You are on page 1of 67

Microeconomics, 11e - eBook PDF

Visit to download the full and correct content document:


https://ebooksecure.com/download/microeconomics-11e-ebook-pdf/
microeconomics

C O L A N D E R
11e
MICROECONOMICS
The McGraw-Hill Series in Economics
Essentials of economics Schiller Frank
The Economy Today, The Micro Microeconomics and Behavior
Brue, McConnell, and Flynn
­Economy Today, and The Macro Ninth Edition
Essentials of Economics
Economy Today
Fourth Edition Advanced Economics
Fifteenth Edition
Mandel Romer
Slavin
Economics: The Basics Advanced Macroeconomics
Economics, Microeconomics, and
M: Economics—The Basics Fifth Edition
­Macroeconomics
Third Edition
Eleventh Edition Money and Banking
Schiller
Essentials of Economics Economics of Social Issues Cecchetti and Schoenholtz
Tenth Edition Money, Banking, and Financial
Guell
­Markets
Issues in Economics Today
Principles of economics Seventh Edition
Fifth Edition
Asarta and Butters Urban Economics
Register and Grimes
Connect Master: Economics
Economics of Social Issues O’Sullivan
Second Edition
Twenty-First Edition Urban Economics
Colander Ninth Edition
Economics, Microeconomics, Econometrics and Data
and Macroeconomics ­Analytics Labor Economics
Eleventh Edition Hilmer and Hilmer Borjas
Frank, Bernanke, Antonovics, and Heffetz Practical Econometrics Labor Economics
Principles of Economics, Principles First Edition Eighth Edition
of Microeconomics, and Principles of Prince McConnell, Brue, and Macpherson
Macroeconomics Predictive Analytics for Business Contemporary Labor Economics
Seventh Edition Strategy Eleventh Edition
Frank, Bernanke, Antonovics, and Heffetz First Edition
Public Finance
A Streamlined Approach for:
Principles of Economics, Principles Managerial Economics Rosen and Gayer
of Microeconomics, and Principles of Baye and Prince Public Finance
Macroeconomics Managerial Economics and Business Tenth Edition
Third Edition Strategy
Ninth Edition Environmental Economics
Karlan and Morduch Field and Field
Economics, Microeconomics, and Brickley, Smith, and Zimmerman Environmental Economics:
Macroeconomics Managerial Economics and An Introduction
Second Edition ­Organizational Architecture Seventh Edition
Sixth Edition
McConnell, Brue, and Flynn
Economics, Microeconomics, and Thomas and Maurice International Economics
­Macroeconomics Managerial Economics Appleyard and Field
Twenty-First Edition Twelfth Edition International Economics
Ninth Edition
McConnell, Brue, and Flynn Intermediate Economics
Brief Editions: Microeconomics and Pugel
Bernheim and Whinston International Economics
Macroeconomics
Microeconomics Seventeenth Edition
Third Edition
Second Edition
Samuelson and Nordhaus
Dornbusch, Fischer, and Startz
Economics, Microeconomics, and
Macroeconomics
­Macroeconomics
Thirteenth Edition
Nineteenth Edition
ELEVENTH EDITION

Microeconomics
David C. Colander
Middlebury College
MICROECONOMICS, ELEVENTH EDITION
Published by McGraw-Hill Education, 2 Penn Plaza, New York, NY 10121. Copyright ©2020 by
McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. Previous editions
©2017, 2013, and 2010. No part of this publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by
any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill
Education, including, but not limited to, in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or
broadcast for distance learning.
Some ancillaries, including electronic and print components, may not be available to customers outside
the United States.
This book is printed on acid-free paper.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 LWI 21 20 19
ISBN 978-1-260-50714-0 (bound edition)
MHID 1-260-50714-9 (bound edition)
ISBN 978-1-260-50700-3 (loose-leaf edition)
MHID 1-260-50700-9 (loose-leaf edition)
Director: Anke Weekes
Senior Product Developer: Christina Kouvelis
Marketing Manager: Bobby Pearson
Lead Content Project Manager, core: Christine Vaughan
Senior Content Project Manager, assessment: Bruce Gin
Senior Buyer: Laura Fuller
Designer: Egzon Shaqiri
Content Licensing Specialist: Melissa Homer
Cover Image: ©Andis Rea/Shutterstock
Compositor: Aptara®, Inc.
All credits appearing on page or at the end of the book are considered to be an extension of the copyright
page.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Colander, David C.
Title: Microeconomics / David C. Colander, Middlebury College.
Description: Eleventh edition. | New York, NY : McGraw-Hill Education, [2020]
Identifiers: LCCN 2018046219 | ISBN 9781260507140 (alk. paper) | ISBN
1260507149 (alk. paper)
Subjects: LCSH: Microeconomics.
Classification: LCC HB172 .C558 2020 | DDC 338.5—dc23 LC record available at
https://lccn.loc.gov/2018046219

The Internet addresses listed in the text were accurate at the time of publication. The inclusion of a
website does not indicate an endorsement by the authors or McGraw-Hill Education, and McGraw-Hill
Education does not guarantee the accuracy of the information presented at these sites.

mheducation.com/highered
About the
Author
David Colander is Distinguished College Professor at Middlebury College.
He has authored, coauthored, or edited over 40 books and over 200 articles on a
wide range of economic topics.
He earned his BA at Columbia College and his MPhil and PhD at Columbia
University. He also studied at the University of Birmingham in England and at
Wilhelmsburg Gymnasium in Germany. Professor Colander has taught at
Columbia University, Vassar College, the University of Miami, and Princeton
University as the Kelley Professor of Distinguished Teaching. He has also been
Courtesy of David Colander
a consultant to Time-Life Films, a consultant to Congress, a Brookings Policy
Fellow, and Visiting Scholar at Nuffield College, Oxford.
Professor Colander has been president of both the History of Economic
Thought Society and the Eastern Economics Association. He has also served on
the editorial boards of The Journal of Economic Perspectives, The Journal of
Economic Education, The Journal of Economic Methodology, The Journal of the
History of Economic Thought, The Journal of Socio-Economics, and The Eastern
Economic Journal. He has been chair of the American Economic Association
Committee on Electronic Publishing, a member of the AEA Committee on
Economic Education, and is currently the associate editor for content of The
Journal of Economic Education.
He is married to a pediatrician, Patrice. In their spare time, the Colanders
designed and built an oak post-and-beam house on a ridge overlooking the Green
Mountains to the east and the Adirondacks to the west. The house is located on
the site of a former drive-in movie theater. (They replaced the speaker poles with
fruit trees and used the I-beams from the screen as support for the second story of
the carriage house and the garage.) They now live in both Florida and Vermont.
Preface
Economics is about ideas, not models. The goal of this a­ rchitectural blueprints to hold the building blocks to-
text is to convey to students the ideas that make up mod- gether. That mortar and those blueprints are embedded in
ern economics. The ideas are both about the way the the text’s narrative. Unfortunately, mortar and ­blueprints
economy works, and about how to design policy to make don’t fit nicely into building block modules captured by
the economy work better. learning objectives. Mortar and blueprints require con-
ceptualization that goes beyond the standard models—
How This Book Differs conceptualization that brings the big picture into focus.
And, because there are a variety of architectural blue-
from Others prints, there is not a single, but a variety of, big pictures;
Ideas are nuanced; models are not. From its beginning, this models highlight only one of those blueprints.
book has provided a nuanced narrative that emphasizes The study of such issues is the grist for “big think”
both ideas and models. Its distinctive features have been economics that characterizes this book where nuance is
its conversational style and its inclusion of different views integrated into understanding, and students see the im-
within mainstream economics. It doesn’t offer a cookie cut- portance of mortar. Consideration of such issues often
ter presentation of material, but instead offers a blend of goes under the heading of critical thought. To learn to
logical model building and nuanced discussion of applying think critically students have to be presented with some
the models. The writing style is conversational, designed to questions without definitive answers, but ones upon
allow the student to feel a connection with me—the which, when addressed creatively, economic models can
writer—to make it clear that I am a human being, not a ma- shed light. My book contains lots of such questions.
chine. This approach is particularly welcomed as students My approach to models follows the approach Alfred
spend more and more time learning material online. Marshall used back when he first introduced the supply/
Even while spending a lot of time online, students seek demand model into the principles course. Marshall em-
personal connections. It still makes my day when students phasized that economics was an approach to problems,
whom I’ve never met in person write me thanking me for not a body of confirmed truths. In my view, the modeling
making the course fun and for relating to them. I’m delighted method, not the models, is the most important element of
with the reception this book has received, and the loyal an economic understanding. In my presentation of mod-
­following who have used, and continue to use, the book. els, I carefully try to guide students in the modeling
While the book is consciously mainstream, it differs from method, rather than having them memorize truths from
most other top books in its tone. It presents economic theory models. I carefully emphasize the limitations of the mod-
more as a changing heuristic than as an unchanging scientific els and the assumptions that underlie them, and am con-
theory. So, while the discussion of the models is the same as stantly urging students to think beyond the models. This
in other books, the discussion of the application of the mod- approach pushes the students a bit harder than the alterna-
els is different. I emphasize the difficulties of applying the tive, but it is, in my view, the best pedagogical approach;
models while most principles books gloss over them. it is the critical thinking approach.
When taking a critical thinking approach two princi-
Nuanced Economics: Teaching ples stand out: (1) Institutions and history are important
More Than Models in policy discussions and (2) good economics is open to
Recent economic pedagogy has shifted away from seeing dealing with various viewpoints. Let me discuss each of
textbooks as a narrative, to seeing them as a compilation these principles briefly.
of models that can be presented in separable building
blocks or modules. This modularization of the teaching of Institutions and History Are Important to
economic principles involves dividing economic knowl- Understand Policy
edge into learning objectives, sub learning objectives, and If you open up Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations, John
sub-sub learning objectives. Stuart Mill’s Principles of Political Economy, or Alfred
This building block approach makes lots of sense as Marshall’s Principles of Economics, you will see eco-
long as one remembers that you also need mortar and nomic analysis placed in historical and institutional
vi
Preface vii

c­ ontext. The modern textbook template moved away from and Sense Collective, a group with whom I’ve worked to
that, and in previous editions, I have tried to return the coordinate their readers (www.dollarsandsense.org/
principles of economics toward that broader template, bookstore.html) with this text. I also often integrate Aus-
presenting models in a historical and institutional context. trian ideas into my class; I find that The Free Market
This edition continues that emphasis on institutions and (www.mises.org) is a provocative resource.
history. Modern work in game theory and strategic deci- I often pair an article in The Free Market with one in
sion making is making it clear that the implications of Dollars and Sense in my assignments to students for sup-
economic reasoning depend on the institutional setting. plementary reading. Having students read both Radical
To understand economics requires an understanding of and Austrian views, and then integrate those views into
existing institutions and the historical development of more middle-of-the-road views is, for me, a perfect way
those institutions. In a principles course we don’t have to teach the principles course. (If I have a lot of radicals
time to present much about history and institutions, and libertarians in the class, I assign them articles that
but that does not preclude us from letting students know advocate more middle-of-the-road views.)
that these issues are important. And that’s what I try to do.
When I say that institutions and history are important, Integrating Nuance into the
I am talking especially about economic policy. This text
and the accompanying supplements are not ­designed for
Learning Platform
future economics majors. Most principles students aren’t Changes in technology are changing the medium through
going to go on in economics. I write for students who will which ideas are conveyed and the way students learn. Stu-
probably take only one or two economics courses in their dents today don’t know a time without the Internet and
lifetime. These students are interested in policy, and what social media, which provide them with access to a broad
I try to present to them is modern economic reasoning range of digital resources and instant feedback. Technol-
relevant to policy questions. ogy has changed the way they learn, and if we are to reach
Because I think policy is so important in explaining them, we have to present material in ways that fit their
how to apply economic reasoning, I utilize a distinction learning style. They want to be able to access their
made by J. N. Keynes (John Maynard Keynes’ father) and courses anywhere, anytime—at a coffee shop in the after-
Classical economists generally. That distinction is be- noon, in their dorm room late at night, or at lunch hour at
tween theorems—the deductive conclusions of models— work. They still want material that speaks to them, but it
and precepts—the considered judgments of economists has to speak to them in their language at the time they
about the policy implications of the models. I make it want to listen. Modern learning is blended learning in
clear to students that models do not tell us what to do which online presentations, review, testing of material,
about policy—they give us theorems. Only when we and feedback are seamlessly blended with the narrative of
combine the models’ results with our understanding of the text. This revision is designed to improve what the
institutions, our understanding of the social context, and publisher calls the learning platform in both the content
our understanding of the normative goals we want to presented and in the delivery of that content.
achieve, can we arrive at policy conclusions embodied in I think of this book as consisting of both the text and
precepts. the delivery system for the text. For the book to succeed,
the online delivery system has to deliver the material to
Openness to Various Views students in a manner that they can access both online and
While I present modern economics, I present it in such a in the physical book. The new reality of accessing books
way that is open to many different points of view. I don’t online has driven important changes in the last edition,
present the material as “the truth” but simply as the con- and in this edition. Specifically, while the content and
ventional wisdom. Learning conventional wisdom is a pedagogical approach described above remain largely the
useful hurdle for all students to jump over. To encourage same, the delivery is different.
students to question conventional wisdom, at the end of In the last two editions the learning platform was re-
each chapter I include a set of questions—Questions from fined, and all of the content, including end-of-chapter
Alternative Perspectives—written by economists from a questions, was made to line up directly with learning
variety of different perspectives. These include Post- ­objectives. These learning objectives serve as the organi-
Keynesian, Feminist, Austrian, Radical, Institutionalist, zational structure for the material. The learning objectives
and Religious perspectives. Each is described further in themselves were broken down into further learning objec-
the “Distinguishing Features” section that follows the tives associated with concepts that are presented in bite-
preface. The Radical questions come from the Dollars sized portions of the text as part of the SmartBook offer.
viii Preface

This now allows students the opportunity to master con- n­ uance its own general learning objective—a learning
cepts that support the larger picture no matter how they objective that relates to the entire book. So in addition to
access it in the Colander learning platform. Within the learning objectives specific to individual chapters,
­McGraw-Hill’s Connect and SmartBook platforms, stu- there is a general learning objective that is relevant to all
dents can learn the core building blocks online with in- chapters. The general learning objective—the mortar
stant feedback; instructors can assess student learning data that holds the building blocks together—is: Know that to
and know what their students understand, and what they relate models to the real world, you need to use a nuanced
don’t. With that information, they can devote class time to approach.
those issues with which students are having problems. For professors who want to include this learning ob-
In the previous two editions, the end-of-chapter ma- jective in their course, I have written a prologue to the
terial was also restructured for online delivery: All of student found on pages P-1 to P-5, just before Chapter 1.
the standard questions and problems were made auto- In it I discuss the need for context and nuance in applying
gradable and integrated with the online experience. the models, and introduce students to two methodological
Such integration allows students to move seamlessly tools that philosophers use to move from models to policy
between homework problems and portions of the narra- positions. This prologue, what you might think of as
tive to get the information they need, when they need it. ­Chapter 0, serves as the mortar and blueprint to guide stu-
This is a significant advance in pedagogy. Now, even dents in thinking critically about the models and their
professors in large lecture classes can assign questions ­application. This short prologue, which can be assigned
and exercises at the end of chapters and provide feed- along with Chapter 1, presents a general discussion of the
back to students at the point of need. problem of context and nuance and introduces the general
While the new learning platforms made the teaching learning objective.
of the building blocks easier, they presented a challenge Students are reminded of this general learning objec-
for my approach that emphasized the nuance of interpre- tive throughout the book in chapter discussions of nu-
tation as a key element of what students were to learn. anced issues, which are highlighted in SmartBook and
That discussion of nuance was scattered throughout the probes that focus on nuance. I also provide professors
text; it wasn’t a building block to be learned in one place. with some guidance and suggestions on how to integrate
Rather it was mortar to be learned over the course of the a discussion of values and ethics into the course, along
entire semester. This learning goal did not come through with a list of Connect questions and material in SmartBook
in the learning platform as strongly as it did in the text it- that deal with integrating values into the analysis. These
self. While the modular learning platform worked well in are to be found in the Instructor’s website for the book. For
teaching a building block approach to models, it didn’t those who want to emphasize critical thought and nuance
work so well helping students understand the context of in the course, it is much easier to do so than before.
the models. It provided the building blocks but not the
mortar. So the previous versions of my online learning
platforms emphasized models a bit more than I would Specific Content Changes
have liked and context a bit less.
The nuance material was still there, but it was not in-
to This Edition
tegrated into the learning platform as much as I thought it Any new edition provides the possibility to update dis-
should be. In previous editions, I did what I could to ac- cussions and I have done so throughout the book, both in
count for that. Specifically I added aspects of the book updating references to events, and in examples. On a
that allowed professors who wanted to emphasize nuance mundane level I changed examples and products being
to do so. These included two sets of end-of-chapter ques- discussed. For example, there was an earlier discussion of
tions, Issues to Ponder and Questions from Alternative the supply and demand for CDs, which at one point in the
Perspectives, which have no “correct” answer, but instead past seemed reasonable. CDs have gone the way of buggy
are designed to get the students to think. In a learning whips, and so the discussion was changed to chocolate,
environment that blends both online and in-person expe- which has a longer shelf life—there will always be
riences, these are the questions that can form the basis for ­demand for 80 percent dark chocolate, at least from me.
rich classroom discussions that engage the students with I also reviewed all the boxes, eliminating or updat-
broad issues as much as the online material engages them ing those that were outdated, replacing them with new
with the building blocks. boxes that capture some of the new ideas being dis-
In this edition I go a step further in integrating nuance cussed. For example, in Chapter 3 I added a box on
into the course. Specifically, I have essentially made polycentric ­g overnment and the ideas of economist
Preface ix

­ linor Ostrom, and in Chapter 8W I updated the discus-


E e­ leventh edition reviewers, whose insightful comments
sion of the farm program. kept me on track. Reviewers include:
I did the same with discussions in the text, adding up-
dates where needed. That led to substantial changes in Catherine M. Chambers Benjamin Leyden
some chapters. For example, President Trump’s changing University of Central University of Virginia
the narrative on trade meant some significant changes in Missouri Victoria Miller
Chapter 10 on trade were needed. I replaced the opening Frankie P. Albritton Jr. Akin Technical College
discussion of trade to include Trump’s criticism of Seminole State College ABM E. Nasir
free trade agreements and updated the discussion of WTO Paul Chambers North Carolina Central
trade negotiations and U.S. trade policy to account for the University of Central University
Trump presidency. The growing importance of platform Missouri Christina Ann Robinson
monopolies and network externalities led to substantial B. Andrew Chupp Central Connecticut
changes in Chapter 14 and the discussion of antitrust pol- Georgia Institute of State University
icy in Chapter 15. Chapter 17 on labor also was modified Technology
to account for developments in the information revolu- William Shambora
tion. I also added discussions of artificial intelligence and Diane Cunningham Ohio University
deep learning in both the micro and macro chapters. Los Angeles Valley College Mark Griffin Smith
These developments will likely have significant implica- Gregory E. DeFreitas Colorado College
tions for the economy in the coming decade, as AI and Hofstra University Don Uy-Barreta
deep learning do to mental labor what the Industrial John P. Finnigan De Anza College
­Revolution did to physical labor. Marist College Kenneth Woodward
Finally, there were a number of changes to allow the Bernhard Georg Gunter Saddleback College
introduction of nuanced understanding as a separate American University
learning objective. I added a discussion of Adam Smith’s
impartial spectator tool, and how in assessing policy, one In addition to the comments of the formal reviewers
must go beyond how it will benefit oneself, and concen- listed above, I have received helpful suggestions, encour-
trate on how it can be judged from society’s point of view. agement, and assistance from innumerable individuals
I encourage students to discuss contentious policy issues via e-mails, letters, symposia, and focus groups. Their
with others who approach the issues differently as a way help made this edition even stronger than its predecessor.
of advancing the discussion. They include James Wetzel, Virginia Commonwealth
University; Dmitry Shishkin, Georgia State University;
Enjoy! Amy Cramer, Pima Community College–West; Andrea
Terzi, Franklin College; Shelby Frost, Georgia State Uni-
In summary, this book differs from others in its distinc- versity; Doris Geide-Stevenson, Weber State University;
tive blend of nuance and no-nonsense modeling. Working James Chasey, Advanced Placement Economics Teaching
with models doesn’t involve nuance; it involves knowing Consultant and Homewood-Flossmoor High School
the models and their assumptions—questions about (ret.); David Tufte, Southern Utah University; Eric
models are right or wrong—and nuanced discussion of ­Sarpong, Georgia State University; Jim Ciecka, DePaul
applying the models where there are inevitably gray areas University; Fran Bradley, George School; Ron Olive,
where critical thought is needed. Seeing students navigate University of Massachusetts–Lowell; Rachel Kreier,
this gray area and arrive at a nuanced understanding of Hofstra University; Kenneth Elzinga, University of
­
economic principles gives me enormous joy. I hope it ­Virginia; Ben Leyden, University of Virginia; Poul Thøis
does for you as well. Madse, Danmarks Medie—OG Journalistehojskole; Rich
Tarmey, Colorado Mountain College; Michael Mandelberg,
People to Thank Stuart Webber, Trinity Lutheran College; Bob Rogers,
Let me conclude this preface by thanking the hundreds of Ashland University; Zackery Hansen, Southern Utah
people who have offered suggestions, comments, kudos, University; and Matt Gaffney, Missouri State University.
and criticism on this project since its inception. This book I want to give a special thank-you to the supplement
would not be what it is without their input. So many peo- authors and subject matter experts including Jennifer
ple have contributed to this text in so many ways that I Rester Savoie, Pearl River Community College; Susan
cannot thank everyone. So, to all the people who helped— Bell, Seminole State University; Per Norander, University
many, many thanks. I specifically want to thank the of North Carolina at Charlotte; Frankie P. Albritton Jr.,
x Preface

Seminole State University; and Kenneth Woodward, by providing research, critiquing expositions and often
­Saddleback College. They all did an outstanding job. improving them, and being a good friend. She has an
I’d also like to thank the economists who wrote the amazing set of skills, and I thank her for using them
alternative perspective questions. These include Ann to improve the book. The second is Christina Kouvelis,
Mari May of the University of Nebraska–Lincoln, John senior product developer, who came into this project and
Miller of Wheaton College, Dan Underwood of P ­ eninsula with her hard work, dedication, and superb ability made it
College, Ric Holt of Southern Oregon University, and possible to get the book done on time. She and Jenifer are
Bridget Butkevich of George Mason University. I en- two amazing women.
joyed working with each of them, and while their views Next, I want to thank the entire McGraw-Hill team,
often differed substantially, they were all united in want- including Terri Schiesl, managing director; Anke Weekes,
ing questions that showed economics as a pluralist field director; Christine Vaughan, lead content project man-
that encourages students to question the text from all ager; Bruce Gin, senior assessment project manager; Egzon
­perspectives. Shaqiri, designer; Bobby Pearson, marketing manager; Julia
I have hired numerous students to check aspects of the ­Blankenship, marketing specialist; and Doug Ruby, director
book, to read over my questions and answers to questions, of digital content. All of them have done a superb job, for
and to help proofread. For this edition, these include Reid which I thank them sincerely.
Smith, Amelia Pollard and Zhewei Yang. I thank them all. Finally, I want to thank Pat, my wife, and my sons,
A special thank-you for this edition goes to two peo- Kasey and Zach, for helping me keep my work in per-
ple. The first is Jenifer Gamber, whose role in the book spective, and for providing a loving environment in which
cannot be overestimated. She helped me clarify its vision to work.
Distinguishing
Features
Margin Comments Austrian Economists
Austrian economists believe in methodological individu-
Located throughout the text in the margin, these key take- alism, by which they mean that social goals are best met
aways underscore and summarize the importance of the through voluntary, mutually beneficial interactions. Lack
material, at the same time helping students focus on the of information and unsolvable incentive problems under-
most relevant topics critical to their understanding. mine the ability of government to plan, making the mar-
ket the best method for coordinating economic activity.
Margin Questions Austrian economists oppose state intrusion into private
property and private activities. They are not economists
These self-test questions are presented in the margin of from Austria; rather, they are economists from anywhere
the chapter to enable students to determine whether the who follow the ideas of Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich
preceding material has been understood and to reinforce Hayek, two economists who were from Austria.
understanding before students read further. Answers to Austrian economists are sometimes classified as con-
Margin Questions are found at the end of each chapter. servative, but they are more appropriately classified as
libertarians, who believe in liberty of individuals first and
Web Notes in other social goals second. Consistent with their views,
they are often willing to support what are sometimes con-
This feature extends the text discussion onto the web.
sidered radical ideas, such as legalizing addictive drugs
Web Notes are denoted within the margins, and are
or eliminating our current monetary system—ideas that
housed within Connect and featured in SmartBook.
most mainstream economists would oppose. Austrian
economists emphasize the uncertainty in the economy and
Nuance Prologue and Questions the inability of a government controlled by self-­interested
Nuanced aspects of economics are presented throughout politicians to undertake socially beneficial policy.
the book, and in a Prologue for the Student. In SmartBook,
nuance questions have been added that directly relate to Institutionalist Economists
applying the models and the problems of integrating values Institutionalist economists argue that any economic analy-
into the analysis. A guide to these questions can be found sis must involve specific considerations of institutions. The
on the Instructor Resource website. lineage of Institutionalist economics begins with the pio-
neering work of Thorstein Veblen, John R. Commons, and
Issues to Ponder Wesley C. Mitchell. Veblen employed evolutionary analy-
sis to explore the role of institutions in directing and retard-
Each chapter ends with a set of Issues to Ponder questions ing the economic process. He saw human behavior driven
that are designed to encourage additional economic think- by cultural norms and conveyed the way in which they
ing and application. were with sardonic wit and penetrating insight, leaving us
with enduring metaphors such as the leisure class and con-
Questions from Alternative spicuous consumption. Commons argued that institutions
are social constructs that improve general welfare. Accord-
Perspectives ingly, he established cooperative investigative programs to
The end-of-chapter material includes a number of ques- support pragmatic changes in the legal structure of govern-
tions that ask students to assess economics from alterna- ment. Mitchell was a leader in developing economics as an
tive perspectives. Specifically, six different approaches empirical study; he was a keen observer of the business
are highlighted: Austrian, Post-Keynesian, Institutional- cycle and argued that theory must be informed by system-
ist, Radical, Feminist, and Religious. Below are brief atic attention to empirical data, or it was useless.
­descriptions of each group. Contemporary Institutionalists employ the founders’
“trilogy”—empirically informed, evolutionary analysis,
xi
xii Preface

directed toward pragmatic alteration of institutions shap- economics to include women as practitioners and as
ing economic outcomes—in their policy approach. ­worthy of study and for the elimination of the masculine
bias in mainstream economics. Is there such a bias? To
Radical Economists see it, simply compare the relative number of women in
Radical economists believe substantial equality-preferring your economics class to the relative number of women at
institutional changes should be implemented in our your school. It is highly likely that your class has relatively
­economic system. Radical economists evolved out of more men. Feminist economists want you to ask why that
Marxian economics. In their analysis, they focus on the is, and whether anything should be done about it.
lack of equity in our current economic system and on in-
stitutional changes that might bring about a more equita- Religious Economists
ble system. Specifically, they see the current economic Religion is the oldest and, arguably, the most influential
system as one in which a few people—capitalists and institution in the world—be it Christianity, Islam, Juda-
high-level managers—benefit enormously at the expense ism, Buddhism, Hinduism, or any of the many other reli-
of many people who struggle to make ends meet in jobs gions in the world. Modern science, of which economics
that are unfulfilling or who even go without work at is a part, emphasizes the rational elements of thought. It
times. They see the fundamental instability and irratio- attempts to separate faith and normative issues from ra-
nality of the capitalist system at the root of a wide array tional analysis in ways that some religiously oriented
of social ills that range from pervasive inequality to alien- economists find questionable. The line between a reli-
ation, racism, sexism, and imperialism. Radical econo- gious and nonreligious economist is not hard and fast; all
mists often use a class-oriented analysis to address these economists bring elements of their ethical considerations
issues and are much more willing to talk about social into their analysis. But those we call “religious econo-
conflict and tensions in our society than are mainstream mists” integrate the ethical and normative issues into eco-
economists. nomic analysis in more complex ways than the ways
A policy favored by many Radicals is the establish- presented in the text.
ment of worker cooperatives to replace the corporation. Religiously oriented economists have a diversity of
Radicals argue that such worker cooperatives would see views; some believe that their views can be integrated
that the income of the firm is more equitably allocated. reasonably well into standard economics, while others
Likewise, Radical economists endorse policies, such as see the need for the development of a distinctive faith-
universal health care insurance, that conform to the ethic based methodology that focuses on a particular group of
of “putting people before profits.” normative concerns centered on issues such as human
dignity and caring for the poor.
Feminist Economists
Feminist economics offers a substantive challenge to the Post-Keynesian Economists
content, scope, and methodology of mainstream econom- Post-Keynesian economists believe that uncertainty is a
ics. Feminist economists question the boundaries of what central issue in economics. They follow J. M. Keynes’ ap-
we consider economics to be and examine social arrange- proach more so than do mainstream economists in em-
ments surrounding provisioning. Feminist economists phasizing institutional imperfections in the economy and
have many different views, but all believe that in some the importance of fundamental uncertainty that rational-
way traditional economic analysis misses many important ity cannot deal with. They agree with Institutionalists that
issues pertaining to women. the study of economics must emphasize and incorporate
Feminist economists study issues such as how the in- the importance of social and political structure in deter-
stitutional structure tends to direct women into certain mining market outcomes.
types of jobs (generally low-paying jobs) and away from While their view about the importance of uncertainty
other types of jobs (generally high-paying jobs). They is similar to the Austrian view, their policy response to
draw our attention to the unpaid labor performed by that uncertainty is quite different. They do not see uncer-
women throughout the world and ask, “What would GDP tainty as eliminating much of government’s role in the
look like if women’s work were given a value and economy; instead, they see it leading to policies in which
­included?” They argue for an expansion in the content of government takes a larger role in guiding the economy.
Supplements

McGraw-Hill has established a strong history of top-rate a­ ssessment. They are also included as extra assessment
supplements to accompany this text, and this eleventh content available within Connect.
edition strives to carry on the tradition of excellence. The
following ancillaries are available for quick download Assurance of Learning Ready
and convenient access via the Instructor Resource mate- Many educational institutions today are focused on the
rial available through McGraw-Hill Connect®. notion of assurance of learning, an important element of
Solutions Manual some accreditation standards. Microeconomics, 11/e is
designed specifically to support your assurance of learning
Prepared by Jenifer Gamber and me, this manual provides initiatives with a simple yet powerful solution.
answers to all end-of-chapter questions—the Questions Instructors can use Connect to easily query for
and Exercises, Questions from Alternative Perspectives, ­learning outcomes/objectives that directly relate to the
and Issues to Ponder. learning objectives of the course. You can then use the
Test Banks reporting features of Connect to aggregate student results
in similar fashion, making the collection and presentation
The test bank contains more than 5,600 quality multiple of assurance of learning data simple and easy.
choice and true-false questions for instructors to draw from
in their classrooms. Jenifer Gamber and I have worked AACSB Statement
diligently to make sure that the questions are clear and McGraw-Hill Global Education is a proud corporate
useful. Each question is categorized by learning objective, member of AACSB International. Understanding the im-
level of difficulty, economic concept, AACSB learning portance and value of AACSB accreditation, the author
categories, and Bloom’s Taxonomy objectives. Questions of Microeconomics, 11/e has sought to recognize the cur-
were reviewed by professors and students alike to ensure ricula guidelines detailed in the AACSB standards for
that each one was effective for classroom use. All of the test business accreditation by connecting questions in the test
bank content is available for assigning within Connect. bank and end-of-chapter material to the general knowl-
A computerized test bank is available via TestGen, a edge and skill guidelines found in the AACSB standards.
complete, state-of-the-art test generator and editing applica- It is important to note that the statements contained in
tion software that allows instructors to quickly and easily Microeconomics, 11/e are provided only as a guide for the
select test items. Instructors can then organize, edit, and cus- users of this text. The AACSB leaves content coverage and
tomize questions and answers to rapidly generate tests for assessment within the purview of individual schools, the
paper or online administration. With both quick-and-simple mission of the school, and the faculty. While Microeconomics,
test creation and flexible and robust editing tools, TestGen 11/e and the teaching package make no claim of any
is a complete test generator system for today’s educators. specific AACSB qualification or evaluation, we have
An essay-only test bank, organized by chapter, will be within Microeconomics, 11/e labeled selected questions
available via the Instructor Resource material available according to the general knowledge and skills areas.
within Connect.
McGraw-Hill Customer Care
PowerPoint Presentations Contact Information
Jennifer Rester Savoie of Pearl River Community College At McGraw-Hill, we understand that getting the most from
worked tirelessly to revise the PowerPoint slide program, new technology can be challenging. That’s why our services
animating graphs and emphasizing important concepts. don’t stop after you purchase our products. You can e-mail
Each chapter has been scrutinized to ensure an accurate, our Product Specialists 24 hours a day to get product training
direct connection to the text. online. Or you can search our knowledge bank of Frequently
Asked Questions on our support website. For Customer
Problem Sets Support, call 800-331-5094 or visit www.mhhe.com/
Additional problem sets accompany each chapter, which support. One of our Technical Support Analysts will be
can be assigned to students either for practice or able to assist you in a timely fashion. xiii
Students—study more efficiently, retain more
and achieve better outcomes. Instructors—focus
on what you love—teaching.

SUCCESSFUL SEMESTERS INCLUDE CONNECT

For Instructors
You’re in the driver’s seat.
Want to build your own course? No problem. Prefer to use our turnkey,
prebuilt course? Easy. Want to make changes throughout the semester?
65%
Less Time
Sure. And you’ll save time with Connect’s auto-grading too.
Grading

They’ll thank you for it.


Adaptive study resources like SmartBook® help your
students be better prepared in less time. You can
transform your class time from dull definitions to dynamic
debates. Hear from your peers about the benefits of
Connect at www.mheducation.com/highered/connect

Make it simple, make it affordable.


Connect makes it easy with seamless integration using any of the
major Learning Management Systems—Blackboard®, Canvas,
and D2L, among others—to let you organize your course in one
convenient location. Give your students access to digital materials
at a discount with our inclusive access program. Ask your
McGraw-Hill representative for more information.
©Hill Street Studios/Tobin Rogers/Blend Images LLC

Solutions for your challenges.


A product isn’t a solution. Real solutions are affordable,
reliable, and come with training and ongoing support when
you need it and how you want it. Our Customer Experience
Group can also help you troubleshoot tech problems—
although Connect’s 99% uptime means you might not need
to call them. See for yourself at status.mheducation.com
For Students
Effective, efficient studying.
Connect helps you be more productive with your
study time and get better grades using tools like
SmartBook, which highlights key concepts and creates
a personalized study plan. Connect sets you up for
success, so you walk into class with confidence and
walk out with better grades.
©Shutterstock/wavebreakmedia

“ I really liked this app it


made it easy to study when

Study anytime, anywhere.
Download the free ReadAnywhere app and access your
you don’t have your text-

online eBook when it’s convenient, even if you’re offline.
book in front of you. And since the app automatically syncs with your eBook in
Connect, all of your notes are available every time you open
— Jordan Cunningham, it. Find out more at www.mheducation.com/readanywhere
Eastern Washington University

No surprises.
The Connect Calendar and Reports tools
keep you on track with the work you need 13 14
to get done and your assignment scores.
Life gets busy; Connect tools help you
keep learning through it all. Chapter 12 Quiz Chapter 11 Quiz
Chapter 13 Evidence of Evolution Chapter 11 DNA Technology

Chapter 7 Quiz
Chapter 7 DNA Structure and Gene...
and 7 more...

Learning for everyone.


McGraw-Hill works directly with Accessibility Services
Departments and faculty to meet the learning needs of all
students. Please contact your Accessibility Services office
and ask them to email accessibility@mheducation.com, or
visit www.mheducation.com/about/accessibility.html for
more information.
Brief
Contents

part I I NTRODUCTION: THINKING


 MARKET STRUCTURE
13
Perfect Competition 272
LIKE AN ECONOMIST 14
Monopoly and Monopolistic Competition 293
11 Economics and Economic Reasoning 4 Appendix: The Algebra of Competitive and
2 The Production Possibility Model, Trade, and Monopolistic Firms 319
Globalization 25 15
Oligopoly and Antitrust Policy 321
Appendix: Graphish: The Language of Graphs 44 16
Real-World Competition and Technology 340
3 Economic Institutions 53
Appendix: The History of Economic Systems 73 FACTOR MARKETS
4 Supply and Demand 78 17
Work and the Labor Market 359
5 Using Supply and Demand 101 Appendix: Derived Demand 383
Appendix: Algebraic Representation of Supply, 17W Nonwage and Asset Income: Rents, Profits, and
Demand, and Equilibrium 117 Interest 389
18
Who Gets What? The ­Distribution of Income 390
part II MICROECONOMICS
CHOICE AND DECISION MAKING
THE POWER OF TRADITIONAL 19
The Logic of Individual Choice:
ECONOMIC MODELS The Foundation of Supply and Demand 416
6 Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities 124 Appendix: Indifference Curve Analysis 436
7 Taxation and Government Intervention 144 20
Game Theory, Strategic ­Decision Making, and
8 Market Failure versus ­Government Failure 165 ­Behavioral Economics 441
8W Politics and Economics: The Case of Agricultural Appendix: Game Theory and Oligopoly 462
Markets 187
MODERN ECONOMIC THINKING
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC 21
Thinking Like a Modern ­Economist 466
POLICY ISSUES 22
Behavioral Economics and Modern Economic
Policy 492
9 Comparative Advantage, Exchange Rates,
and Globalization 188
23
Microeconomic Policy, ­Economic Reasoning,
and Beyond 511
10
International Trade Policy 207

PRODUCTION AND COST ANALYSIS


11 Production and Cost Analysis I 229
12 Production and Cost Analysis II 249
Appendix: Isocost/Isoquant Analysis 267

xvi
Contents
Trade and Comparative Advantage 32
PART I
Markets, Specialization, and Growth 33
The Benefits of Trade 34
INTRODUCTION:
Globalization and the Law of One Price 36
THINKING LIKE Globalization 36
AN ECONOMIST Exchange Rates and Comparative Advantage 38
The Law of One Price 38
Globalization and the Timing of Benefits of Trade 39
11 Economics and Economic Reasoning 4
Conclusion 39
What Economics Is 5
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Scarcity 5
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Microeconomics and Macroeconomics 6
Margin Questions 40–43
A Guide to Economic Reasoning 6
Appendix: Graphish: The Language of Graphs 44
Marginal Costs and Marginal Benefits 8
The Economic Decision Rule 8
Economics and Passion 8 3 Economic Institutions 53
Opportunity Cost 9
Economic Systems 54
Economic Forces, Social Forces, and Political Forces 11
How Markets Work 54
Economic and Market Forces 11
What’s Good about the Market? 55
Social and Political Forces 11
Capitalism and Socialism 55
Using Economic Insights 13
Economic Institutions in a Market Economy 58
The Invisible Hand Theorem 14
Business 59
Economic Theory and Stories 15
Households 61
Economic Institutions 15
The Roles of Government 62
Economic Policy Options 16
Government as an Actor 62
Objective Policy Analysis 17
Government as a Referee 64
Policy and Social and Political Forces 20
Specific Roles for Government 65
Conclusion 20 Market Failures and Government Failures 67
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Global Institutions 68
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to Global Corporations 68
Margin Questions 21–24 Coordinating Global Issues 68
Conclusion 69
2 The Production Possibility Model, Trade, Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
and Globalization 25 from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 69–72
The Production Possibility Model 26
Appendix: The History of Economic Systems 73
A Production Possibility Curve for an Individual 26
Increasing Opportunity Costs of the Trade-Off 27
Comparative Advantage 28 4 Supply and Demand 78
Efficiency 29
Demand 78
Distribution and Productive Efficiency 30
The Law of Demand 79
Examples of Shifts in the PPC 31
The Demand Curve 79

xvii
xviii Contents

Shifts in Demand versus Movements


PART II
along a Demand Curve 80
Some Shift Factors of Demand 81
The Demand Table 82
MICROECONOMICS
From a Demand Table to a Demand Curve 82
Individual and Market Demand Curves 83 THE POWER OF TRADITIONAL
Supply 85 ECONOMIC MODELS
The Law of Supply 85
The Supply Curve 86
Shifts in Supply versus Movements along a Supply
6 Describing Supply and Demand:
Curve 87 Elasticities 124
Shift Factors of Supply 88 Price Elasticity 124
The Supply Table 88 What Information Price Elasticity Provides 125
From a Supply Table to a Supply Curve 88 Classifying Demand and Supply as Elastic
Individual and Market Supply Curves 88 or Inelastic 125
The Interaction of Supply and Demand 89 Elasticity Is Independent of Units 126
Equilibrium 90 Calculating Elasticities 126
The Graphical Interaction of Supply and Demand 91 Other Examples 128
What Equilibrium Isn’t 91 Elasticity Is Not the Same as Slope 128
Political and Social Forces and Equilibrium 92 Five Terms to Describe Elasticity 130
Shifts in Supply and Demand 93 Substitution and Elasticity 130
A Limitation of Supply/Demand Analysis 95 Substitution and Demand 131
Conclusion 95 How Substitution Factors Affect Specific
Decisions 132
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises,
Questions from Alternative Perspectives, Elasticity, Total Revenue, and Demand 133
Issues to Ponder, Answers to Total Revenue along a Demand Curve 134
Margin Questions 96–100 Income and Cross-Price Elasticity 135
Income Elasticity of Demand 135
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand 136
5 Using Supply and Demand 101 Some Examples 137
Real-World Supply and Demand The Power of Supply/Demand Analysis 138
Applications 101 When Should a Supplier Not Raise Price? 138
Government Intervention: Price Ceilings Elasticity and Shifting Supply and Demand 139
and Price Floors 104 Conclusion 139
Price Ceilings 105 Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Price Floors 106 from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Government Intervention: Excise Taxes Margin Questions 140–143
and Tariffs 108
Government Intervention: Quantity 7 Taxation and Government
Restrictions 109 Intervention 144
Third-Party-Payer Markets 111
Producer and Consumer Surplus 144
Conclusion 112
Burden of Taxation 146
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Who Bears the Burden of a Tax? 148
Questions from Alternative Perspectives, Tax Incidence and Current Policy Debates 151
Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Government Intervention as Implicit Taxation 152
Margin Questions 112–116
Price Ceilings and Floors 152
Appendix: Algebraic Representation of Supply, Demand, The Difference between Taxes and Price
and Equilibrium 117 Controls 153
Contents xix

Rent Seeking, Politics, and Elasticities 154 Economics, Politics, and Real-World Policies 8W-10
Inelastic Demand and Incentives to Restrict Supply 154 Interest Groups 8W-11
Inelastic Supplies and Incentives to Restrict Prices 157 International Issues 8W-12
The Long-Run/Short-Run Problem of Price Conclusion 8W-12
Controls 158
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Conclusion 160 from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Margin Questions 8W-13–8W-16
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 160–164

8 Market Failure versus ­Government INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY


Failure 165 ISSUES
Externalities 166
Effects of Positive and Negative Externalities 167
9 Comparative Advantage, Exchange
Alternative Methods of Dealing with
Externalities 168 Rates, and Globalization 188
Direct Regulation 169 The Principle of Comparative Advantage 188
Incentive Policies 170 The Gains from Trade 189
Voluntary Reductions 171 Dividing Up the Gains from Trade 190
The Optimal Policy 172 Why Economists and Laypeople Differ in Their Views
Public Goods 172 of Trade 192
The Market Value of a Public Good 173 Gains Are Often Stealth 192
Excludability and the Costs of Pricing 175 Opportunity Cost Is Relative 192
Informational and Moral Hazard Problems 176 Trade Is Broader Than Manufactured Goods 192
Signaling and Screening 177 Trade Has Distributional Effects 193
Policies to Deal with Informational Problems 177 Sources of U.S. Comparative Advantage 194
Government Failure and Market Failures 180 Some Concerns about the Future 196
Inherent and Transferable Sources of
Conclusion 182
Comparative Advantages 196
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions The Law of One Price 196
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to How the United States Gained and Is Now Losing
Margin Questions 182–186 Sources of Comparative Advantage 197
Methods of Equalizing Trade Balances 197
8W Politics and Economics: The Case of Determination of Exchange Rates and Trade 198
Exchange Rates and Trade 200
Agricultural Markets 187 and 8W-1
Some Complications in Exchange Rates 201
The Good/Bad Paradox in Agriculture 8W-3 Conclusion 202
The Long-Run Decline of Farming 8W-3
The Short-Run Cyclical Problem Facing Farmers 8W-4 Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
The Difficulty of Coordinating Farm Production 8W-4 from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Ways around the Good/Bad Paradox 8W-4 Margin Questions 202–206
The General Rule of Political Economy 8W-5
Four Price Support Options 8W-5
Supporting the Price by Regulatory Measures 8W-6
10 International Trade Policy 207
Providing Economic Incentives to Reduce Supply 8W-8 The Nature and Patterns of Trade 207
Subsidizing the Sale of the Good 8W-9 Increasing but Fluctuating World Trade 207
Buying Up and Storing, Giving Away, or Destroying Differences in the Importance of Trade 208
the Good 8W-9 What and with Whom the United States Trades 208
Which Group Prefers Which Option? 8W-10 Debtor and Creditor Nations 210
xx Contents

Varieties of Trade Restrictions 212


Tariffs and Quotas 212 12 Production and Cost
Voluntary Restraint Agreements 214 Analysis II 249
Sanctions 214 Technical Efficiency and Economic
Regulatory Trade Restrictions 215 Efficiency 250
Nationalistic Appeals and “Buy Domestic”
The Shape of the Long-Run Cost Curve 250
Requirements 215
Economies of Scale 251
Reasons for and against Trade Restrictions 215 Diseconomies of Scale 253
Unequal Internal Distribution of the Gains from Trade 216 Constant Returns to Scale 254
Haggling by Companies over the Gains from Trade 218 The Importance of Economies and
Haggling by Countries over Trade Restrictions 218 Diseconomies of Scale 255
Specialized Production 219 Envelope Relationship 255
Macroeconomic Costs of Trade 220
Entrepreneurial Activity and the
National Security 221
Supply Decision 257
International Politics 221
Increased Revenue Brought In by Tariffs 221 Using Cost Analysis in the Real World 258
Why Economists Generally Oppose Trade Economies of Scope 258
Restrictions 221 Learning by Doing and Technological Change 259
Many Dimensions 262
Institutions Supporting Free Trade 223
Unmeasured Costs 262
Conclusion 225 The Standard Model as a Framework 263
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Conclusion 263
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Margin Questions 225–228
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 264–267
Appendix: Isocost/Isoquant Analysis 267
PRODUCTION AND COST ANALYSIS

11 Production and Cost MARKET STRUCTURE


Analysis I 229
The Role of the Firm 230 13 Perfect Competition 272
Firms Maximize Profit 231
The Difference between Economists’ Profits and Perfect Competition as a Reference Point 272
Accountants’ Profits 232 Conditions for Perfect Competition 273
Demand Curves for the Firm and the Industry 273
The Production Process 233
The Long Run and the Short Run 233 The Profit-Maximizing Level of Output 274
Production Tables and Production Functions 233 Marginal Revenue 274
The Law of Diminishing Marginal Productivity 235 Marginal Cost 275
Profit Maximization: MC = MR 275
The Costs of Production 236
The Marginal Cost Curve Is the Supply Curve 276
Fixed Costs, Variable Costs, and Total Costs 236
Firms Maximize Total Profit 276
Average Costs 237
Marginal Cost 237 Total Profit at the Profit-Maximizing
Level of Output 278
Graphing Cost Curves 238
Determining Profit from a Table of Costs and
Total Cost Curves 239
Revenue 278
Average and Marginal Cost Curves 239
Determining Profit from a Graph 279
Intermission 243 The Shutdown Point 281
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Short-Run Market Supply and Demand 282
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to Long-Run Competitive Equilibrium:
Margin Questions, 244–248 Zero Profit 283
Contents xxi

Adjustment from the Short Run to the Long Run 284 Classifying Industries and Markets in Practice 327
An Increase in Demand 284 The North American Industry Classification
Long-Run Market Supply 285 System 328
An Example in the Real World 286 Empirical Measures of Industry Structure 329
Conclusion 287 Conglomerate Firms and Bigness 330
Oligopoly Models and Empirical Estimates
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
of Market Structure 330
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 288–292 Antitrust Policy 331
Judgment by Performance or Structure? 331
The Role of Antitrust in Today’s Economy 333
14 Monopoly and Monopolistic
Conclusion 335
Competition 293
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
The Key Difference between a Monopolist and a Perfect from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Competitor 293 Margin Questions 336–339
A Model of Monopoly 294
Determining the Monopolist’s Price and Output
Numerically 294 16 Real-World Competition and
Determining Price and Output Graphically 295 Technology 340
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition 297 Competition Is for Losers 341
An Example of Finding Output and Price 297
The Goals of Real-World Firms
Profits and Monopoly 298
and the Monitoring Problem 341
Welfare Loss from Monopoly 300 What Do Real-World Firms Maximize? 344
The Normal Monopolist 300 The Lazy Monopolist and X-Inefficiency 344
The Price-Discriminating Monopolist 301
The Fight between Competitive and Monopolistic
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly 302 Forces 346
Natural Ability 304 How Monopolistic Forces Affect Perfect Competition 347
Natural Monopolies 304 Economic Insights and Real-World Competition 347
Network and Platform Monopolies 306 How Competitive Forces Affect Monopoly 348
Monopolistic Competition 308 Competition: Natural and Platform Monopolies 349
Characteristics of Monopolistic Competition 308 How Firms Protect Their Monopolies 350
Advertising and Monopolistic Competition 309 Cost/Benefit Analysis of Creating and
Output, Price, and Profit of a Monopolistic Maintaining Monopolies 351
Competitor 311 Establishing Market Position 351
Comparing Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition,
Platform Monopolies and Technology 352
and Perfect Competition 312
Standards and Winner-Take-All Industries 352
Conclusion 313 Technological Lock-In 353
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Conclusion 354
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Margin Questions 314–319
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Appendix: The Algebra of Competitive and Monopolistic Margin Questions 354–358
Firms 319

15 Oligopoly and Antitrust Policy 321 FACTOR MARKETS


The Distinguishing Characteristics of Oligopoly 321
Models of Oligopoly Behavior 322
The Cartel Model 322
17 Work and the Labor Market 359
The Contestable Market Model 325 The Supply of Labor 360
Comparison of the Contestable Market Model Real Wages and the Opportunity Cost of Work 361
and the Cartel Model 325 The Supply of Labor and Nonmarket Activities 362
xxii Contents

Income Taxation, Work, and Leisure 362


The Elasticity of the Supply of Labor 363 18 Who Gets What?
Immigration and the International Supply The ­Distribution of Income 390
of Labor 364 Measuring the Distribution of Income,
The Derived Demand for Labor 364 Wealth, and Poverty 391
Factors Influencing the Elasticity of Demand for The Lorenz Curve 391
Labor 365 U.S. Income Distribution over Time 393
Labor as a Factor of Production 365 Defining Poverty 394
Shift Factors of Demand 365 International Dimensions of Income Inequality 397
Determination of Wages 369 The Distribution of Wealth 398
Imperfect Competition and the Labor Market 370 Socioeconomic Dimensions of Income
Political and Social Forces and the Labor Market 371 and Wealth Inequality 400
Fairness and the Labor Market 372 Income Distribution According to
Discrimination and the Labor Market 374 Socioeconomic Characteristics 400
Three Types of Direct Demand-Side Income Distribution According to Class 400
Discrimination 374 Income Distribution and Fairness 403
Institutional Discrimination 376 Philosophical Debates about Equality
The Evolution of Labor Markets 377 and Fairness 403
Evolving Labor Laws 377 Fairness and Equality 403
The Labor Market and You 377 Fairness as Equality of Opportunity 404
Conclusion 378 The Problems of Redistributing Income 405
Three Important Side Effects of Redistributive
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Programs 405
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Politics, Income Redistribution, and Fairness 405
Margin Questions 379–382
Income Redistribution Policies 407
Appendix: Derived Demand 383 How Successful Have Income Redistribution Programs
Been? 410
Conclusion 411
17W Nonwage and Asset Income: Rents, Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
Profits, and Interest 389 and 17W-1 from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Rent 17W-3 Margin Questions 412–415
The Effect of a Tax on Land 17W-3
Quasi Rents 17W-4
Rent Seeking and Institutional Constraints 17W-5 CHOICE AND DECISION MAKING
Profit 17W-6
Profit, Entrepreneurship, and Disequilibrium
Adjustment 17W-6 19 The Logic of Individual Choice:
Market Niches, Profit, and Rent 17W-7 The Foundation of Supply and
Interest 17W-7 Demand 416
The Present Value Formula 17W-8 Rational Choice Theory 417
Some Rules of Thumb for Determining Present Total Utility and Marginal Utility 417
Value 17W-9 Diminishing Marginal Utility 419
The Importance of Present Value 17W-11 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility 419
The Marginal Productivity Theory Maximizing Utility and Equilibrium 422
of Income Distribution 17W-11 An Example of Maximizing Utility 422
Conclusion 17W-12 Extending the Principle of Rational Choice 423
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Rational Choice and the Laws
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to of Demand and Supply 424
Margin Questions 17W-12–17W-14 The Law of Demand 424
Contents xxiii

Income and Substitution Effects 425 MODERN ECONOMIC THINKING


The Law of Supply 426
Opportunity Cost 427
Applying Economists’ Theory of Choice 21 Thinking Like a Modern ­
to the Real World 427 Economist 466
The Cost of Decision Making 427 The Nature of Economists’ Models 467
Given Tastes 428 Scientific and Engineering Models 468
Utility Maximization 430 Behavioral and Traditional Building Blocks 468
Conclusion 431 Behavioral Economic Models 468
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions The Advantages and Disadvantages of Modern Traditional
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to and Behavioral Models 471
Margin Questions 432–435 Behavioral and Traditional Informal
Appendix: Indifference Curve Analysis 436 (Heuristic) Models 473
The Armchair Economist: Heuristic Models
Using Traditional Building Blocks 473
The Economic Naturalist: Heuristic Models
20 Game Theory, Strategic ­Decision Using Behavioral Building Blocks 476
Making, and ­Behavioral Economics 441 The Limits of Heuristic Models 477
Empirical and Formal Models 478
Game Theory and the Economic
The Importance of Empirical Work in Modern
Way of Thinking 442
Economics 478
Game Theory and Economic Modeling 442
The Role of Formal Models 481
The Game Theory Framework 443
The Prisoner’s Dilemma 444 What Difference Does All This Make to Policy? 487
Dominant Strategies and Nash Equilibrium 445 Conclusion 488
An Overview of Game Theory as a Tool Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
in Studying Strategic Interaction 447 from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Some Specific Games 447 Margin Questions 488–491
Strategies of Players 448
Informal Game Theory and Modern
Behavioral Economics 451 22 Behavioral Economics and Modern
Informal Game Theory 452 Economic Policy 492
Real-World Applications of Informal Game Behavioral Economic Policy in Perspective 492
Theory 452 Behavioral Economics and Economic Engineering 493
An Application of Game Theory: Auction Economists as Mechanism Design Engineers 494
Markets 454 Behavioral Economics and Mechanism Design 495
Game Theory and the Challenge to Standard Economic Policy Implications of Traditional Economics 497
Assumptions 455 Choice Architecture and Behavioral
Fairness 455 Economic Policy 497
Endowment Effects 456 Nudge Policy and Libertarian Paternalism 499
Framing Effects 456 When Are Nudges Needed? 499
Behavioral Economics and the Traditional Two Types of Nudges 501
Model 456
The Problems of Implementing Nudges 502
The Importance of the Traditional Model:
Distinguishing a Nudge from a Push 503
Money Is Not Left on the Table 457
Behavioral and Traditional Economic Policy
Conclusion 457 Frames 503
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Concerns about Behavioral Economic Policies 505
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to Few Policies Meet the Libertarian Paternalism
Margin Questions 458–461 Criterion 505
Appendix: Game Theory and Oligopoly 462 Designing Helpful Policies Is Complicated 505
xxiv Contents

It Isn’t Clear Government Knows Better 506 Putting Cost/Benefit Analysis in Perspective 518
Government Policy May Make the Situation Worse 506 The Problem of Other Things Changing 518
A Changing View of Economists: From Pro-market The Cost/Benefit Approach in Context 519
Advocates to Economic Engineers 507 Failure of Market Outcomes 519
Conclusion 507 Distribution 520
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions Consumer Sovereignty and Rationality Problems 521
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to Inalienable Rights 523
Margin Questions 508–510 Government Failure 524
Conclusion 525
23 Microeconomic Policy, ­Economic Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Reasoning, and Beyond 511 Margin Questions 527–530
Economists’ Differing Views about Social Policy 512
How Economists’ Value Judgments Creep into Policy
Proposals 512 Glossary G-1
The Need for a Worldview 514
Agreement among Economists about Social Policy 514
Economists’ Cost/Benefit Approach
to Government Regulation 515 Colloquial Glossary CG
The Value of Life 515
Comparing Costs and Benefits of Different
Dimensions 517 Index I-1
List of
Boxes
The Developing Country’s Perspective on
REAL-WORLD APPLICATION Globalization 37
Winston Churchill and Lady Astor 12 Tradition and Today’s Economy 56
Economists and Market Solutions 16 Our International Competitors 67
Economics and Climate Change 19 The Supply and Demand for Children 94
Made in China? 36 Geometric Tricks for Estimating Price Elasticity 131
What Government Are We Talking About? 64 The Ambiguity of Total Surplus 146
Uber, Lyft, and Taxi Pricing 110 Pareto Optimality and the Perfectly Competitive
Empirically Measuring Elasticities 136 Benchmark 166
Economists and the Debate about the Corporate Common Resources and the Tragedy of the Commons 169
Income Tax 151 Licensure and Surgery 179
The Excess Burden of a Draft 155 International Issues in Perspective 211
Is It Time to Start Paying for Driving on Roads? 173 Dumping 224
Climate Change, Global Warming, and Economic Policy 181 Value Added and the Calculation of Total
Hormones and Economics 216 Production 232
Trump Trade Policy and Antiglobalization Forces 219 A Trick in Graphing the Marginal Revenue Curve 296
Transaction Costs and the Internet 231 Can Price Controls Increase Output and Lower Market
Economies of Scale and 3D Printing 251 Price? 303
Travels of a T-Shirt and Economies of Scale 253 Monopolizing Monopoly 305
Holacracy, Diseconomies of Scale, and Zappos 254 Normative Views of Monopoly 306
Why Are Textbooks So Long? 256 Who Controls Corporations? 342
The Internet and the Perfectly Competitive Model 275 Other Factors of Production 360
The Shutdown Decision and the Relevant Costs 286 Income and Substitution Effects 362
The Dark Side of Amazon 307 Nonwage Income and Property Rights 373
Strategic Competition between Uber and Lyft 326 The Gini Coefficient 396
Nefarious Business Practices 332 What Should Be the Goal of Economic Policy? 404
Why Are CEOs Paid So Much? 343 Income Distribution Policy, Fairness, and the Takeaway
Branding 352 Principle 406
Are Humans Obsolete? 368 Making Stupid Decisions 430
Why Do Women Earn Less Than Men? 375 Game Theory and Experimental Economics 448
From Welfare to Work 410 The Segregation Game and Agent-Based Modeling 453
What Game Is Being Played? 450 Neuroeconomics and Microeconomics 472
Can You Explain Landsburg’s Provocative Insights? 475 Karl Marx and Shove Policy 505
Can You Explain Frank’s Observations? 477 Economic Efficiency and the Goals of Society 520
Markets as Information-Gathering Mechanisms 496 Elasticity and Taxation to Change Behavior 522
The Nudge Unit 502 The Conventional Policy Wisdom among Economists 526
Economists in the Courtroom 516
Where to Locate Polluting Industries 523
A REMINDER
Production Possibility Curves 29
ADDED DIMENSION
Inverse and Direct Relationships 46
Economic Knowledge in One Sentence: TANSTAAFL 7 Six Things to Remember about a Demand Curve 85
Economics in Perspective 10 Six Things to Remember about a Supply Curve 90
Choices in Context: Decision Trees 31 Supply and Demand in Action 103
xxv
xxvi List of Boxes

A Review of Various Elasticity Terms 138


What Goods Should Be Taxed? 148
THINKING LIKE A MODERN ECONOMIST
A Review of Costs 244 Why Do So Many Prices End in 99 Cents? 130
Finding Output, Price, and Profit 284 How to Get Students to Be Responsible 159
A Summary of a Perfectly Competitive Industry 287 What “Goods” Do Firms Produce? The Costs of Producing
Finding a Monopolist’s Output, Price, and Profit 299 Image 238
A Comparison of Various Market Structures 327 Social Norms and Production 259
Choices at the Margin 424 Profit Maximization and Real-World Firms 281
The Austan Goolsbee Check-a-Box Method for Finding The Traditional Models as Stepping-Stones 417
Dominant Strategies and Nash Equilibria 446 Mental Accounting 428
Modern Traditional and Behavioral Economists 485
Some Useful Tools
in Moving from Models
to the Real World
PROLOGUE
The study of economics is generally divided into two separate fields: positive
economics and normative economics. Positive economics is the study of what
FOR THE
is and how the economy works. It is the science of economics; it follows sci-
entific methodology, focuses on facts and logic, and tries to be as value-free
STUDENT
as possible. The majority of any principles of economics course involves
teaching you the methods and tools of positive economics. For example, you
will learn the supply/demand model and its implications. One of the conclu-
sions of that model is that if supply increases, price will fall. In good positive
economics, given the assumptions, that is the only right answer. No in
between. No nuance.
Policy makers, however, aren’t especially interested in whether price will
fall in an abstract model; they are interested in what will happen in the real
world. More specifically, they want to know what will be the impact of a
particular policy. Is it a good or a bad policy? Policy analysis extends eco-
nomics into the arena of normative economics—the study of the goals of the
economy. Normative economics involves an explicit discussion of what is
meant by “good” and by “bad” according to the values of a society. Norma-
tive economics follows a humanist and philosophical methodology that
relies on logical thought experiments, reflection, and discussion among
practitioners to move toward a consensus on values. Because normative eco-
nomics incorporates often poorly understood and highly uncertain values
and sensibilities into the analysis, its methodology requires a much more
nuanced understanding of how the models relate to reality than scientific
methodology provides.
Many economic policy discussions pirouette around the normative difficul-
ties of specifying goals by simply assuming that the goal is to get as much
output as possible from as few inputs as possible—the more stuff the better.
Sounds reasonable. But what if who gets what, and how he or she gets it, mat-
ters (as it generally does)? What if, for example, a policy results in Person A
getting an extra 100 stuffs, while Person B loses 50 stuffs? There’s more stuff
overall, but Person B has less. Person B might not think the policy is fair. So
fairness needs to be considered. Alternatively, say Person B needs a kidney or
he will die. Person A has an extra one, and so sells her kidney to Person B.
While the number of kidneys hasn’t changed, they are allocated in a way that
keeps more people alive. That’s good, right? Not necessarily. Many people find
it immoral to sell kidneys. Should such morality guide policy? U.S. society has
decided that it should; selling organs is illegal in the United States. Applied
policy has to deal with these and hundreds of similar questions of values and
morality.
Normative and positive economics are often presented as distinct areas,
as if values can be excluded from positive economics. Philosophers have
pointed out that, regardless of how hard we try, we can never do purely
positive analysis. Values are just too entangled in the way we look at the
world—how we interpret data, the assumptions we make, and the emphasis
P-2 Prologue for the Student

we give to different lines of reasoning. For example, if you believe that putting a
price on something—such as in the kidney example—undermines the relationship
among individuals, then the supply/demand model is not the correct model for
analyzing the effect of a policy that involves kidneys because the supply/demand
model doesn’t allow for a consideration of such questions. So, just by using a
model you have already made certain implicit moral judgments that influence your
policy conclusions.
Even if we could do pure positive economics, as soon as we move into policy
analysis, we have to deal with values, and thus must include an explicit consideration
of values. Policy involves achieving normatively determined goals. Because policy
involves using insights from positive analysis to achieve goals determined in norma-
tive analysis, policy analysis cannot be classified as either completely normative or
completely positive. It is a bit of both. As you’ll soon read in Chapter 1, I place policy
in the netherworld between normative and positive economics—in the art of economics—
the application of the knowledge gained in positive economics to the goals of econom-
ics determined in normative economics.

The Tools of Normative Economies


In this prologue I want to introduce you to two tools that economists have developed to
deal with questions about integrating values into the analysis. They are the impartial
spectator tool and the devil’s advocate tool. The impartial spectator tool is a thought
experiment in which a person strives to see the world apart from her own position in it.
An impartial spectator basically tries to maintain a neutral position. Doing so is
extremely difficult. That’s where the devil’s advocate tool comes in. The devil’s advo-
cate tool is a tool that helps a person take seriously the arguments of people with
whom he or she is least likely to agree so that a person can be as impartial as possible.
These two philosophical tools are meant to help economists deal with the nuance
inherent in applied policy, and help policy economists arrive at policies that capture
society’s shared values.

The Impartial Spectator Tool


The impartial spectator tool comes from 18th-century Scottish moral philosopher and
economist Adam Smith. In his Theory of Moral Sentiments Smith argued that when
trying to come to a position on a policy, an economist should not support or reject a
policy on the basis of the benefit or cost it will provide himself. Instead, he should
decide on the basis of his estimate of whether the policy will benefit society as a
whole. Is it a policy that individuals from all walks of life would generally accept if
they studied it carefully with an economists’ understanding of how the world works?
The impartial spectator tool is designed to address such issues.
The impartial spectator tool requires that individuals place themselves behind
a veil of ignorance, and from that position ask: Would I support this position if I
were in each of the many different positions people hold in the world? Having
considered the policy from many different positions, how would I best resolve dif-
ferences of opinions? The goal is to arrive at what the individual would argue is a
reasonable consensus of people from all different walks of life. If done correctly,
and if people can really place themselves behind this veil of ignorance, then a
person’s support for a policy will be disconnected from whether that policy will ben-
efit him or her. For example, a poor person might favor a work requirement on food
assistance for healthy individuals, while a rich person might oppose that work
requirement.
Prologue for the Student P-3

The Devil’s Advocate Tool


Thinking through a problem on its own based on the impartial spectator tool will lead
you only so far in arriving at defensible normative goals. To further narrow down the
set of normative goals, you also have to subject your values to the strongest challenge
possible. You do this with the devil’s advocate tool. The devil’s advocate tool chal-
lenges the policy economist to search out and discuss her views with others who hold
different views, and to argue with them, not in order to win the argument, but in order
to better understand those opposing positions, and her own. Free and open speech—no
safe zones—are central to the devil’s advocate tool.
Probably the economist who developed the most nuanced use of these tools was
19th-century British moral philosopher and economist John Stuart Mill. In his book
On Liberty, which provided the normative foundation to his principles of economics
book, he wrote the following:
He who knows only his own side of the case, knows little of that. His reasons
may be good, and no one may have been able to refute them. But if he is equally
unable to refute the reasons on the opposite side; if he does not so much as
know what they are, he has no ground for preferring either opinion. . . . He
must be able to hear them from persons who actually believe them; who defend
them in earnest, and do their very utmost for them. He must know them in their
most plausible and persuasive form; . . . So essential is this discipline to a real
understanding of moral and human subjects, that if opponents of all important
truths do not exist, it is indispensable to imagine them, and supply them with
the strongest arguments which the most skilful devil’s advocate can conjure up.
(Mill 1859/1947: 35–36)
Mill’s support of the market was based on both deeply held values about the
importance of individual freedom, as well as positive analysis. Mill also strongly
advocated for women’s rights and argued against slavery when many noneconomist
elite in British society supported slavery, and saw advocating for women’s rights as
heresy. Even though Mill strongly favored the market and was considered a laissez-
faire advocate, he also favored significant government action to create and maintain
the freedom of opportunity for all that he felt was necessary for fair and functioning
markets.
Similarly, today, many economists advocate for progressive values and sensibili-
ties in their policies, even as they advocate for the market. Where progressive pro-
market economists often disagree with other progressive advocates is in how best to
achieve progressive goals. Economists have found that often policies that on the sur-
face are designed to achieve seemingly desirable progressive goals, in practice, end
up helping a small group of people quite different than the intended beneficiaries.
There are unintended consequences. To avoid these unintended consequences,
­progressive pro-market economists often see policies designed to protect competi-
tion, and to prevent government policy from being captured by vested interests, as the
most effective means of achieving progressive goals.

The Importance of Nuance


The material in this course focuses on positive economics—learning the models. But
throughout I will also discuss the problems with interpreting, applying, and integrating
values into the models. Such discussion will inevitably involve problems of nuance. So
as you read, keep in mind the need for nuance and the importance of values whenever
you are relating the models you learn to real-world problems.
P-4 Prologue for the Student

I consider the need for nuance in applied policy thinking so important that you
should consider it a general learning objective that relates to the entire book: Know
that to relate models to the real world, you need to use a nuanced approach. To ensure
that you learn this principle, you will find questions that address issues of nuance
incorporated within the end-of-chapter materials. If you’re using Connect, you’ll be
asked nuance questions that are based on that material in SmartBook that addresses
this general learning objective. The goal is to keep in focus the issues involved with
applying the models and with interpreting the goals of economic policy even as you
are learning the models.

Alternative Perspectives in Economics


One of the choices I made when approaching this product was to concentrate almost
exclusively on the consensus or mainstream view. I strongly believe that focusing on
that mainstream view is the best way to introduce students to economics. However, I
also strongly believe that all students should be aware of the diverse views among
economists and know that the mainstream view is not the only view out there. Numer-
ous economists see the mainstream presentation as misleading, or as diverting the dis-
cussion away from other, more relevant, moral issues. These economists are generally
called heterodox economists and are classified into groups, including Austrian, Post-
Keynesian, Institutionalist, Radical, Feminist, and Religious economists. (The “Distin-
guishing Features” section of the preface has a brief description of these groups.)
These heterodox groups fall on various sides of the ideological perspective, and in
their work they often raise normative questions that standard economics avoids. Some
believe that the conventional analysis is unfair to the market; others believe that the
conventional analysis is unfair to government-focused policy. Still others believe that
the conventional analysis misses what is truly important in life.
These alternative perspectives are often not presented in principles courses. If the
goal were only to teach positive economics, that makes sense. Alternative perspectives
distract from the models. But if the goal is also to teach how the models are interpreted
and used (which I believe it should be), then leaving out alternative perspectives is
problematic because alternative perspectives provide the devil’s advocate arguments
needed to firm up one’s own arguments.
To integrate these alternative perspectives into the course, at the end of every chap-
ter I present a set of questions from alternative perspectives. These questions challenge
the conventional economics presented in the text from different perspectives. My sug-
gestion is that you use these questions as devil’s advocate’s assistants. If you are pro-
gressive and somewhat anti-market, focus on answering the Austrian questions. If you
are pro-market, focus on answering the Radical questions. If you are STEM focused,
look at the Institutionalist and Religious questions. And if you are male, focus on
answering the Feminist questions. Alternatively, get a study partner whose policy
views are as different from your own as you can find. Work collaboratively with her to
study the material—explain what she finds objectionable, and how it differs from what
you find objectionable.

Conclusion
Economic policy is a moral endeavor. How to integrate normative issues is a question
that economists have struggled with from the beginning of economics. Conventional
economics deals with this by focusing on the less value-laden scientific aspects of
economics embedded in models. That’s what most of the book will teach you. But that
leaves students on their own to struggle with adding values back into the analysis to
Prologue for the Student P-5

arrive at a policy conclusion. The goal of this prologue, and of the nuance discussions
throughout the text, is to assist you in integrating values back into the analysis so you
can arrive at supportable policy positions. In doing so you should:
• Be impartial: You should think of yourself as an impartial spectator, a position
that involves placing yourself in other people’s shoes. Analyze the policy from
those other perspectives, and see if your answer would remain convincing to
you when standing in others’ shoes. (If you are poor you might favor progres-
sive taxation, but if you’re rich will you also favor them?) If you can’t convince
yourself standing in other people’s shoes, explore why you can’t and modify
your support for the policy accordingly.
• Be skeptical: Start with being skeptical of your views and others. Unless you
have studied an issue, do not take strong policy stands. Instead be open to argu-
ments from all points of view. Take a firm position on policy only once you
have gone through this process of reflection, discussion, and challenge.
• Be reasonable: Choose a tentative policy position that seems reasonable to
you. Think hard about it, doing research of views on all sides. After you have
taken a side, to add nuance to the consideration, think hard about how someone
could object to your proposal, and develop responses. If you can’t develop
responses to those objections that satisfy yourself, modify your proposal to
account for those objections.
• Be creative: When there seem to be irreconcilable differences in values about a
policy, be creative and see if you can design a policy that avoids the difference
in values. Think of how you can come to a solution to the problem you are
dealing with. For example, if one person favors a proportional tax and another
favors a progressive tax as a matter of policy, is there a way to achieve the
equivalence of a progressive tax by other means—for example by making the
tax proportional in both income and wealth, rather just in terms of income.
• Be humble: Present your reasoning to others who are actually in the other
shoes, and see if your answer convinces them. If not, explore with them why,
and modify your support for the policy accordingly.
• Be open to challenge: If you can’t find individuals representing different
views, make the arguments for them, playing the role of the devil’s advocate.
Challenge the argument at each level.
MICROECONOMICS
PART
I
Introduction:
Thinking Like an Economist
CHAPTER 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning
CHAPTER 2 The Production Possibility Model, Trade, and Globalization
CHAPTER 3 Economic Institutions
CHAPTER 4 Supply and Demand
CHAPTER 5 Using Supply and Demand
Part I is an introduction, and an introduction to an intro- five kids make sure he doesn’t get carried away in the
duction seems a little funny. But other sections have in- professorial cloud.
troductions, so it seemed a little funny not to have an Will the entire book be like this?
introduction to Part I; and besides, as you will see, I’m a No, the introduction is just trying to rope you in. Much of
little funny myself (which, in turn, has two interpreta- the book will be hard going. Learning happens to be a
tions; I’m sure you will decide which of the two is appro- difficult process: no pain, no gain. But the author isn’t a
priate). It will, however, be a very brief introduction, sadist; he tries to make learning as pleasantly painful as
consisting of questions you may have had and some possible.
­answers to those questions. What do the author’s students think of him?
Weird, definitely weird—and hard. But fair, interesting,
Some Questions and Answers and sincerely interested in getting us to learn. (Answer
Why study economics? written by his students.)
Because it’s neat and interesting and helps provide insight So there you have it. Answers to the questions that
into events that are constantly going on around you. you might never have thought of if they hadn’t been put in
Why is this book so big? front of you. I hope they give you a sense of me and the
Because there’s a lot of important information in it and approach I’ll use in the book. There are some neat ideas
because the book is designed so your teacher can pick and in it. Let’s now briefly consider what’s in the first five
choose. You’ll likely not be required to read all of it, chapters.
­especially if you’re on the quarter system. But once you
start it, you’ll probably read it all anyhow. (Would you A Survey of the
believe?) First Five Chapters
Why does this book cost so much? This first section is really an introduction to the rest of the
To answer this question, you’ll have to read the book. book. It gives you the background necessary so that the
Will this book make me rich? later chapters make sense. Chapter 1 gives you an over-
No. view of the entire field of economics as well as an intro-
Will this book make me happy? duction to my style. Chapter 2 focuses on the production
It depends. possibility curve, comparative advantage, and trade. It
This book doesn’t seem to be written in a normal textbook explains how trade increases production possibilities but
style. Is this book really written by a professor? also why, in the real world, free trade and no government
Yes, but he is different. He misspent his youth working regulation may not be the best policy. Chapter 3 gives you
on cars; he married his high school sweetheart after they some history of economic systems and introduces you
met again at their 20th high school reunion, and they re- to the institutions of the U.S. economy. Chapters 4 and
main happily married today, still totally in love. Twenty- 5 introduce you to supply and demand, and show you
five years after graduating from high school, his wife not only the power of those two concepts but also the
went back to medical school and got her MD because limitations.
she was tired of being treated poorly by doctors. Their Now let’s get on with the show.
Economics and
Economic Reasoning
CHAPTER In my vacations, I visited the poorest quarters of
­several cities and walked through one street after

1 another, looking at the faces of the poorest people.


Next I resolved to make as thorough a study as
I could of Political Economy.
—Alfred Marshall

After reading this chapter,


you should be able to:

LO1-1 Define economics and


­identify its components.
LO1-2 Discuss various ways in
which economists use
­economic reasoning.
LO1-3 Explain real-world events in
terms of economic forces,
social forces, and political
forces.
LO1-4 Explain how economic
­insights are developed
and used.
LO1-5 Distinguish among positive
economics, normative
­economics, and the art
of economics.

©Ingram Publishing

When an artist looks at the world, he sees color. When a musician looks at the
world, she hears music. When an economist looks at the world, she sees a sym-
phony of costs and benefits. The economist’s world might not be as colorful or
as melodic as the others’ worlds, but it’s more practical. If you want to under-
stand what’s going on in the world that’s really out there, you need to know
economics.
I hardly have to convince you of this fact if you keep up with the news.
You will be bombarded with stories of unemployment, interest rates, how
commodity prices are changing, and how businesses are doing. The list is
endless. So let’s say you grant me that economics is important. That still
doesn’t mean that it’s worth studying. The real question then is: How much
will you learn? Most of what you learn depends on you, but part depends on
the teacher and another part depends on the textbook. On both these counts,
Chapter 1 ■ Economics and Economic Reasoning 5

you’re in luck; since your teacher chose this book for your course, you must have a
super teacher.1

What Economics Is
Economics is the study of how human beings coordinate their wants and desires, given
the decision-making mechanisms, social customs, and political realities of the society.
One of the key words in the definition of the term economics is coordination. Coordi-
nation can mean many things. In the study of economics, coordination refers to how
the three central problems facing any economy are solved. These central problems are:
1. What, and how much, to produce. Three central coordination problems
any economy must solve are what to
2. How to produce it. produce, how to produce it, and for
3. For whom to produce it. whom to produce it.

How hard is it to make the three decisions? Imagine for a moment the problem of
living in a family: the fights, arguments, and questions that come up. “Do I have to do
the dishes?” “Why can’t I have piano lessons?” “Bobby got a new sweater. How come
I didn’t?” “Mom likes you best.” Now multiply the size of the family by millions. The
same fights, the same arguments, the same questions—only for society the questions The coordination questions faced by
are millions of times more complicated. In answering these questions, economies find ­society are complicated.

that inevitably individuals want more than is available, given how much they’re will-
ing to work. That means that in our economy there is a problem of scarcity—the
goods available are too few to satisfy individuals’ desires.

Scarcity
Scarcity has two elements: our wants and our means of fulfilling those wants. These
can be interrelated since wants are changeable and partially determined by society. The
way we fulfill wants can affect those wants. For example, if you work on Wall Street,
you will probably want upscale and trendy clothes. In Vermont I am quite happy wearing
Levi’s and flannel; in Florida I am quite happy in shorts.
The degree of scarcity is constantly changing. The quantity of goods, services, and The quantity of goods, services,
usable resources depends on technology and human action, which underlie production. and ­usable resources depends on
­technology and human action.
Individuals’ imagination, innovativeness, and willingness to do what needs to be done
can greatly increase available goods and resources. Who knows what technologies are
in our future—nanites or micromachines that change atoms into whatever we want
could conceivably eliminate scarcity of goods we currently consume. But they would
not eliminate scarcity entirely since new wants are constantly developing.
So, how does an economy deal with scarcity? The answer is coercion. In all known
economies, coordination has involved some type of coercion—limiting people’s wants
and increasing the amount of work individuals are willing to do to fulfill those wants.
The reality is that many people would rather play than help solve society’s problems.
So the basic economic problem involves inspiring people to do things that other people
want them to do, and not to do things that other people don’t want them to do. Thus, an
alternative definition of economics is: the study of how to get people to do things
they’re not wild about doing (such as studying) and not to do things they are wild

1
This book is written by a person, not a machine. That means that I have my quirks, my odd sense
of humor, and my biases. All textbook writers do. Most textbooks have the quirks and eccentricities
edited out so that all the books read and sound alike—professional but dull. I choose to sound like
me—sometimes professional, sometimes playful, and sometimes stubborn. In my view, that makes
the book more human and less dull. So forgive me my quirks—don’t always take me too seriously—
and I’ll try to keep you awake when you’re reading this book at 3 a.m. the day of the exam. If you
think it’s a killer to read a book this long, you ought to try writing one.
6 Introduction ■ Thinking Like an Economist

about doing (such as eating all the ice cream they like), so that the things some people
want to do are consistent with the things other people want to do.

Microeconomics and Macroeconomics


Economic theory is divided into two parts: microeconomic theory and macroeconomic
theory. Microeconomic theory considers economic reasoning from the viewpoint of indi-
Microeconomics is the study of how viduals and firms and builds up to an analysis of the whole economy. Microeconomics is
­individual choice is influenced by the study of individual choice, and how that choice is influenced by economic forces.
­economic forces.
Microeconomics studies such things as the pricing policies of firms, households’ deci-
sions on what to buy, and how markets allocate resources among alternative ends.
As we build up from microeconomic analysis to an analysis of the entire economy,
everything gets rather complicated. Many economists try to uncomplicate matters by taking
a different approach—a macroeconomic approach—first looking at the aggregate, or
Macroeconomics is the study of the whole, and then breaking it down into components. Macroeconomics is the study of the
economy as a whole. It considers the economy as a whole. It considers the problems of inflation, unemployment, business cycles,
problems of inflation, unemployment,
business cycles, and growth. and growth. Macroeconomics focuses on aggregate relationships such as how household
consumption is related to income and how government policies can affect growth.
Consider an analogy to the human body. A micro approach analyzes a person by
looking first at each individual cell and then builds up. A macro approach starts with
the person and then goes on to his or her components—arms, legs, fingernails, feel-
ings, and so on. Put simply, microeconomics analyzes from the parts to the whole;
Q-1 Classify the following topics
as primarily macroeconomic or macroeconomics analyzes from the whole to the parts.
­microeconomic: Microeconomics and macroeconomics are very much interrelated. What happens in
1. The impact of a tax increase on the economy as a whole is based on individual decisions, but individual decisions are
­aggregate output. made within an economy and can be understood only within its macro context. For
2. The relationship between two example, whether a firm decides to expand production capacity will depend on what the
­competing firms’ pricing behavior.
owners expect will happen to the demand for their products. Those expectations are
3. A farmer’s decision to plant soy or
wheat. determined by macroeconomic conditions. Because microeconomics focuses on indi-
4. The effect of trade on economic viduals and macroeconomics focuses on the whole economy, traditionally microeco-
growth. nomics and macroeconomics are taught separately, even though they are interrelated.

A Guide to Economic Reasoning


People trained in economics think in a certain way. They analyze everything critically;
they compare the costs and the benefits of every issue and make decisions based on those
costs and benefits. For example, say you’re trying to decide whether a policy to eliminate
terrorist attacks on airlines is a good idea. Economists are trained to put their emotions
aside and ask: What are the costs of the policy, and what are the benefits? Thus, they are
open to the argument that security measures, such as conducting body searches of every
passenger or scanning all baggage with bomb-detecting machinery, might not be the
appropriate policy because the costs might exceed the benefits. To think like an econo-
mist involves addressing almost all issues using a cost/benefit approach. Economic rea-
soning also involves abstracting from the “unimportant” elements of a question and
focusing on the “important” ones by creating a simple model that captures the essence of
the issue or problem. How do you know whether the model has captured the important
elements? By collecting empirical evidence and “testing” the model—matching the
Economic reasoning is making decisions ­predictions of the model with the empirical evidence—to see if it fits. Economic
on the basis of costs and benefits. ­reasoning—how to think like a modern economist, making decisions on the basis of
costs and benefits—is the most important lesson you’ll learn from this book.
The book Freakonomics gives examples of the economist’s approach. It describes
a number of studies by University of Chicago economist Steve Levitt that unlock
ADDED DIMENSION

Economic Knowledge in One Sentence: TANSTAAFL


Once upon a time, Tanstaafl was made king of all the The economists returned to their desks, shivering in
lands. His first act was to call his economic advisers and their sandals and pondering their impossible task. Think-
tell them to write up all the economic knowledge the society ing about their fate if they were not successful, they de-
possessed. After years of work, they presented their mon- cided to send out for one last meal. Unfortunately, when
umental effort: 25 volumes, each about 400 pages long. they were collecting money to pay for the meal, they dis-
But in the interim, King Tanstaafl had become a very busy covered they were broke. The disgusted delivery person
man, what with running a kingdom of all the lands and all. took the last meal back to the restaurant, and the econo-
Looking at the lengthy volumes, he told his advisers to mists started down the path to the beheading station. On
summarize their findings in one volume. the way, the delivery person’s parting words echoed in
Despondently, the economists returned to their desks, their ears. They looked at each other and suddenly they
wondering how they could summarize what they’d been so realized the truth. “We’re saved!” they screamed. “That’s it!
careful to spell out. After many more years of rewriting, they That’s economic knowledge in one sentence!” They wrote
were finally satisfied with their one-volume effort and tried down the sentence and presented it to the king, who
to make an appointment to see the king. Unfortunately, af- thereafter fully understood all economic problems. (He
fairs of state had become even more pressing than before, also gave them a good meal.) The sentence?
and the king couldn’t take the time to see them. Instead he
There Ain’t No Such Thing As A Free Lunch—
sent word to them that he couldn’t be bothered with a whole
TANSTAAFL
volume, and ordered them, under threat of death (for he had
become a tyrant), to reduce the work to one sentence.

seemingly mysterious observations with basic economic reasoning. For example, Levitt
asked the question: Why do drug dealers on the street tend to live with their mothers?
The answer he arrived at was that they couldn’t afford to live on their own; most
earned less than $5 an hour. Why, then, were they dealing drugs and not working a
legal job that, even for a minimum wage job, paid over $7 an hour? The answer to that
is determined through cost/benefit analysis. While their current income was low, their
potential income as a drug dealer was much higher since, given their background and
existing U.S. institutions, they were more likely to move up to a high position in
the local drug business (and Freakonomics describes how it is a business) and earn a
six-figure income than they were to move up from working as a Taco Bell technician to
an executive earning a six-figure income in corporate America. Levitt’s model is a very
simple one—people do what is in their best interest financially—and it assumes that
people rely on a cost/benefit analysis to make decisions. Finally, he supports his argu-
ment through careful empirical work, collecting and organizing the data to see if they fit
the model. His work is a good example of “thinking like a modern economist” in action.
Economic reasoning, once learned, is infectious. If you’re susceptible, being
exposed to it will change your life. It will influence your analysis of everything, includ-
ing issues normally considered outside the scope of economics. For example, you will
likely use economic reasoning to decide the possibility of getting a date for Saturday
night, and who will pay for dinner. You will likely use it to decide whether to read this
book, whether to attend class, whom to marry, and what kind of work to go into after
you graduate. This is not to say that economic reasoning will provide all the answers.
As you will see throughout this book, real-world questions are inevitably complicated,
and economic reasoning simply provides a framework within which to approach a
question. In the economic way of thinking, every choice has costs and benefits, and
decisions are made by comparing them. 7
8 Introduction ■ Thinking Like an Economist

Marginal Costs and Marginal Benefits


The relevant costs and relevant benefits to economic reasoning are the expected incre-
mental, or additional, costs incurred and the expected incremental benefits that result
from a decision. Economists use the term marginal when referring to additional or
incremental. Marginal costs and marginal benefits are key concepts.
A marginal cost is the additional cost to you over and above the costs you have
Web Note 1.1 already incurred. That means not counting sunk costs—costs that have already been
incurred and cannot be recovered—in the relevant costs when making a decision.
Costs and Benefits Consider, for example, attending class. You’ve already paid your tuition; it is a sunk
cost. So the marginal (or additional) cost of going to class does not include tuition.
Similarly with marginal benefit. A marginal benefit is the additional benefit
above what you’ve already derived. The marginal benefit of reading this chapter is the
additional knowledge you get from reading it. If you already knew everything in this
chapter before you picked up the book, the marginal benefit of reading it now is zero.

The Economic Decision Rule


Comparing marginal (additional) costs with marginal (additional) benefits will often
tell you how you should adjust your activities to be as well off as possible. Just follow
If the marginal benefits of doing the economic decision rule:
­something exceed the marginal costs,
do it. If the marginal costs of doing If the marginal benefits of doing something exceed the marginal costs, do it.
something exceed the marginal
­benefits, don’t do it.
If the marginal costs of doing something exceed the marginal benefits, don’t do it.
As an example, let’s consider a discussion I might have with a student who tells me that
she is too busy to attend my classes. I respond, “Think about the tuition you’ve spent for this
class—it works out to about $60 a lecture.” She answers that the book she reads for class is a
book that I wrote, and that I wrote it so clearly she fully understands everything. She goes on:
Q-2 Say you bought a share of I’ve already paid the tuition and whether I go to class or not, I can’t get any of the
­ racle for $100 and a share of Cisco for
O tuition back, so the tuition is a sunk cost and doesn’t enter into my decision. The
$10. The price of each is currently $15.
Assuming taxes are not an issue, which marginal cost to me is what I could be doing with the hour instead of spending it
would you sell if you needed $15? in class. I value my time at $75 an hour [people who understand everything value
their time highly], and even though I’ve heard that your lectures are super, I esti-
mate that the marginal benefit of attending your class is only $50. The marginal
cost, $75, exceeds the marginal benefit, $50, so I don’t attend class.
I congratulate her on her diplomacy and her economic reasoning, but tell her that I give
a quiz every week, that students who miss a quiz fail the quiz, that those who fail all the quiz-
zes fail the course, and that those who fail the course do not graduate. In short, she is under-
estimating the marginal benefits of attending my classes. Correctly estimated, the marginal
benefits of attending my class exceed the marginal costs. So she should attend my class.

Economics and Passion


Recognizing that everything has a cost is reasonable, but it’s a reasonableness that
Web Note 1.2 many people don’t like. It takes some of the passion out of life. It leads you to consider
possibilities like these:
Blogonomics
• Saving some people’s lives with liver transplants might not be worth the
­additional cost. The money might be better spent on nutritional programs that
would save 20 lives for every 2 lives you might save with transplants.
Economic reasoning is based on the • Maybe we shouldn’t try to eliminate all pollution because the additional cost
premise that everything has a cost. of doing so may be too high. To eliminate all pollution might be to forgo too
much of some other worthwhile activity.
Chapter 1 ■ Economics and Economic Reasoning 9

• Providing a guaranteed job for every person who


wants one might not be a worthwhile policy goal if it
means that doing so will reduce the ability of an
economy to adapt to new technologies.
You get the idea. This kind of reasonableness is often
criticized for being coldhearted. But, not surprisingly, econ-
omists disagree; they argue that their reasoning leads to a
better society for the majority of people.
Economists’ reasonableness isn’t universally appreciated.
Businesses love the result; others aren’t so sure, as I discovered
some years back when my then-girlfriend told me she was leav-
ing me. “Why?,” I asked. “Because,” she responded, “you’re
so, so . . . reasonable.” It took me many years after she left to
learn what she already knew: There are many types of reason-
ableness, and not everyone thinks an economist’s reasonable-
ness is a virtue. I’ll discuss such issues later; for now, let me Opportunity costs have always made choice ­difficult, as we
simply warn you that, for better or worse, studying economics see in the early-19th-century engraving One or the Other.
will lead you to view questions in a cost/benefit framework. ©Heritage Images/Houlton Archive/Getty Images

Opportunity Cost
Putting economists’ cost/benefit rules into practice isn’t easy. To do so, you have to be Q-3 Can you think of a reason why
able to choose and measure the costs and benefits correctly. Economists have devised the a cost/benefit approach to a problem
might be inappropriate? Can you give
concept of opportunity cost to help you do that. Opportunity cost is the benefit that you an example?
might have gained from choosing the next-best alternative. To obtain the benefit of
something, you must give up (forgo) something else—namely, the next-best alternative.
The opportunity cost is the market value of that next-best alternative; it is a cost because
in choosing one thing, you are precluding an alternative choice. The TANSTAAFL story
in the earlier Added Dimension box embodies the opportunity cost concept because it
tells us that there is a cost to everything; that cost is the next-best forgone alternative.
Let’s consider some examples. The opportunity cost of going out once with Natalie
(or Nathaniel), the most beautiful woman (attractive man) in the world, is the benefit
you’d get from going out with your solid steady, Margo (Mike). The opportunity cost Opportunity cost is the basis of cost/
of cleaning up the environment might be a reduction in the money available to assist benefit economic reasoning; it is the
benefit that you might have gained from
low-income individuals. The opportunity cost of having a child might be two boats, choosing the next-best alternative.
three cars, and a two-week vacation each year for five years, which are what you could
have had if you hadn’t had the child. (Kids really are this expensive.)
Examples are endless, but let’s consider two that are particularly relevant to you: what
courses to take and how much to study. Let’s say you’re a full-time student and at the
beginning of the term you had to choose five courses. Taking one precludes taking some
other, and the opportunity cost of taking an economics course may well be not taking a
course on theater. Similarly with studying: You have a limited amount of time to spend
studying economics, studying some other subject, sleeping, or partying. The more time
you spend on one activity, the less time you have for another. That’s opportunity cost.
Notice how neatly the opportunity cost concept takes into account costs and bene-
fits of all other options and converts these alternative benefits into costs of the decision Web Note 1.3
you’re now making. One of the most useful aspects of the opportunity cost concept is
that it focuses on two aspects of costs of a choice that often might be forgotten— Opportunity Cost
implicit costs and illusionary sunk costs. Implicit costs are costs associated with a
decision that often aren’t included in normal accounting costs.
For example, in thinking about whether it makes sense to read this book, the next-
best value of the time you spend reading it should be one of the costs that you consider.
ADDED DIMENSION

Economics in Perspective
All too often, students study economics out of context. itself split into subdivisions: economics, political science,
They’re presented with sterile analysis and boring facts to history, geography, sociology, anthropology, and psychol-
memorize, and are never shown how economics fits into ogy. Many of the insights about how the economic system
the larger scheme of things. That’s bad; it makes econom- worked were codified in Adam Smith’s The Wealth of
ics seem boring—but economics is not boring. Every so ­Nations, written in 1776. Notice that this is before econom-
often throughout this book, sometimes in the appendixes ics as a subdiscipline developed, and Adam Smith could
and sometimes in these boxes, I’ll step back and put the also be classified as an anthropologist, a sociologist, a
analysis in perspective, giving you an idea from whence ­political scientist, and a social philosopher.
the analysis sprang and its historical context. In educa- Throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, economists such
tional jargon, this is called enrichment. as Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, John Stuart Mill, David
I begin here with economics itself. ­Ricardo, and Karl Marx were more than economists; they
First, its history: In the 1500s there were few universi- were social philosophers who covered all aspects of social
ties. Those that existed taught religion, Latin, Greek, phi- science. These writers were subsequently called Classical
losophy, history, and mathematics. No economics. Then economists. Alfred Marshall continued in that classical tradi-
came the Enlightenment (about 1700), in which reasoning tion, and his book, Principles of Economics, published in the
replaced God as the explanation of why things were the late 1800s, was written with the other social sciences much
way they were. Pre-Enlightenment thinkers would answer in evidence. But Marshall also changed the questions econ-
the question “Why am I poor?” with “Because God wills it.” omists ask; he focused on those questions that could be
Enlightenment scholars looked for a different explanation. asked in a graphical supply/demand framework.
“Because of the nature of land ownership” is one answer This book falls solidly in the Marshallian tradition. It
they found. presents economics as a way of thinking—as an engine of
Such reasoned explanations required more knowledge analysis used to understand real-world phenomena. But
of the way things were, and the amount of information ex- it goes beyond Marshall, and introduces you to a wider
panded so rapidly that it had to be divided or categorized variety of models and thinking than the supply and demand
for an individual to have hope of knowing a subject. Soon models that Marshall used.
philosophy was subdivided into science and philosophy. In Marshallian economics is primarily about policy, not
the 1700s, the sciences were split into natural sciences theory. It sees institutions as well as political and social di-
and social sciences. The amount of knowledge kept increas- mensions of reality as important, and it shows you how
ing, and in the late 1800s and early 1900s social science economics ties in to those dimensions.

Often, it isn’t because it is an implicit, not normally measured cost. Similarly with
firms—owners often think that they are making a profit from a business, but if they
add the value of their time to their cost, which economists argue they should, then their
profit often becomes a loss. They might have earned more simply by taking a job
somewhere else. Implicit costs should be included in opportunity costs. Sunk costs,
however, are often included in making decisions, but should not be. These costs are
called illusionary sunk costs—costs that show up in financial accounts but that econo-
mists argue should not be considered in a choice because they are already spent. They
will not change regardless of what the person making the decision chooses. For exam-
ple, once you have bought a book (that can’t be resold), what you paid for that book is
sunk. Following economic reasoning, that sunk cost shouldn’t enter into your decision
The costs relevant to decisions are often on whether to read it. An important role of the opportunity cost concept is to remind
different from the measured costs. you that the costs relevant to decisions are often different from the measured costs.
The relevance of opportunity cost isn’t limited to your individual decisions. Oppor-
tunity costs are also relevant to government’s decisions, which affect everyone in
10 ­society. A common example is what is called the guns-versus-butter debate. The
Chapter 1 ■ Economics and Economic Reasoning 11

resources that a society has are limited; therefore, its decision to use those resources to Q-4 John, your study partner, has
have more guns (more weapons) means that it will have less butter (fewer consumer just said that the opportunity cost of
studying this chapter is about 1/38 the
goods). Thus, when society decides to spend $50 billion more on an improved health price you paid for this book, since the
care system, the opportunity cost of that decision is $50 billion not spent on helping chapter is about 1/38 of the book. Is he
the homeless, paying off some of the national debt, or providing for national defense. right? Why or why not?
The opportunity cost concept has endless implications. It can even be turned upon itself.
For instance, thinking about alternatives takes time; that means that there’s a cost to being
reasonable, so it’s only reasonable to be somewhat unreasonable. If you followed that argu-
ment, you’ve caught the economic bug. If you didn’t, don’t worry. Just remember the oppor-
tunity cost concept for now; I’ll infect you with economic thinking in the rest of the book.

Economic Forces, Social Forces,


and Political Forces
The opportunity cost concept applies to all aspects of life and is fundamental to under- Q-5 Ali, your study partner, states
standing how society reacts to scarcity. When goods are scarce, those goods must be that rationing health care is immoral—
that health care should be freely
rationed. That is, a mechanism must be chosen to determine who gets what. ­available to all individuals in society.
How would you respond?
Economic and Market Forces
Let’s consider some specific real-world rationing mechanisms. Dormitory rooms are
often rationed by lottery, and permission to register in popular classes is often rationed
by a first-come, first-registered rule. Food in the United States, however, is generally
rationed by price. If price did not ration food, there wouldn’t be enough food to go
around. All scarce goods must be rationed in some fashion. These rationing mecha-
nisms are examples of economic forces, the necessary reactions to scarcity.
One of the important choices that a society must make is whether to allow these
economic forces to operate freely and openly or to try to rein them in. A market force When an economic force operates
is an economic force that is given relatively free rein by society to work through the through the market, it becomes a
­market force.
market. Market forces ration by changing prices. When there’s a shortage, the price
goes up. When there’s a surplus, the price goes down. Much of this book will be devoted
to analyzing how the market works like an invisible hand, guiding economic forces to
coordinate individual actions and allocate scarce resources. The invisible hand is the Economic reality is controlled by
price mechanism, the rise and fall of prices that guides our actions in a market. three forces:
1. Economic forces (the invisible hand).
Social and Political Forces 2. Social forces.
3. Political forces.
Societies can’t choose whether or not to allow economic forces to operate—economic
forces are always operating. However, societies can choose whether to allow market forces
to predominate. Social forces—forces that guide individual actions even though those
actions may not be in an individual’s selfish interest, and political forces—legal direc-
tives that direct individuals’ actions—play a major role in deciding whether to let market
forces operate. Economic reality is determined by a contest among these various forces.
Let’s consider a historical example in which social forces prevented an economic Social, cultural, and political forces can
force from becoming a market force: the problem of getting a date for Saturday night play a significant role in the economy.

back when people actually dated (or called the pairing off of two individuals a “date”).
If a school (or a society) had significantly more heterosexual people of one gender than
the other (let’s say more men than women), some men would find themselves without a
date—that is, men would be in excess supply—and would have to find something else
to do, say study or go to a movie by themselves. An “excess supply” person could solve
the problem by paying someone to go out with him or her, but that would have changed
the nature of the date in unacceptable ways. It would be revolting to the person who
offered payment and to the person who was offered payment. That unacceptability is an
REAL-WORLD APPLICATION

Winston Churchill and Lady Astor


There are many stories about Nancy Astor, would, if the money were guaranteed.
the first woman elected to Britain’s Parlia­ Churchill then asked her if she would sleep
ment. A vivacious, fearless American woman, with him for five pounds. Her response
she married into the English aristocracy and, was sharp: “Of course not. What do you
during the 1930s and 1940s, became a bright think I am—a prostitute?” Churchill re-
light on the English social and political sponded, “We have already established that
scenes, which were already quite bright. fact; we are now simply negotiating about
One story told about Lady Astor is that price.”
she and Winston Churchill, the unorthodox One moral that economists might draw
genius who had a long and distinguished from this story is that economic incentives, if
political career and who was Britain’s prime high enough, can have a powerful influence
minister during World War II, were sitting in a on behavior. But an equally important moral
Lady Astor
pub having a theoretical discussion about of the story is that noneconomic incentives
©Bettmann/Getty Images
morality. Churchill suggested that as a also can be very strong. Why do most people
thought experiment Lady Astor ponder the feel it’s wrong to sell sex for money, even if
following question: If a man were to promise her a huge they might be willing to do so if the price were high
amount of money—say a million pounds—for the privi- enough? Keeping this second moral in mind will signifi-
lege, would she sleep with him? Lady Astor did ponder cantly increase your economic understanding of real-
the question for a while and finally answered, yes, she world events.

Q-6 Your study partner, Joan, states example of the complex social and cultural norms that guide and limit our activities.
that market forces are always operative. People don’t try to buy dates because social forces prevent them from doing so.2
Is she right? Why or why not?
Often political and social forces work together against the invisible hand. For exam-
ple, in the United States there aren’t enough babies to satisfy all the couples who desire
them. Babies born to particular sets of parents are rationed—by luck. Consider a group of
parents, all of whom want babies. Those who can, have a baby; those who can’t have one,
but want one, try to adopt. Adoption agencies ration the available babies. Who gets a baby
depends on whom people know at the adoption agency and on the desires of the birth
mother, who can often specify the socioeconomic background (and many other character-
istics) of the family in which she wants her baby to grow up. That’s the economic force in
action; it gives more power to the supplier of something that’s in short supply.
If our society allowed individuals to buy and sell babies, that economic force would
be translated into a market force. The invisible hand would see to it that the quantity of
babies supplied would equal the quantity of babies demanded at some price. The market,
not the adoption agencies, would do the rationing.3

2
Pairing habits of young adults have changed in ways that have made “dating” somewhat of a
h­ istorical social convention. The new social conventions that guide such pairing functions do not
©Rachel Epstein/PhotoEdit eliminate the problem of excess individuals, but they do obscure it and create multiple dimensions
of “excess.” Thinking about how they do so is a useful exercise.
3
Even though it’s against the law, some babies are nonetheless “sold” on a semilegal market, also called
a gray market. Recently, the “market price” for a healthy baby was about $30,000. If selling babies were
legal (and if people didn’t find it morally repugnant to have babies in order to sell them), the price would
be much lower because there would be a larger supply of babies. (It was not against the law to sell
human eggs in the early 2000s, and one human egg was sold for $50,000. The average price was much
lower; it varied with donor characteristics such as SAT scores and athletic accomplishments.)
12
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
CHAPTER XVII.

THE DISTRIBUTION OF FRESHWATER FISHES.

Having shown above that numerous marine fishes enter fresh


waters, and that some of them have permanently established
themselves therein, we have to eliminate from the category of
freshwater fishes all such adventitious elements. They are derived
from forms, the distribution of which is regulated by other agencies,
and which, therefore, would obscure the relations of the faunæ of
terrestrial regions if they were included in them. They will be
mentioned with greater propriety along with the fishes constituting
the fauna of the brackish water.
True freshwater fishes are the following families and groups only:

Dipnoi with 4 species.
Acipenseridæ and „ 26 „
Polyodontidæ
Amiidæ „ 1 „
Polypteridæ. „ 2 „
Lepidosteidæ. „ 3 „
Percina „ 46 „
Grystina „ 11 „
Aphredoderidæ „ 1 „
Centrarchina „ 26 „
Dules „ 10 „
Nandidæ „ 7 „
Polycentridæ „ 3 „
Labyrinthici „ 30 „
Luciocephalidæ „ 1 „
Gastrosteus „ 10 „
Ophiocephalidæ „ 31 „
Mastacembelidaæ „ 13 „
Chromides „ 105 „
Comephoridæ „ 1 „
Gadopsidæ „ 1 „
Siluridæ „ 572 „
Characinidæ „ 261 „
Haplochitonidæ „ 3 „
Salmonidæ (3 genera excepted) „ 135 „
Percopsidæ „ 1 „
Galaxiidæ „ 15 „
Mormyridæ (and Gymnarchidæ) „ 52 „
Esocidæ „ 8 „
Umbridæ „ 2 „
Cyprinodontidæ „ 112 „
Heteropygii „ 2 „
Cyprinidæ „ 724 „
Kneriidæ „ 2 „
Hyodontidæ „ 1 „
Osteoglossidæ „ 5 „
Notopteridæ „ 5 „
Gymnotidæ „ 20 „
Symbranchidæ „ 5 „
Petromyzontidæ „ 12 „
Total 2269 species.

As in every other class of animals, these freshwater genera and


families vary greatly with regard to the extent of their geographical
range; some extend over the greater half of the continental areas,
whilst others are limited to one continent only, or even to a very small
portion of it. As a general rule, a genus or family of freshwater fishes
is regularly dispersed and most developed within a certain district,
the species and individuals becoming scarcer towards the periphery
as the type recedes more from its central home, some outposts
being frequently pushed far beyond the outskirts of the area
occupied by it. But there are not wanting those remarkable instances
of closely allied forms occurring, almost isolated, at most distant
points, without being connected by allied species in the intervening
space; or of members of the same family, genus, or species
inhabiting the opposite shores of an ocean, and separated by many
degrees of abyssal depths. We mention of a multitude of such
instances the following only:—

A. Species identical in distant continents—


1. A number of species inhabiting Europe and the temperate
parts of eastern North America, as Perca fluviatilis, Gastrosteus
pungitius, Lota vulgaris, Salmo solar, Esox lucius, Acipenser sturio,
Acipenser maculosus, and several Petromyzonts.
2. Lates calcarifer is common in India as well as in Queensland.
3. Galaxias attenuatus inhabits Tasmania, New Zealand, the
Falkland Islands, and the southernmost part of the South American
continent.
4. Several Petromyzonts enter the fresh waters of Tasmania,
South Australia, New Zealand, and Chili.

B. Genera identical in distant continents—


1. The genus Umbra, so peculiar a form as to be the type of a
distinct family consisting of two most closely allied species only, one
of which is found in the Atlantic States of North America, the other in
the system of the Danube.
2. A very distinct genus of Sturgeons, Scaphirhynchus, consisting
of two species only, one inhabiting fresh waters of Central Asia, the
other the system of the Mississippi.
3. A second most peculiar genus of Sturgeons, Polyodon,
consists likewise of two species only, one inhabiting the Mississippi,
the other the Yang-tse-kiang.
4. Amiurus, a Siluroid, and Catostomus, a Cyprinoid genus, both
well represented in North America, occur in a single species in
temperate China.
5. Lepidosiren is represented by one species in tropical America,
and by the second in tropical Africa (Protopterus).
6. Notopterus consists of three Indian and two West African
species.
7. Mastacembelus and Ophiocephalus, genera characteristic of
the Indian region, emerge severally by a single species in West and
Central Africa.
8. Symbranchus has two Indian and one South American
species.
9. Prototroctes, the singular antarctic analogue of Coregonus,
consists of two species, one in the south of Australia the other in
New Zealand.
10. Galaxias is equally represented in Southern Australia, New
Zealand, and the southern parts of South America.

C. Families identical in distant continents—


1. The Labyrinthici, represented in Africa by 5, and in India by 25
species.
2. The Chromides, represented in Africa by 25, and in South
America by 80 species.
3. The Characinidæ, represented in Africa by 35, and in South
America by 226 species.
4. The Haplochitonidæ, represented in Southern Australia by
one, in New Zealand by one, and in Patagonia by a third species.
This list could be much increased from the families of Siluridæ
and Cyprinidæ, but as these have a greater range than the other
Freshwater fishes, they do not illustrate with equal force the object
for which the list has been composed.

The ways in which the dispersal of Freshwater fishes has been


effected were various; they are probably all still in operation, but
most work so slowly and imperceptibly as to escape direct
observation; perhaps, they will be more conspicuous, after science
and scientific inquiry shall have reached to a somewhat greater age.
From the great number of freshwater forms which we see at this
present day acclimatised in, gradually acclimatising themselves in, or
periodically or sporadically migrating into, the sea, we must conclude
that, under certain circumstances, salt water may cease to be an
impassable barrier at some period of the existence of freshwater
species, and that many of them have passed from one river through
salt water into another. Secondly, the headwaters of some of the
grandest rivers, the mouths of which are at opposite ends of the
continents which they drain, are sometimes distant from each other a
few miles only; the intervening space may have been easily bridged
over for the passage of fishes by a slight geological change affecting
the level of the watershed, or even by temporary floods; and a
communication of this kind, if existing for a limited period only, would
afford the ready means of an exchange of a number of species
previously peculiar to one or the other of those river or lake systems.
Some fishes, provided with gill-openings so narrow that the water
moistening the gills cannot readily evaporate; and endowed,
besides, with an extraordinary degree of vitality, like many Siluroids
(Clarias, Callichthys), Eels, etc., are enabled to wander for some
distance over land, and may thus reach a water-course leading them
thousands of miles from their original home. Finally, fishes or their
ova may be accidentally carried by waterspouts, by aquatic birds or
insects, to considerable distances.
Freshwater fishes of the present fauna were already in existence
when the great changes of the distribution of land and water took
place in the tertiary epoch; and having stated that salt water is not an
absolute barrier to the spreading of Freshwater fishes, we can now
more easily account for those instances of singular disconnection of
certain families or genera. It is not necessary to assume that there
was a continuity of land stretching from the present coast of Africa to
South America, or from South America to New Zealand and
Australia, to explain the presence of identical forms at so distant
localities; it suffices to assume that the distances were lessened by
intervening archipelagoes, or that an oscillation has taken place in
the level of the land area.
Dispersal of a type over several distant continental areas may be
evidence of its great antiquity, but it does not prove that it is of
greater antiquity than another limited to one region only. Geological
evidence is the only proof of the antiquity of a type. Thus, although
the Dipnoi occur on the continents of Africa, South America, and
Australia, and their present distribution is evidently the consequence
of their wide range in palæozoic and secondary epochs; the proof of
their high antiquity can be found in their fossil remains only. For,
though the Siluroids have a still greater range, their wide distribution
is of comparatively recent date, as the few fossil remains that have
been found belong to the tertiary epoch. The rapidity of dispersal of a
type depends entirely on its facility to accommodate itself to a variety
of physical conditions, and on the degree of vitality by which it is
enabled to survive more or less sudden changes under unfavourable
conditions; proof of this is afforded by the family of Siluroids, many of
which can suspend for some time the energy of their respiratory
functions, and readily survive a change of water.

To trace the geological sequence of the distribution of an ichthyic


type, and to recognise the various laws which have governed, and
are still governing its dispersal, is one of the ultimate tasks of
Ichthyology. But the endeavour to establish by means of our present
fragmentary geological knowledge the divisions of the fauna of the
globe, leads us into a maze of conflicting evidence; or, as Mr.
Wallace truly observes, “any attempt to exhibit the regions of former
geological ages in combination with those of our own period must
lead to confusion.” Nevertheless, as the different types of animals
found at the present day within a particular area have made their
appearance therein at distant periods, we should endeavour to
decide as far as we can, in an account of the several zoo-
geographical divisions, the following questions:—
1. Which of the fishes of an area should be considered to be the
remnants of ancient types, probably spread over much larger areas
in preceding epochs?
2. Which of them are to be considered to be autochthont species,
that is, forms which came in the tertiary epoch or later into existence
within the area to which they are still limited, or from which they have
since spread?
3. Which are the forms which must be considered to be
immigrants from some other region?
The mode of division of the earth’s surface into zoological regions
or areas now generally adopted, is that proposed by Mr. Sclater,
which recommends itself as most nearly agreeing with the
geographical divisions. These regions are as follows:—
I. Palæogæa.
1. The Palæarctic region; including Europe, temperate Asia,
and North Africa.
2. The Ethiopian region; including Africa, south of the
Sahara, Madagascar, and the Mascarene Islands; also
Southern Arabia.
3. The Indian region; including India south of the
Himalayas, to Southern China, Borneo, and Java.
4. The Australian region; including Australia, the Pacific
Islands, Celebes, and Lombock.
II. Neogæa.
5. The Nearctic region; including North America to Northern
Mexico.
6. The Neotropical region; including South America, the
West Indies, and Southern Mexico.
Comparatively few classes and orders of animals have been
carefully studied with regard to their geographical distribution, but the
majority of those which have been examined show that the
difference of latitude is accompanied by a greater dissimilarity of
indigenous species than that of longitude, and that a main division
into an old world and new world fauna is untenable. More especially
the Freshwater fishes, with which we are here solely concerned,
have been spread in circumpolar zones, and in a but limited degree
from north to south. No family, much less a genus, ranges from the
north to the south, whilst a number of families and genera make the
entire circuit, and some species more than half of the circuit round
the globe within the zone to which they belong. Not even the
Cyprinoids and Siluroids, which are most characteristic of the
freshwater fauna of our period, are an exception to this. Temperature
and climate, indeed, are the principal factors by which the character
of the freshwater fauna is determined; they form the barriers which
interfere with the unlimited dispersal of an ichthyic type, much more
than mountain ranges, deserts, or oceans. Hence the tropical zone is
an impassable barrier to the northern Freshwater fish in its progress
towards the south; where a similarly temperate climate obtains in the
southern hemisphere, fish-forms appear analogous to those of the
north, but genetically and structurally distinct.
The similarity which obtains in fishes at somewhat distant points
of the same degree of longitude, rarely extends far, and is due to the
natural tendency of every animal to spread as far as physical
conditions will permit. Between two regions situated north and south
of each other there is always a debateable border ground, in parts of
which sometimes the fishes of the one, sometimes those of the
other, predominate, and which is, in fact, a band of demarcation.
Within this band the regions overlap each other; therefore, their
border lines are rarely identical, and should be determined by the
northern and southernmost extent of the most characteristic types of
each region. Thus, for instance, in China, a broad band intervenes
between temperate and tropical Asia, in which these two faunæ mix,
and the actual northern border line of the tropical fauna is north of
the southern border line of temperate Asia.
It is the aim of every philosophical classification to indicate the
degree of affinity which obtains between the various divisions; but
the mode of division into six equivalent regions, as given above,
does not fulfil this aim with regard to Freshwater fishes, the
distribution of which allows of further generalisation and subdivision.
The two families, Cyprinidæ and Siluridæ, of which the former yields
a contingent of one-third, and the latter of one-fourth of all the
freshwater species known of our period, afford most valuable
guidance for the valuation of the degrees of affinity between the
various divisions. The Cyprinoids may be assumed to have taken
their origin in the Alpine region, dividing the temperate and tropical
parts of Asia; endowed with a greater capability of acclimatising
themselves in a temperate as well as tropical climate than any other
family of freshwater fishes, they spread north and south as well as
east and west; in the preglacial epoch they reached North America,
but they have not had time to penetrate into South America,
Australia, or the islands of the Pacific. The Siluroids, principally
fishes of the sluggish waters of the plains, and well adapted for
surviving changes of the water in which they live, for living in mud or
sea-water, flourish most in the tropical climate, in which this type
evidently had its origin. They came into existence after the
Cyprinoids, fossil remains being known only from tertiary deposits in
India, none from Europe. They rapidly spread over the areas of land
within the tropical zone, reaching northern Australia from India, and
one species even immigrated into the Sandwich Islands, probably
from South America. The Coral Islands of the Pacific still remain
untenanted by them. Their progress into temperate regions was
evidently slow, only very few species penetrating into the temperate
parts of Asia and Europe; and the North American species, although
more numerous, showing no great variety of structure, all belonging
to the same group (Amiurina). Towards the south their progress was
still slower, Tasmania, New Zealand, and Patagonia being without
representatives, whilst the streams of the Andes of Chili are
inhabited by a few dwarfed forms identical with such as are
characteristic of similar localities in the more northern and warmer
parts of the South American continent.
After these preliminary remarks we propose the following division
of the fauna of Freshwater fishes:—
I. The Northern Zone.—Characterised by Acipenseridæ. Few
Siluridæ. Numerous Cyprinidæ. Salmonidæ, Esocidæ.
1. Europo-Asiatic or Palæarctic Region.—Characterised by
absence of osseous Ganoidei; Cobitidæ and Barbus
numerous.
2. North American Region.—Characterised by osseous Ganoidei,
Amiurina, and Catostomina; but no Cobitidæ or Barbus.
II. The Equatorial Zone.—Characterised by the development of
Siluridæ.
A. Cyprinoid Division.—Characterised by presence of Cyprinidæ
and Labyrinthici.
1. Indian Region.—Characterised by [absence of Dipnoi[18]]
Ophiocephalidæ, Mastacembelidæ. Cobitidæ numerous.
2. African Region.—Characterised by presence of Dipnoi and
Polypteridæ. Chromides and Characinidæ numerous.
Mormyridæ. Cobitidæ absent.
B. Acyprinoid Division.—Characterised by absence of Cyprinidæ
and Labyrinthici.
1. Tropical American Region.—Characterised by presence of
Dipnoi. Chromides and Characinidæ numerous.
Gymnotidæ.
2. Tropical Pacific Region.—Characterised by presence of
Dipnoi. Chromides and Characinidæ absent.
III. The Southern Zone.—Characterised by absence of Cyprinidæ,
and scarcity of Siluridæ. Haplochitonidæ and Galaxiidæ
represent the Salmonoids and Esoces of the Northern zone.
One region only.
1. Antarctic Region.—Characterised by the small number of
species; the fishes of—
a. The Tasmanian sub-region; b. The New Zealand sub-region;
c. The Patagonian sub-region;
being almost identical.[19]
In the following detailed account we begin with a description of
the equatorial zone, this being the one from which the two principal
families of freshwater fishes seem to have spread.

I. Equatorial Zone.
Roughly speaking, the borders of this zoological zone coincide
with the geographical limits of the tropical zone, the tropics of the
Cancer and Capricorn; its characteristic forms, however, extend in
undulating lines several degrees north and southwards.
Commencing from the west coast of Africa the desert of the Sahara
forms a well-marked boundary between the equatorial and northern
zones; as the boundary approaches the Nile it makes a sudden
sweep towards the north as far as Northern Syria (Mastacembelus,
near Aleppo, and in the Tigris; Clarias and Chromides, in the lake of
Galilee); crosses through Persia and Afghanistan (Ophiocephalus),
to the southern ranges of the Himalayas, and follows the course of
the Yang-tse-Kiang, which receives its contingent of equatorial fishes
through its southern tributaries. Its continuation through the North
Pacific may be considered to be indicated by the tropic which strikes
the coast of Mexico at the southern end of the Gulf of California.
Equatorial types of South America are known to extend so far
northwards; and by following the same line the West India Islands
are naturally included in this zone.
Towards the south the equatorial zone embraces the whole of
Africa and Madagascar, and seems to extend still farther south in
Australia, its boundary probably following the southern coast of that
continent; the detailed distribution of the freshwater fishes of South-
Western Australia has been but little studied, but the few facts which
we know show that the tropical fishes of Queensland follow the
principal water-course of that country, the Murray River, far towards
the south and probably to its mouth. The boundary-line then
stretches northwards of Tasmania and New Zealand, coinciding with
the tropic until it strikes the western slope of the Andes, on the South
American Continent, where it again bends southwards to embrace
the system of the Rio de la Plata.
The equatorial zone is divided into four regions:—
A. The Indian region.
B. The African region.
C. The Tropical American region.
D. The Tropical Pacific region.

These four regions diverge into two well-marked divisions, one of


which is characterised by the presence of Cyprinoid fishes,
combined with the development of Labyrinthici; whilst in the other
both these types are absent. The boundary between the Cyprinoid
and Acyprinoid division seems to follow Wallace’s line, a line drawn
from the south of the Philippines between Borneo and Celebes, and
farther south between Bali and Lombock. Borneo abounds in
Cyprinoids; from the Philippine Islands a few only are known at
present, and in Bali two species have been found; but none are
known from Celebes or Lombock, or from islands situated farther
east of them.[20]
Taking into consideration the manner in which Cyprinoids and
Siluroids have been dispersed, we are obliged to place the Indian
region as the first in the order of our treatment; and indeed the
number of its freshwater fishes, which appear to have spread from it
into the neighbouring regions, far exceeds that of the species which
it has received from them.

A. The Indian Region comprises the whole continent of Asia


south of the Himalayas and the Yang-tse-kiang; it includes the
islands to the west of Wallace’s line. Towards the north-east the
island of Formosa, which also by other parts of its fauna leans more
towards the equatorial zone, has received some characteristic
Japanese Freshwater fishes, for instance, the singular Salmonoid
Plecoglossus. Within the geographical boundaries of China the
Freshwater fishes of the tropics pass gradually into those of the
northern zone, both being separated by a broad debateable ground.
The affluents of the great river traversing this district are more
numerous from the south than from the north, and carry the southern
fishes far into the temperate zone. The boundary of this region
towards the north-west is scarcely better defined. Before Persia
passed through the geological changes by which its waters were
converted into brine and finally dried up, it seems to have been
inhabited by many characteristic Indian forms, of which a few still
survive in the tract intervening between Afghanistan and Syria;
Ophiocephalus and Discognathus have each at least one
representative, Macrones has survived in the Tigris, and
Mastacembelus has penetrated as far as Aleppo. Thus, Freshwater
fishes belonging to India, Africa, and Europe, are intermingled in a
district which forms the connecting link between the three continents.
Of the freshwater fishes of Arabia we are perfectly ignorant; so much
only being known that the Indian Discognathus lamta occurs in the
reservoirs of Aden, having, moreover, found its way to the opposite
African coast; and that the ubiquitous Cyprinodonts flourish in
brackish pools of Northern Arabia.
The following is the list of the forms of freshwater fishes
inhabiting this region:[21]—
Percina—
Lates[22] [Africa, Australia] 1 species.
Nandina 7 „
Labyrinthici [Africa] 25 „
Luciocephalidæ 1 „
Ophiocephalidæ [1 species in Africa] 30 „
Mastacembelidæ [3 species in Africa] 10 „
Chromides [Africa, South America]
Etroplus 2 „

Siluridæ—
Clariina [Africa] 12 „
Chacina 3 „
Silurina [Africa, Palæarct.] 72 „
Bagrina [Africa] 50 „
Ariina [Africa, Australia, South America] 40 „
Bagariina 20 „
Rhinoglanina [Africa] 1 „
Hypostomatina [South America] 5 „

Cyprinodontidæ—
Carnivoræ [Palæarct., North America, Africa, South America]
Haplochilus [Africa, South America, North America, Japan] 4 „

Cyprinidæ [Palæarct., N. America, Africa]—


Cyprinina [Palæarct., N. America, Africa] 190 „
Rasborina [Africa, 1 species] 20 „
Semiplotina 4 „
Danionina [Africa] 30 „
Abramidina [Palæarct., N. Amer., Africa] 30 „
Homalopterina 10 „
Cobitidina [Palæarct.] 50 „
Osteoglossidæ [Africa, Australia, S. America] 1 „
Notopteridæ [Africa] 3 „
Symbranchidæ—
Amphipnous 1 „
Monopterus 1 „
Symbranchus [1 species in S. America] 2 „
625 species.

In analysing this list we find that out of 39 families or groups of


freshwater fishes 12 are represented in this region, and that 625
species are known to occur in it; a number equal to two-sevenths of
the entire number of freshwater fishes known. This large proportion
is principally due to the development of numerous local forms of
Siluroids and Cyprinoids, of which the former show a contingent of
about 200, and the latter of about 330 species. The combined
development of those two families, and their undue preponderance
over the other freshwater types, is therefore the principal
characteristic of the Indian region. The second important character of
its fauna is the apparently total absence of Ganoid and
Cyclostomous fishes. Every other region has representatives of
either Ganoids or Cyclostomes, some of both. However, attention
has been directed to the remarkable coincidence of the geographical
distribution of the Sirenidæ and Osteoglossidæ, and as the latter
family is represented in Sumatra and Borneo, it may be reasonably
expected that a Dipnoous form will be found to accompany it. The
distribution of the Sirenidæ and Osteoglossidæ is as follows:—
Tropical America.
Lepidosiren paradoxa. Osteoglossum bicirrhosum.
Arapaima gigas.

Tropical Australia.
Ceratodus forsteri. Osteoglossum leichardti.
Ceratodus miolepis.

East Indian Archipelago.


? Osteoglossum formosum.

Tropical Africa.
Protopterus annectens. Heterotis niloticus.
Not only are the corresponding species found within the same
region, but also in the same river systems; and although such a
connection may and must be partly due to a similarity of habit, yet
the identity of this singular distribution is so striking that it can only
be accounted for by assuming that the Osteoglossidæ are one of the
earliest Teleosteous types which have been contemporaries of and
have accompanied the present Dipnoi since or even before the
beginning of the tertiary epoch.
Of the autochthont freshwater fishes of the Indian region, some
are still limited to it, viz., the Nandina, the Luciocephalidæ (of which
one species only exists in the Archipelago), of Siluroids the Chacina
and Bagariina, of Cyprinoids the Semiplotina and Homalopterina;
others very nearly so, like the Labyrinthici, Ophiocephalidæ,
Mastacembelidæ, of Siluroids the Silurina, of Cyprinoids the
Rasborina and Danionina, and Symbranchidæ.
The regions with which the Indian has least similarity are the
North American and Antarctic, as they are the most distant. Its
affinity to the other regions is of a very different degree:—
1. Its affinity to the Europo-Asiatic region is indicated almost
solely by three groups of Cyprinoids, viz., the Cyprinina, Abramidina,
and Cobitidina. The development of these groups north and south of
the Himalayas is due to their common origin in the highlands of Asia;
but the forms which descended into the tropical climate of the south
are now so distinct from their northern brethren that most of them are
referred to distinct genera. The genera which are still common to
both regions are only the true Barbels (Barbus), a genus which, of all
Cyprinoids, has the largest range over the old world, and of which
some 160 species have been described; and, secondly, the
Mountain Barbels (Schizothorax, etc.), which, peculiar to the Alpine
waters of Central Asia, descend a short distance only towards the
tropical plains, but extend farther into rivers within the northern
temperate districts. The origin and the laws of the distribution of the
Cobitidina appear to have been identical with those of Barbus, but
they have not spread into Africa.
If, in determining the degree of affinity between two regions, we
take into consideration the extent in which an exchange has taken
place of the faunæ originally peculiar to each, we must estimate that
obtaining between the freshwater fishes of the Europo-Asiatic and
Indian regions as very slight indeed.
2. There exists a great affinity between the Indian and African
regions; seventeen out of the twenty-six families or groups found in
the former are represented by one or more species in Africa, and
many of the African species are not even generically different from
the Indian. As the majority of these groups have many more
representatives in India than in Africa, we may reasonably assume
that the African species have been derived from the Indian stock; but
this is probably not the case with the Siluroid group of Clariina, which
with regard to species is nearly equally distributed between the two
regions, the African species being referable to three genera (Clarias,
Heterobranchus, Gymnallabes, with the subgenus Channallabes),
whilst the Indian species belong to two genera only, viz. Clarias and
Heterobranchus. On the other hand, the Indian region has derived
from Africa one freshwater form only, viz. Etroplus, a member of the
family of Chromides, so well represented in tropical Africa and South
America. Etroplus inhabits Southern and Western India and Ceylon,
and has its nearest ally in a Madegasse Freshwater fish,
Paretroplus. Considering that other African Chromides have
acclimatised themselves at the present day in saline water, we think
it more probable that Etroplus should have found its way to India
through the ocean than over the connecting land area; where,
besides, it does not occur.
3. A closer affinity between the Indian and Tropical American
regions than is indicated by the character of the equatorial zone
generally, does not exist. No genus of Freshwater fishes occurs in
India and South America without being found in the intermediate
African region, with two exceptions. Four small Indian Siluroids
(Sisor, Erethistes, Pseudecheneis, and Exostoma) have been
referred to the South American Hypostomatina; but it remains to be
seen whether this combination is based upon a sufficient agreement
of their internal structure, or whether it is not rather artificial. On the
other hand, the occurrence and wide distribution in tropical America
of a fish of the Indian family Symbranchidæ (Symbranchus
marmoratus), which is not only congeneric with, but also most
closely allied to, the Indian Symbranchus bengalensis, offers one of
those extraordinary anomalies in the distribution of animals of which
no satisfactory explanation can be given at present.
4. The relation of the Indian region to the Tropical Pacific region
consists only in its having contributed a few species to the poor
fauna of the latter. This immigration must have taken place within a
recent period, because some species now inhabit fresh waters of
tropical Australia and the South Sea Islands without having in any
way changed their specific characters, as Lates calcarifer, species of
Dules, Plotosus anguillaris; others (species of Arius) are but little
different from Indian congeners. All these fishes must have migrated
by the sea; a supposition which is supported by what we know of
their habits. We need not add that India has not received a single
addition to its freshwater fish-fauna from the Pacific region.
Before concluding these remarks on the Indian region, we must
mention that peculiar genera of Cyprinoids and Siluroids inhabit the
streams and lakes of its alpine ranges in the north. Some of them,
like the Siluroid genera Glyptosternum, Euglyptosternum,
Pseudecheneis, have a folded disk on the thorax between their
horizontally spread pectoral fins; by means of this they adhere to
stones at the bottom of the mountain torrents, and without it they
would be swept away into the lower courses of the rivers. The
Cyprinoid genera inhabiting similar localities, and the lakes into
which the alpine rivers pass, such as Oreinus, Schizothorax,
Ptychobarbus, Schizopygopsis, Diptychus, Gymnocypris, are
distinguished by peculiarly enlarged scales near the vent, the
physiological use of which has not yet been ascertained. These
alpine genera extend far into the Europo-Asiatic region, where the
climate is similar to that of their southern home. No observations
have been made by which the altitudinal limits of fish life in the
Himalayas can be fixed, but it is probable that it reaches the line of
perpetual snow, as in the European Alps which are inhabited by
Salmonoids. Griffith found an Oreinus and a Loach, the former in
abundance, in the Helmund at Gridun Dewar, altitude 10,500 feet;
and another Loach at Kaloo at 11,000 feet.
B. The African Region comprises the whole of the African
continent south of the Atlas and the Sahara. It might have been
conjectured that the more temperate climate of its southern extremity
would have been accompanied by a conspicuous difference of the
fish-fauna. But this is not the case; the difference between the
tropical and southern parts of Africa consists simply in the gradual
disappearance of specifically tropical forms, whilst Siluroids,
Cyprinoids, and even Labyrinthici penetrate to its southern coast; no
new form has entered to impart to South Africa a character distinct
from the central portion of the continent. In the north-east the African
fauna passes the Isthmus of Suez and penetrates into Syria; the
system of the Jordan presenting so many African types that it has to
be included in a description of the African region as well as of the
Europo-Asiatic. This river is inhabited by three species of Chromis,
one of Hemichromis, and Clarias macracanthus, a common fish of
the Upper Nile. This infusion of African forms cannot be accounted
for by any one of those accidental means of dispersal, as
Hemichromis is not represented in the north-eastern parts of Africa
proper, but chiefly on the west coast and in the Central African lakes.
Madagascar clearly belongs to this region. Besides some Gobies
and Dules, which are not true freshwater fishes, four Chromides are
known. To judge from general accounts, its Freshwater fauna is
poorer than might be expected; but, singular as it may appear,
collectors have hitherto paid but little attention to the Freshwater
fishes of this island. The fishes found in the freshwaters of the
Seychelles and Mascarenes are brackish-water fishes, such as
Fundulus, Haplochilus, Elops, Mugil, etc.
The following is the list of the forms of Freshwater fishes
inhabiting this region:—
Dipnoi [Australia, Neotrop.]—
Lepidosiren annectens 1 species.
Polypteridæ 2 „

Percina (Cosmopol.)—
Lates [India, Australia] 1 „
Labyrinthici [India] 5 „
Ophiocephalidæ [India] 1 „
Mastacembelidæ [India] 3 „

Chromides [South America]—


Chromis 23 „
Hemichromis 5 „
Paretroplus 1 „

Siluridæ—
Clariina [India] 14 „
Silurina [India, Palæarct.] 11 „
Bagrina [India] 10 „
Pimelodina [South America] 2 „
Ariina[23] [India, Australia, S. Amer., Patagonia] 4 „
Doradina [South America]—
Synodontis 15 „
Rhinoglanina [India] 2 „
Malapterurina 3 „

Characinidæ [South America]—


Citharinina 2 „
Nannocharacina 2 „
Tetragonopterina—
Alestes 14 „
Crenuchina—
Xenocharax 1 „
Hydrocyonina—
Hydrocyon 4 „
Distichodontina 10 „
Ichthyborina 2 „
Mormyridæ (Gymnarchidæ) 51 „

Cyprinodontidæ—
Carnivoræ [Palæarct., India, S. America—
Haplochilus [India, South America] 7 „
Fundulus [Palæarct., Nearct.] 1 „

Cyprinidæ [Palæarct., India, North America]—


Cyprinina [Palæarct., India, N. America—
Labeo [India] 6 „
Barynotus [India] 2 „
Abrostomus 2 „
Discognathus lamta[24] [India] 1 „
Barbus [Palæarct., India] 35 „

You might also like