant. Ce diable ne
ressemblait en rien au neveu qu’il eût souhaité, studieux et sage disciple
auquel il eût inculqué l’amour de l’histoire, qu’il eût initié lentement à ses
recherches sur l’origine de leur maison.
—Ce n’est pas beau d’abîmer les arbres... prononça-t-il. Et puis, qu’est-
ce que tu fais à cette heure-ci dehors? Tu devrais être à ta salle d’études.
Une fois de plus, il soupira:
—Si tu voulais, Laurent, je t’apprendrais, moi... Et sans t’ennuyer, tu
sais?
Une petite émotion lui fit avancer sa main, gentiment, comme pour
mieux persuader par quelque caresse.
Le gamin, impassible, laissa la main s’avancer. Puis, appliquant dessus
une fort grande claque, il répondit par le mot le plus grossier du monde. Et,
sans reculer, effronté, provocant, il continua de regarder son oncle.
L’autre, remettant sans rien dire sa pauvre main dans sa poche, attentif,
dévisagea le petit. Celui-ci, les yeux égayés par une ironie toute normande,
prit exprès le plein accent du pays pour demander, de sa petite voix trop
haute:
—Est-y qu’ t’ aurais point entendu?
Et, de toutes ses forces, faisant un pas en avant, le menton haut, il cria de
nouveau l’insulte.
Là-dessus, un craquement de branches. Et l’on vit Mᵐᵉ Carmin de
Bonnevie, nerveuse et noire, qui venait à grands pas colères.
—Laurent!... Laurent!...
Alors, avec un geste de petit bouc, il secoua sa tête toute frisée et brune,
exécuta de côté quelque chose comme une ruade, et, faisant un pied de nez
dans la direction de sa mère, à toutes jambes il se sauva, disparut.
L’oncle Jacques, nez à nez avec sa sœur suffoquée, murmura:
—Je te félicite, Alice! Il est bien élevé, ton fils!
A quoi, rouge et méprisante, elle répondit, elle aussi, sur un ton presque
paysan:
—Tu t’occuperais de tes dictionnaires, cela vaudrait peut-être beaucoup
mieux, tu sais?...
Puis, reprenant sa course, elle se remit, haletante, à la poursuite du petit.
II

APPRIVOISEMENT

Il avait continué de fuir, était loin, maintenant, tout au bout du parc. Par
une brèche, il se coula, sur les genoux et les mains, à travers la haute haie
épineuse, et fut sur la route.
Le village commençait là. Quatre heures. Les écoliers sortaient de
l’école.
Il y en avait quatre ou cinq avec lesquels Laurent aimait à jouer. Chaque
fois qu’il le pouvait, il allait les retrouver en cachette. On le lui défendait
expressément, ces enfants n’étant pas de son rang, et connus pour leur
mauvais esprit.
Ils étaient de ces petits Normands dits «fortes têtes», qui ramassent des
cailloux pour lapider les passants et ne rêvent par ailleurs qu’école
buissonnière et maraude.
Ce n’étaient pas des fils de paysans. Ceux-là sont plus pacifiques et plus
lents.
L’un appartient à la dame de la poste, l’autre à l’épicier, le troisième...
Laurent s’était battu longtemps avec eux avant de les dominer.
Maintenant il était leur maître, celui qui décide des jeux et des promenades.
Après saute-mouton et les quilles, la bande quittait le village et s’en
allait à travers les chemins creux, longeant les haies des fermes, en quête de
méfaits nouveaux.
Chaque saison avait ses plaisirs. En hiver, ils s’introduisaient, par des
trous, dans les granges fermées, afin de jouer à cache-cache dans les bottes
de foin, qu’ils mettaient à mal en les piétinant. Au printemps, ils
cherchaient des nids, ou bien volaient des œufs dans les poulaillers. En été,
c’était la cueillette des groseilles dans les vergers mal gardés. En automne,
ils secouaient les pommiers et bourraient leurs poches de pommes qu’ils se
partageaient ensuite, avec cris et batailles.
Laurent avait à profusion, chez lui, toutes ces bonnes choses; mais il ne
les aimait que dérobées, conquises. C’était pour lui le butin de guerre, avec
tout ce que ce mot comporte de risques et d’aventures.
Au retour de ces expéditions, sali, déchiré, les yeux sauvages, il rentrait
au château, sachant fort bien quelles punitions l’attendaient.
C’étaient toujours les mêmes, Mᵐᵉ Carmin n’ayant pas trouvé mieux.
Elle les graduait selon la gravité des cas. Il y avait la privation de dessert,
les lignes à copier, la retenue du dimanche, le dîner au pain sec, le coucher
bien avant l’heure, en plein jour. Il y avait aussi le blâme de M. le curé, la
menace du collège, et autres paroles qui le laissaient indifférent. Mais
personne, jamais, n’avait levé la main sur lui, ce qui, peut-être, eût été la
seule chose à faire.
Avec son instinct d’enfant, il se rendait parfaitement compte qu’aucune
autorité suffisante, dans cette maison sans homme, ne pouvait mater son
indiscipline. Et, sans même le savoir, il méprisait en bloc tout son monde.

... Quand Mᵐᵉ Carmin vit qu’elle ne rattraperait pas son fils, elle rentra
tout époumonnée au château, mit son chapeau, ses gants, et fut au
presbytère trouver M. le curé.
C’était son habitude dans de telles occasions.
Accoutumé, monotone, l’abbé Lost la reçut dans sa petite salle à manger.
C’était un prêtre de campagne, grand et solide, fin visage paysan, cheveux
déjà gris, esprit plein de bonhomie et non sans sagesse.
Quand il eut, avec des yeux demi-clos de confesseur, écouté les
doléances de sa châtelaine:
—Qu’est-ce que vous voulez, Madame, dit-il d’un air las... les punitions
n’agissent pas, les raisonnements encore moins. Le pauvre enfant n’est
sensible à rien et n’a peur de rien. Je vous l’ai déjà dit. Il faudrait vous en
séparer pour le mettre dans une bonne institution, loin d’ici... Ce serait
mieux à tous les points de vue. Il serait enrégimenté, surveillé...
L’émulation... Il est tout aussi apte qu’un autre, quand il veut. Vous n’avez
qu’à voir comme il a vite appris son plain-chant. Voilà! Quand ça lui plaît...
—Je ne me séparerai jamais de mon fils!... répondit froidement Mᵐᵉ
Carmin.
Onctueux, le prêtre accepta cette phrase qu’il attendait.
—Alors, Madame, ayez un précepteur... Un abbé... Je vous ai déjà dit
tout cela.
—Monsieur le curé, fit-elle avec assez de hauteur, je vous ai déjà dit
aussi qu’il ne me convenait pas d’introduire dans ma vie une personne
étrangère...
Ils avaient baissé les yeux tous deux. Mᵐᵉ Carmin était encore trop jeune,
et craignait les mauvaises langues; elle était, de plus, chacun le savait, fort
regardante et redoutait des dépenses non prévues dans ses calculs serrés.
L’abbé Lost releva la tête, cligna, ne regarda pas en face, et conclut:
—Alors, Madame?...
—Alors, Monsieur le curé?...
—C’est un enfant bien difficile... articula-t-il d’un air décourageant.
Une véhémence contenue rendit plus foncés les yeux de la nerveuse
personne.
—Ah! Monsieur le curé!... Quand on pense qu’à dix mois il mordait sa
nourrice au sang, et que j’ai dû renoncer à la garder! Il a fallu...
Il connaissait l’histoire. Patiemment, il reprit quand elle eut fini:
—Puisque vous ne pouvez pas vous en séparer, Madame, peut-être
faudra-t-il essayer... essayer d’autres moyens... Voyons! L’enfant a grand
désir de posséder une bicyclette... Peut-être qu’en la lui promettant s’il est
raisonnable...
Elle le coupa passionnément:
—Non!
Puis, essayant de se modérer:
—Une bicyclette?... Mais on ne le verrait plus jamais, alors? Il serait
tous les jours à la ville... Ce serait du propre!...
Le prêtre ouvrit les bras et haussa les sourcils, comme pour exprimer: «A
la fin, qu’est-ce que vous voulez qu’on dise à une entêtée comme vous?...»
Mais il avait des raisons, d’ordre bien ecclésiastique, pour ménager son
importante paroissienne. Il prit un rassurant air grave:
—Madame, le bon Dieu seul sait ce qu’il veut faire de votre fils. Il faut
avoir confiance. Les Confessions de saint Augustin sont là pour nous
prouver que...
Elle n’était venue que pour entendre cela. A personne d’autre qu’au
prêtre elle n’eût fait voir l’état de son cœur anxieux.
*
**
Laurent n’accompagna pas ses amis dans leurs entreprises d’aujourd’hui.
Depuis sa rencontre de tout à l’heure avec son oncle, une idée s’insinuait
lentement en lui. Jamais il ne semblait entendre les paroles qu’on lui disait,
ne les entendait pas, en réalité. Mais elles restaient comme semées dans sa
tête, et germaient un peu plus tard.
Voici, marchant d’un pas calme, le même galopin qui courait si fort. La
tête basse, il réfléchit, tout en avançant sous les arbres de l’allée. Ses grands
sourcils, froncés, donnent à son front mat, chargé de boucles noires, une
expression qui n’est pas celle d’un enfant. Ses yeux sombres, pleins d’une
âme autoritaire, regardent de côté sans rien voir.
Il cessa soudain d’hésiter et se remit à courir.
A la porte du pavillon habité par son oncle, il frappa trois grands coups,
d’un geste décidé, violent, comme tous ses gestes. Et parce que l’oncle
n’ouvrait pas assez vite, il se mit à trépigner. Enfin, des pas se firent
entendre.
—Qui est là?... demanda la voix étonnée de l’oncle.
—C’est moi, Laurent. Ouvre!
Le verrou, la clef, tout grinça. L’oncle Jacques apparut dans l’ombre de
son corridor.
C’était la première fois que son neveu pénétrait chez lui.
—Qu’est-ce qui t’amène?... fit-il avec une immense surprise.
Laurent lui planta dans ses yeux myopes un regard catégorique. Mais il
ne sut dire que ce mot d’enfant:
—Rien...
L’autre comprit-il qu’il y avait, dans ce mot, beaucoup de choses?
—Entre!... murmura-t-il avec une émotion singulière.
Et quand le petit fut dans le cabinet de travail, au milieu des paperasses
qui envahissaient tout parmi la plus épaisse poussière, devant la table de
travail surchargée de livres, de brouillons, de gravures, qu’éclairait la
fenêtre à petits carreaux à travers laquelle on voyait fuir les perspectives du
parc, il fit un mouvement effaré, comme s’il allait se sauver.
Il n’y eut aucune explication. L’oncle s’assit à sa table. Avec un petit
tremblement dans la voix:
—Puisque tu es venu me voir... Tu sais ce que j’étudie là?
—Non!
—Eh bien! C’est l’histoire de notre famille.
Il se pencha, chercha fiévreusement, ses yeux myopes tout près des
papiers.
Laurent piétinait. Il avait quelque chose à dire, qui voulait sortir, qui ne
pouvait pas attendre. Mais il savait que le moment n’était pas encore
propice. Et il souffrait, de tout son être impatient, péremptoire.
—Je suis presque sûr, maintenant, continuait Jacques de Bonnevie,
presque sûr d’avoir retrouvé les traces de notre premier ancêtre. Il y a de ces
coïncidences qui ne peuvent pas être du hasard...
C’était sa passion à lui. Toute sa personne frémissait. Pour la première
fois, quelqu’un de la famille venait à lui, consentait à l’écouter. Et c’était
justement le plus intéressant, Laurent, l’enfant, celui qui pouvait devenir le
disciple. Depuis vingt ans, les siens le considéraient comme un maniaque
ennuyeux dont on n’entend même plus les propos.
—Ecoute... Je vais te retrouver le livre, où, pour la première fois, il y a
quinze ans, j’ai découvert, je crois, l’origine de notre nom... Tu vas juger
toi-même... C’est presque une certitude... C’est... oui!... oui!... C’est une
certitude! J’ai d’autres documents, tu vas voir... Qu’est-ce que tu fais?...
Ah! oui!... les images!... Tu regardes mes gravures?... On vient de me les
envoyer. Mais ce n’est pas intéressant. Il y en a une que je cherche...
Il secoua la tête d’un air agacé.
—Ils ont bêtes, tous ces libraires! Il va falloir, un de ce jours, que je
fasse le voyage... que j’aille voir moi-même les musées... Il n’y a pas
moyen!...
Brusquement, il se tourna tout entier vers l’enfant. Et, comme si c’eût été
le préambule de toute une conférence:
—C’est dommage que tu ne saches pas l’italien. Mais j’ai mes
traductions.
Laurent fit un pas brutal en avant. Mais l’oncle ne s’en aperçut pas.
—Et, d’abord, poursuivit-il, est-ce que, là-bas, ils t’ont déjà fait faire de
l’histoire universelle?
Laurent secoua rageusement la tête.
—Non!
—C’est dommage! Alors, on ne t’a jamais parlé des Sforza, de Ludovic
le More, des Noirs et des Blancs, des Guelfes et des Gibelins, des Grandes
Compagnies, des condottieri?
La tête remuait toujours, de plus en plus négative et rageuse.
—A ton âge?.... Qu’est-ce qu’ils t’apprennent donc, chez toi?
L’enfant haussa les épaules. Et, comme soulagé d’exhaler son mépris, de
quelque façon que ce fût:
—Ils m’apprennent l’Histoire Sainte et le catéchisme!
Un rire de l’oncle:
—Imbéciles!
Il se leva, prit dans ses mains la tête toute frisée qui résistait d’instinct,
ne parvenait pas à se laisser faire.
—Tu aimerais connaître notre histoire?
Un essai de complaisance passa sur le visage rebiffé du petit.
—Oui, oncle.
D’enthousiasme, le vieux garçon, pour se frotter les mains, lâcha la tête
qu’il tenait.
—Laurent, tu sais comment nous nous appelons, en réalité?
Ses yeux se fermèrent. Il y avait quinze ans qu’il le ressassait à des
moqueurs qui ne l’écoutaient pas.
—Ecoute bien! Notre premier ancêtre était moine au couvent des
Carmes, en Italie. C’était à une époque que je t’expliquerai plus tard. Un
beau jour, il sort de son couvent, décidé, comme on dit maintenant, à vivre
sa vie. Quelle vie!... Je te raconterai. Tu ne saisis pas encore?... Un surnom
lui reste: Carmine. Maintenant, voici autre chose. Il y a, dans l’histoire des
Grandes Compagnies, un fameux Buonavita, ainsi nommé par ironie...
Passons! Eh bien!... Moi je suis à peu près sûr, à présent, que Carmine et
Buonavita ne sont qu’un seul et même personnage. Comprends-tu,
maintenant? Comprends-tu?... Carmine Buonavita, c’est notre nom: Carmin
de Bonnevie!
Se rasseyant, le front en sueur, il attira l’enfant contre lui.
—Qu’est-ce que tu dis de ça?... C’est assez clair! Coïncidence?...
Coïncidence?... Jamais!... Les deux noms, l’italien et le français, sont bien
identiques, voyons!
Une joie subite l’agita.
—Mon petit Laurent! Tu es venu! Tu es venu enfin! Quel bonheur que tu
m’aies compris!
Pour l’embrasser, il se souleva sur son fauteuil.
—Ecoute, maintenant! Je vais te lire...
Mais Laurent n’en pouvait plus. Malgré lui, ce qu’il avait décidé de dire
et qui l’avait amené là, dans ce pavillon, éclata comme une fanfare. Il mit
un bras autour du cou de son oncle, s’assit sur ses genoux, et, de sa plus
haute voix d’enfant de chœur:
—Oncle! Oncle!... Je veux une bicyclette, et c’est toi qui vas me
l’acheter!
La stupeur fit que Jacques de Bonnevie demeura d’abord absolument
muet. Doucement, ses mains avaient repoussé l’enfant. Le cœur serré, le
front bas, il regardait fixement par terre. Cette ridicule bicyclette, tombée
dans son rêve, l’anéantissait d’un seul coup.
Il put enfin relever la tête. Avec une indicible mélancolie, il murmura:
—Une bicyclette?...
C’était donc pour cela qu’il était venu le voir, le petit? Et de tout ce
qu’on venait de lui dire, il n’avait rien retenu, comme les autres...
—Ben oui, une bicyclette!... s’emporta Laurent. Maman ne veut pas me
la donner, et moi je la veux!
Il frappait du pied. Ses yeux flamboyaient.
Un sourire passa sur la figure triste de l’oncle.
—Et tu comptes sur moi pour ça? Je me ferais bien arranger par ta
mère!...
Son sourire finit en rire. Il s’était levé comme pour congédier le jeune
importun. Ce fut avec la plus amère ironie et le plus inutile orgueil qu’il
acheva, la tête haute:
—Et puis, c’est laid, une bicyclette! Un Carmine Buonavita ne monte
pas à bicyclette: il monte à cheval!
Laurent avait reculé comme un petit animal attaqué.
—Tu es aussi bête que les autres!... cria-t-il. Plus bête!... Je te déteste,
entends-tu, vieux idiot!...
Il avait fait un bond.
—Tiens, tes livres!... Tiens, tes papiers!... Tiens, tes gravures!...
Avec un cri déchirant, Jacques de Bonnevie se jeta sur son neveu.
Eparpillées sur le plancher, piétinées, les paperasses volaient. L’encrier
renversé glissait un serpent noir sur la table, menaçant les précieuses pages.
Ce fut une courte lutte. Le malheureux historien, dans le poing crispé du
petit, parvint à reprendre le papier qu’il chiffonnait férocement. Quelques
coups s’échangèrent. Puis, finalement maîtrisé, l’enfant, pris aux poignets,
repassa tout en se débattant la porte du cabinet de travail, celle du couloir,
celle, enfin, du pavillon, laquelle, avec bruit, se referma dans son petit dos
en jersey bleu.
III

LA BELLE DÉCOUVERTE

Par les allées crépusculaires, il revenait enfin au château. L’heure du


repas le ramenait animalement chez lui. C’était la seule discipline qu’il
connût et acceptât.
Il avait passé le reste de son après-midi, depuis six heures, à donner des
coups de pied dans la porte du pavillon de son oncle, puis à lancer des
pierres dans ses vitres. Mais l’oncle ayant fini par fermer les volets,
l’enfant, à la longue, s’était lassé.
Sa crise de colère, épuisée, le laissait encore bouillonnant. Les joues
moites, les yeux animés, il avait rôdé tout autour du pavillon, cherchant des
vengeances.
Maintenant qu’il rentrait, il savait que l’heure était venue de
l’immanquable punition. Mais il ne la redoutait pas beaucoup. Cela faisait
partie du rythme de sa vie. Ses poignets, tordus par les doigts de l’oncle, lui
faisaient encore mal. Il en éprouvait comme une satisfaction. Il s’était battu.
Il était bien.
Il ne se pressait pas. Sa pensée l’occupait, tandis qu’il avançait à travers
les arbres sombres.
Sous ses pieds, le sol était doux et mou, velouté de mousse qu’il ne
pouvait plus distinguer, dans la grande nuit qui tombait des branches
entrecroisées.
Une fraîcheur descendait avec l’heure. L’enfant passait parfois par une
zone de parfums venus de quelque chèvrefeuille invisible, ou bien de
certaines herbes, encore chaudes du soleil de la journée. Et, tout au bout des
avenues, le couchant et les ramures, étroitement mêlés, composaient un
long vitrail bleu, rouge et jaune.
Le grand apaisement du soir calmait peu à peu la petite âme insurgée.
Cependant aucune douceur n’y pénétrait. Laurent, simplement,
réfléchissait; et ses réflexions restaient combatives, ardentes.
—Ma bicyclette, je la veux! Ils me la donneront... Ou bien...

You might also like