You are on page 1of 12

special article

Growth sans Employment: A Quarter Century of


Jobless Growth in India’s Organised Manufacturing

K P Kannan, G Raveendran

T
There has been considerable debate in India about the here is unanimity amongst scholars that the organised
impact of growth on employment especially in the manufacturing sector registered “jobless growth” during
1980-81 to 1990-91. While the average annual rate of
organised manufacturing sector for different periods
growth of gross value added during this period was about 8.66%,
since the early 1980s. However, changes in the coverage the corresponding average annual employment growth was
of the Annual Survey of Industries demand a fresh look merely 0.53%. The resultant employment elasticity was 0.06.
at the issue over a longer period. This paper attempts The reasons advanced by scholars for the near stagnation of
employment are, however, varied. One of the views is that job
such an analysis for 1981-82 to 2004-05. For the period
security regulations introduced in the late 1970s and strengthened
as a whole as well as for two separate periods – the in the early 1980s is the reason for employment stagnation – a
pre- and post-reform phases – the picture that emerges view shared by most official economists and policymakers.
is one of “jobless growth”, due to the combined effect of Some empirical evidence in support of this view has also been
provided by Fallon and Lucas (1993). It has, however, been
two trends that have cancelled each other out. One set
contested by Papola (1994), Ghose (1994) and Bhalotra (1998). It
of industries was characterised by employment-creating was pointed out by Bhalotra that the pattern of employment
growth while another set by employment-displacing growth in factories of different size classes is not consistent with
growth. Over this period, there has been acceleration in the threshold effect that one would expect of the job security
regulations. Her stand has also been supported by Dutta Roy
capital intensification at the expense of creating
(1998) through econometric models.
employment. A good part of the resultant increase in According to a study undertaken by the World Bank (1989), the
labour productivity was retained by the employers as stagnation in factory employment in the 1980s is due to accelera-
the product wage did not increase in proportion to tion in product wages as a result of a union push. This view has
been negated by Papola (1994), Kannan (1994) and Nagaraj (1994).
output growth. The workers as a class thus lost in terms
It has been pointed out by Papola that the increase in labour
of both additional employment and real wages in productivity during the 1980s was much faster than the growth
organised manufacturing sector. in real wages and, therefore, the latter cannot be a reason for
stagnation in employment. He has argued that the decline in em-
ployment in cotton textiles and food products, which accounted
for a sizeable part of factory employment, was caused by closure
of mills due to sickness and rationalisation due to obsolescence.
Kannan demonstrated that the increase in product wage in
organised manufacturing was lower than labour productivity
during 1973 to 1988 although the difference narrowed since the
An earlier version of this paper was presented by the first author at the early 1980s. There was no convincing evidence to show that the
First National Technical Consultation on Employment Policy for India presence of unions was incompatible with dynamic efficiency, i e,
organised by the Ministry of Labour, Government of India and the a higher growth in labour productivity as compared to product
International Labour Office (Sub-regional Office for South Asia), wage. The decline in dynamic efficiency in some industries could
on 21 February 2008, New Delhi. The authors would like to thank
have been due to other factors as industrial sickness (as happened
Arjun Sengupta, T S Papola, Ajit Ghosh, B N Goldar, Arup Mitra and
Sukti Dasgupta for several rounds of discussion on various aspects of the to many textile mills) and supply constraints with regard to
findings of this paper. A special word of thanks is due to Ajaya Kumar certain inputs or problems in capacity utilisation.
Naik for his able computational assistance. However, the authors alone Nagaraj argued that there was a decline in the bargaining
are responsible for errors, if any. power of organised workers during the 1980s and the structure
K P Kannan (kannankp123@gmail.com) and G Raveendran are with the of employment within the organised sector moved towards
National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector, smaller sized establishments. It was, therefore, unlikely that
New Delhi.
unionised labour secured a disproportionate increase in the wage
80 march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10   EPW   Economic & Political Weekly
special article

rate. Nagaraj also found that about one half of real earnings per stagnated, when per capita income grew close to 3% per year
worker was accounted for by an increase in mandays per worker. during the 1990s. Nagaraj, however, seems to have not taken note
The alternative explanations given by Papola (1994), Nagaraj of non-coverage of electricity undertakings in the Annual Survey
(1994) and Bhalotra (1998) for the stagnation of employment in of Industries (ASI) from 1998-99. Nagraj’s conclusions, quite sig-
the organised manufacturing sector in the 1980s are (i) changes in nificant as they are, also call for further investigation on a number
industrial composition, and (ii) increase in actual hours worked of counts. First and foremost, there is need to pay attention to some
per worker indicating a more intensive use of the workforce. database issues since the ASI has excluded certain industries
Nagaraj has also mentioned the overhang of employment by the (mainly departmental undertakings such as electricity and water
end of 1970s caused by a markedly decelerated growth of indus- supply). Second, it is important from a policy point of view
trial output but a sustained growth of employment. In the 1980s, to identify industries that have contributed to jobless growth
when demand picked up, the industries would have first used the performance of the manufacturing sector as a whole. The question
existing stock of labour intensively before deciding to employ is whether jobless growth is a generalised phenomenon or the
additional workers. net result of the jobless growth industries cancelling out the job
Kannan (1994) argued that those who advocate a “flexible” creating growth performance of some other industries. All these
labour market without intervention emphasise only the cost issues can now be examined for a longer period of time of almost
dimension of wages and not the demand dimension arising out of a quarter century.
its role of providing income to the workers. The narrow base of
the domestic market is due to the small size of the organised Scope and Objectives
sector workforce. Hence policies are required to help increase This is the background against which this paper examines the
labour productivity in the unorganised sector and thus the performance of the organised manufacturing sector. In specific
income of a vast segment of the workforce to create a bigger and terms, the objectives of this paper are: (i) to examine the long-
wider base for domestic demand, i e, an argument for expanding term growth performance since the beginning of the 1980s by
the home market. dividing the period into pre- and post-reform years to signify
the onset of major economic reforms in the early 1990s for
Introduction economic liberalisation and globalisation, (ii) to examine the
The growth of employment in the organised manufacturing sector employment implications of growth performance in terms of
during the 1990s has also been analysed by a number of researchers growth in employment as well as the resultant employment
and the general consensus has been that employment growth elasticities so as to further probe the “jobless growth” pheno­
picked up considerably during the first half of the 1990s. Goldar menon reported for earlier but shorter periods, (iii) to subject
(2000) has shown that employment in the organised manufac- the examination of the growth and employment performance
turing sector including electricity registered an impressive annual in terms of industry-groups at the 2-digit level to find if there
rate of growth of about 2.83% during 1990-96. The growth was are any discernible patterns, (iv) to examine the changes in the
mainly contributed by private and joint sector companies as the distribution of income arising out of the growth as between
growth rate registered by the public sector was only 0.39% as capital and labour, and finally (v) to explore the causes under­
against 3.72% by the other firms. Goldar has also shown that lying the performance of the organised manufacturing sector
there was a marked change in the size structure of industries, and put forward certain plausible hypothesis. Some comments
particularly in the 1990s in favour of smaller size classes. While on the larger implications to the economy are also offered for
firms the size classes of 50 to 500 employees gained significantly, further discussion.
the size classes of 2000 and above lost their share of employment
substantially. This structural change must have contributed to The Data Sets for the Present Study
the growth of employment during the 1990s till 1997-98. By us- The present study is aimed at analysing the growth trends in
ing econometric analysis, he has shown that growth in output organised manufacturing at disaggregated levels. The published
(GVA) and real wages have a significant influence on growth in results of the ASI from 1981-82 to 2004-05 at the 3-digit level of
employment. He concluded that changes in the size structure of industrial classification were used for the study. Since the indus-
industries in favour of small and medium-sized factories and the trial classification used for the surveys up to ASI 1988-89 it was
slowdown in the growth in real wages were the factors which NIC-70 and up to ASI 1997-98 it was NIC-87 and thereafter NIC-98,
contributed to employment growth in the 1990s. Nagaraj (2000) the concordance between NIC-70 and NIC-87 with NIC-98 at the
has, however, contested the findings of Goldar and attributed the 3-digit level was used to convert the data sets into NIC-98. The
employment growth during the 1990s to the investment boom estimates at the 2-digit level of industry classification were then
that was witnessed in response to the industrial deregulation and obtained by aggregating the relevant 3-digit level industries. The
trade policy reform. In another article in 2004, Nagaraj has also total employees, including contract workers, supervisory and
noted that jobless growth during the 1980s was followed by an managerial staff, other employees and unpaid family workers,
employment boom for four years during 1992-96 and retrench- were considered for the analysis. The workforce is not collected
ment thereafter. Between 1995-96 and 2001-02, 1.3 million em- in ASI as a direct headcount of the persons in the firm but the
ployees lost their job. These losses have been widespread across average is calculated by dividing the number of mandays worked
major states and industry groups. Real wages have practically with the number of working days.
Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10 81
speciAl article

All the monetary values given here were adjusted for 1993-94 of census sector units. It was also decided to exclude departmen-
prices by using the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) numbers relevant tal undertakings like railway workshops, P&T workshops, etc, from
to specific industry groups at the 2-digit level. The choice of the survey. However, in practice, the sampling frame did include
1993-94 prices was also a matter of convenience as it is one of the the departmental undertakings.
middle years on which the earlier series of national accounts From ASI 2000-01 to ASI 2003-04, the census sector was modi-
were based.1 fied to include units employing 100 and more workers instead of
200 and more workers. In ASI 2004-05, NIC 2004 was introduced
Changes in the Sampling Design and Coverage and a complete change in sampling design was made. These related
There were significant changes in the classification, sampling to: (i) the units employing 100 or more workers were included in
and coverage of industrial units in the ASI over different periods the census sector, (ii) each 4-digit level industry in each state is
of time. Till ASI 1986-87, all large establishments employing 50 or considered as a stratum, (iii) sampling has been done for each of
more workers and using power or 100 or more workers without the years 2004-05 to 2008-09 so that all the units are surveyed
using power and electricity undertakings constituted the “Census during the five-year period, and (iv) a supplementary frame has to
Sector” and the remaining establishments constituted the “Non- be prepared every year and samples have to be selected.
Census or Sample Sector”. In the case of the sample sector, 50% Though the change of sampling design over successive rounds
of the establishments were surveyed every year, covering all the would have introduced some amount of design effect, the unbi-
units once in two years. However, in the case of industries in ased character of the estimates are not expected to be affected,
which the total number of units in the country did not exceed 50 except from ASI 1998-99 onwards when significant changes were
and the units were located in relatively less industrialised states2 introduced in coverage. For example, electricity undertakings
the manufacturing units were surveyed completely every year. were excluded since 1998-99 and departmental undertakings
In the case of other establishments, the units with odd serial were excluded since ASI 1999-2000. The use of published results
numbers were surveyed in the first year and those with even for estimating growth and elasticity has to be, therefore, industry-
numbers during second year, after stratifying by industry and specific taking into account the coverage changes.
district and arranging in descending order of employment. The period of 23 years from 1981-82 to 2004-05 has been
From ASI 1987-88 to ASI 1996-97, the Census sector comprised divided into the pre-reform period up to 1991-92 and the post-
all the units employing 100 or more workers, irrespective of the reform period from 1992-93 onwards for the purpose of the anal-
use of power, and all electricity undertakings. Out of the remain- ysis. The division is guided by the initiation of major and wide-
ing units, if the number of factories at the 3-digit level of NIC in a ranging reforms of economic liberalisation in the country in
state was 20 or less, those units were completely enumerated. 1991-92. The focus of the analysis is primarily on manufacturing
Further, the units located in 12 relatively less industrialised states industries as per NIC-98, as there have been significant changes
and union territories (UTs) (see Note 2) were also completely in the coverage of ASI in the case of industries not classified as
enumerated every year. From amongst the remaining units in manufacturing. The industries which are grouped together and
each industry in each state, one-third of the units subject to a are not considered as part of manufacturing are given in Table 1.
minimum of 20 were selected circular systematically for survey
Table 1: Industries Excluded from the List of Organised Manufacturing in this Study
every year. All the units were surveyed once in three years. NIC Code Description
For ASI 1997-98 the Census Sector was redefined to consist of 14 Extraction of salt
the following: (i) The units belonging to all the 12 less industrialised 40 Electricity, gas, steam and hot water
states/UTs, (ii) in the case of other 16 States/UTs: (a) units having 41 Collection, purification, and distribution of water
200 or more workers, (b) significant industries in terms of NVA as 50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles
reflected in ASI 1993-94, ASI 1994-95 and ASI 1995-96 results, and 52 Retail trade except motor vehicles and motorcycles: repair of personal and
(c) all units belonging to the public sector undertaking (PSU) and household goods
63 Storage and warehousing
the electricity sector.
72 Maintenance and repair of office, accounting and computing machinery
All the remaining units were included in the sample sector.
90 Sewage and refuse disposal, sanitation and similar activities
The sample size at the all-India level was determined on the basis
92 Recreational, cultural and sporting activities
of variability of specific industry group and further allocated to 93 Other service activities
different states on a proportional basis.
In ASI 1998-99, a number of modifications were made to the In addition to the above, the industry, Recycling (NIC-37) was
design adopted in ASI 1997-98. These are: (i) the number of com- also grouped along with non-manufacturing activities, as the
pletely enumerated states/UTs was reduced to Manipur, Meghalaya, industry group was not covered prior to 1998-99.
Nagaland, Tripura and Andaman and Nicobar Island, (ii) NIC-1998
was introduced for industry classification, (iii) electricity under- Growth, Employment and Employment Elasticity
takings registered with Central Electricity Regulatory Authority The performance of the organised manufacturing for the two
were excluded, and (iv) public sector units were not considered time periods as well as the combined period of nearly a quarter
as Census only. century with regard to output (gross value added), employment
In ASI 1999-2000, the same methodology was used except that and the resultant employment elasticity are given in Table 3 (p 83)
the concept of significant units was not used for the identification and Tables 4, 5 (p 84).
82 march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10   EPW   Economic & Political Weekly
special article

The average annual growth of employment in the manufactur- done quite well with many of them registering double digit
ing industries during the period from 1981-82 to 2004-05 was growth rates during the post-reform period. Unlike in the case of
0.78%. During the pre-reform period from 1981-82 to 1991-92, employment no polarisation is discernible.
the employment growth rate in manufacturing industries was
0.40% while it marginally increased to 0.63% during the post- Making Sense of Employment Elasticities
reform period from 1992-93 to 2004-05. Employment elasticity expresses the percentage change in em-
What is important to note is that a majority of industries – 16 ployment growth for a percentage change in growth of output.
out of 22 – registered positive employment growths during the For the pre- and post-reform periods as well as the combined pe-
first period 1981-82 to 1991-92. But this declined to 12 in the sec- riod we have calculated the employment elasticities for organ-
ond period. However, the employment growth in the first period ised manufacturing as a whole and for individual industry groups
was strong enough to show a positive growth in 15 industry at the 2-digit level. It must, however, be noted that employment
groups for the whole period. Six industry groups showed a de- elasticities cannot be used or interpreted uncritically because
cline in employment but this increased to 12 in the post-reform some of them are meaningless and some of them are not useful.
period. Whether this is indicative of a polarisation of the manu- We therefore classify employment elasticities as in Table 2.
facturing sector in terms of “job creating” and “job displacing” In these possible outcomes A2 is clearly meaningless because
ones even while they continue to grow in terms of output is some- the industry is declining and the positive sign is due to the double
thing that we shall return to later in the discussion. Table 2: Possible Outcomes in the Sign of Employment Elasticity (EE) and Their Meaning
As can be seen from Figure 1, the employment growth scenario A  EE Positive B  EE Negative C  EE Zero/Close to Zero

for a period close to a quarter of a century analysed here is not A1 Growth in both B1 Positive growth in C1 Positive growth in
employment and output output but negative output but no
one of continuous stagnation but marked by a period of net in- growth in employment growth or decline
crease (roughly from 1987-88 to 1997-98) preceded and suc- in employment
ceeded by periods of net decline. Whether the recovery in A2 Growth both in B2 Positive growth in C2 No growth or decline
2004-05 to the level of 1996-97 is the beginning of a turnaround employment and output employment but in employment
negative (declining negative growth in and output
to sustained employment growth is something we cannot now industry) output
say given the diverging tendencies of industries. During the
whole period of 24 years a mere 1.77 million jobs were created Table 3: Growth in Output and Employment and Employment Elasticities in Period I
(in average annual %, 1981-82 to 1991-92)
while 0.42 million jobs were destroyed with a net job creation of NIC Industry Name Growth in Growth in Employment
around 1.35 million. This works out to just 0.3% of the workforce Code Gross Value Employment Elasticity
Added (Arc)
in the economy as on 2004-05. The “excluded industries”
A Employment creating growth
accounted for around 12 to 16% of total employment. As such the 16 Tobacco products 9.10 1.37(58.6) 0.15
manufacturing group considered here accounted for 84 to 88% of 18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur 22.53 9.61(76.9) 0.43

Figure 1: Total Employment, Supervisory Staff and Workers (1981-82 to 2004-05, in lakhs) 19 Leather tanning and dressing 10.74 5.65(49.3) 0.53
100
100 21 Paper and paper products 4.69 0.90(12.6) 0.19
23 Coke, refined petro products and nuclear fuel 10.47 2.15(11.1) 0.20
Total persons engaged
80
80 24 Chemicals and chemical products 9.77 2.41(130.6) 0.25
25 Rubber and plastic products 13.42 3.89(57.9) 0.29
60
60 26 Other non-metallic mineral products 12.82 2.17(89.7) 0.17
27 Basic metals 2.20 0.23(13.6) 0.10
Workers
40
40
28 Fabricated metal products 4.51 1.36(36.3) 0.30
29 Machinery and equipments 7.29 2.99(119.2) 0.41
30 Office, accounting and computing machinery 35.92 14.89(22.7) 0.41
20
20
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 6.67 0.46(11.1) 0.07
Supervisory staff
00
32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 23.28 7.92(62.9) 0.34
1981-82
1981-82 1984-85
1984-85 1987-88
1987-88 1990-91
1990-91 1993-94
1993-94 1996-97
1996-97 1999-2000
1999-00 2002-03 2004-05
2002-03 34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 6.09 0.87(15.8) 0.14
36 Furniture, manufacturing nec 7.77 1.33(7.5) 0.17
total employment in organised manufacturing including indus- Total of A 7.93 2.07(775.9) 0.26
tries that are now excluded.
Workers Total Persons Engaged Supervisory Staff B Employment displacing growth
15 Food products and beverages 8.75 -1.71(-215.8) -0.20
Unlike the employment scenario, the growth scenario is
17 Textile 4.33 -1.37(-200.6) -0.32
indeed a buoyant one. All the 22 industry groups examined
20 Wood and products of wood and cork 5.48 -2.00(-13.3) -0.37
here showed positive growth of 7.4% per annum for the whole 35 Other transport equipment 2.27 -0.69(-21.7) -0.30
period as well as the second period relating to post-reform. The Total of B 5.58 -1.45(-451.5) -0.26
pre-reform period witnessed only a marginally lower growth C Neither growth nor employment
rate of around 7% mainly due to the negative growth rates of 22 Publishing, printing, etc -0.02 -0.89(-13.8) 57.31
two industries. In fact, one of them – Medical, Precision and 33 Medical, precision and optical instruments -4.48 -6.89(-30.0) 1.54
Optical Instruments – rebounded in the second period and Total of C -0.84 -2.19(-43.7) 2.62
All manufacturing 6.97 0.40(280.6) 0.06
registered a growth rate of more than 14%. Therefore, in terms
The absolute change in employment (in ‘000) is given in brackets.
of output growth, all the manufacturing industries seem to have Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Summary Results for Factory Sector.

Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10 83


speciAl article

negative signs. B2 is useless because employment is retained even the first period. This resulted in an employment elasticity of just
when the industry concerned is declining in terms of output. C2 0.09. Even this marginal increase is mainly due to the perfor­
is also not useful since it is a case of stagnation. Based on this mance in the last year of the second period, i e, 2004-05. Other-
classification the results of our exercise are given in Tables 3 to 5. wise the employment elasticity would have been a lower one of
The 2-digit level industry employment elasticities present a 0.01. Figure 1 illustrates this point clearly. Industries shed jobs
differentiated picture. During the pre-reform period 16 out of 22 that increased to 10 from the earlier six and together they ac-
industry groups showed positive employment elasticities arising counted for 43% of the total employment in 1992-93.
out of what we call “employment creating growth”. These varied For the whole period of 24 years, the picture is somewhat
from a high of 0.53 in Leather Tanning and Dressing to a low of brighter from an employment point of view because the employ-
0.10 in Basic Metals. We may recall here that limited economic ment elasticity inched up to 0.10. However, this is as good or
reforms in capacity utilisation, broad-banding and so on were ini- bad as jobless growth since the total employment effect was
tiated during the 1980s that confined to internal economic re- only 8.29 million in 2004-05 which is less than the peak of
form. The main reason for hardly any growth in employment 8.78 million in 1995-96.
during this period is due to the performance of six industry The picture emerging from the employment elasticities is one
groups who accounted for more than half the employment in the of acceleration in capital intensification in organised manufac-
beginning of the period. Therefore a majority of the industries turing at the expense of creating employment. While we must
which performed well, both in terms of employment and output recognise that this is not a generalised phenomenon across all
growth, accounted for only a relatively small share of total em- industry groups, but the net effect of employment creating
ployment to begin with. What is striking is the job loss in two growth in some industries and the employment displacing
major industry groups, viz, Food Products and Beverages and growth of another group. While the increase in number of such
Textiles which together accounted for 42% of the employment individual groups should be a matter of concern, their decreasing
share. This has resulted in an employment elasticity of just 0.06 share in employment holds a ray of hope.
which is close to zero. The main points arising from the analysis so far may be
Despite a higher rate of growth in output during the post- summed up as follows. First, the higher growth in organised
reform period, the growth in employment witnessed only a very manufacturing both during the pre- and post-reform periods is
marginal improvement to 0.63% per annum as against 0.40% in due to an increase in labour productivity. Second, the process

Table 4: Growth in Output and Employment and Employment Elasticities in Period II Table 5: Growth in Output and Employment and Employment Elasticities Over the
(in average annual %, 1992-93 to 2004-05) Larger Period (in average annual %, 1981-82 to 2004-05)
NIC Industry Name Growth in Growth in Employment NIC Industry Name Growth in Growth in Employment
Code Gross Value Employment Elasticity Code Gross Value Employment Elasticity
Added (Arc) Added (Arc)
A Employment creating growth A Employment creating growth
15 Food products and beverages 5.11 0.47(73.0) 0.09 16 Tobacco products 6.80 0.71(70.9) 0.10
18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur 10.60 9.58(300.0) 0.90 18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur 15.55 9.92(399.0) 0.64
19 Leather tanning and dressing 3.49 2.28(35.5) 0.65 19 Leather tanning and dressing 6.93 3.54(82.5) 0.51
21 Paper and paper products 4.45 1.13(22.4) 0.25 21 Paper and paper products 3.84 1.24(44.0) 0.32
23 Coke, refined petro products and nuclear fuel 9.24 1.33(11.6) 0.14 23 Coke, refined petro products and nuclear fuel 11.58 2.31(32.5) 0.20
24 Chemicals and chemical products 5.60 1.33(115.2) 0.24 24 Chemicals and chemical products 8.30 2.11(299.7) 0.25
25 Rubber and plastic products 9.08 3.62(105.7) 0.40 25 Rubber and plastic products 11.28 3.96(179.8) 0.35
26 Other non-metallic mineral products 7.94 0.99(58.3) 0.12 26 Other non-metallic mineral products 8.62 1.47(149.1) 0.17
28 Fabricated metal products 3.83 0.98(35.3) 0.26 28 Fabricated metal products 3.77 1.06(68.6) 0.28
33 Medical, precision and optical instruments 13.79 5.03(27.6) 0.37 29 Machinery and equipment 7.25 1.01(90.0) 0.14
34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 13.86 4.46(137.2) 0.32 30 Office, accounting and computing machinery 19.69 5.50(18.3) 0.28
36 Furniture, manufacturing nec 11.44 8.05(106.6) 0.70 32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 15.34 2.72(47.0) 0.18
Total of A 7.38 2.07(1028.5) 0.28 33 Medical, precision and optical instruments 6.37 0.24(3.3) 0.04
B Employment displacing growth 34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 9.90 2.91(162.7) 0.29
16 Tobacco products 5.06 -0.35(-20.4) -0.07 36 Furniture, manufacturing nec 8.06 5.37(123.3) 0.67
17 Textile 5.34 -0.15(-24.8) -0.03 Total of A 8.64 2.26(1770.8) 0.26
20 Wood and products of wood and cork 0.31 -2.15(-15.1) -6.94 B Job displacing growth
22 Publishing, printing, etc 1.69 -2.28(-36.8) -1.35 15 Food products and beverages 6.50 -0.06(-20.2) -0.01
27 Basic metals 8.88 -1.19(-89.4) -0.13 17 Textile 4.96 -0.53(-178.9) -0.11
29 Machinery and equipments 7.33 -1.21(-68.6) -0.16 20 Wood and products of wood and cork 0.09 -1.57(-22.2) -16.55
30 Office, accounting and computing machinery 7.29 -2.46(-9.0) -0.34 22 Publishing, printing, etc 0.35 -1.44(-45.8) -4.07
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 6.24 -0.57(-16.8) -0.09 27 Basic metals 7.13 -0.09(11.8) -0.01
32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 9.62 -1.62(-22.1) -0.17 31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 6.46 -0.03(-1.5) -0.00
35 Other transport equipment 10.63 -4.13(-121.9) -0.39 35 Other transport equipment 6.79 -2.44(-141.5) -0.36
Total of B 7.41 -0.93(-424.9) -0.13 Total of B 6.05 -0.45(-421.9) -0.07
All manufacturing 7.39 0.63(603.6) 0.09 All manufacturing 7.41 0.78(1348.9) 0.10
The absolute change in employment (in ‘000) is given in brackets. The absolute change in employment (in ‘000) is given in brackets.
Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Summary Results for Factory Sector. Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Summary Results for Factory Sector.

84 march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10   EPW   Economic & Political Weekly


special article

of jobless growth is not uniform across industries. In fact, Figure 2: Index of Output of Emoluments in Organised Manufacturing Industries
(1981-82 = 100, Index of GVA employment and emolument)
there is a divergence in the situation with one set of industries 600
600
able to register employment creating growth while another set
registering jobless growth. Since they cancel each other out, the 500
500
GVA
performance of the organised manufacturing as a whole has
400
400
been a dismal one. Third, the jobless growth phenomenon has
been going on for far too long a period, i e, almost a quarter of 300
300

a century. Fourth, the jobless growth process has profound


200
200
implications for the distribution of the gross surplus as between Emoluments
capital and labour. If labour has not benefited in terms of 100
100
expanded employment opportunities, has it benefited in terms
00
of wage share as well as real wages? We turn to this question in 1981-82 1984-85 1987-88 1990-91 1993-94 1996-97 1999-2000 2002-03
1981-82 1984-85 1987-88 1990-91 1993-94 1996-97 1999-00 2002-03 2004-05
the following section.
Figure 3: Share of Total Emoluments of Employees, Wages of Workers and
Trends in Labour Productivity and Share of Wages Wages of Supervisors (as % of Gross Value Added)
45
45
When an industry grows, it could result in greater employment
as a result of expansion of capacity resulting in creating more Total emoluments
employment to the workers as a class. Or, it could result in higher 35
35

wages if growth is the result of increasing capital intensity.


Both these are also possible depending on the character of 25
Wages
the techno­logy as well as the extent of the sharing of the value
added as between capital and labour. The case of organised
15
15
manufacturing examined here is one of jobless growth. The share
of wages has fallen sharply indicating a fall in product wage Other than wages
50
1981-82
1981-82 1984-85
1984-85 1987-88
1987-88 1990-91
1990-91 1993-94
1993-94 1996-97
1996-97 1999-2000
1999-00 2002-03 2004-05
2002-03
Table 6: Percentage Share of Gross Value Added (GVA) and Employment in
Organised Manufacturing
NIC Description 1981-82 1992-93 2004-05 (i e, share of wages in the value added per worker) which is the
Code GVA Employ- GVA Employ- GVA Employ- relevant element of cost of labour in production. However, it is
ment ment ment
A Employment creating growth also important to examine the wage as real wage to workers rep-
27 Basic metals 16.0 8.5 12.8 8.7 18.9 7.0 resenting its purchasing power or income.
24 Chemicals and chemical products 12.9 7.0 19.1 8.7 16.6 9.5 When organised manufacturing as a whole grows at an
15 Food products and beverages 8.7 19.6 9.3 16.5 7.3 16.2 annual growth rate of 7.4% for nearly a quarter century what it
28 Fabricated metal products 4.7 3.6 3.2 3.7 2.3 3.9 means is that it has increased its output by more than five times.
34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 4.3 2.5 3.6 2.6 6.7 4.1
This could be compared with the increase in share of wages that
26 Other non-metallic mineral products 4.2 5.4 5.1 6.1 5.0 6.3
represents the “product wage”. There was hardly any significant
21 Paper and paper products 3.1 1.9 2.0 2.0 1.5 2.1
increase in employment except for a short interim period from
23 Coke, refined petroleum products
and nuclear fuel 2.9 0.7 5.7 0.9 11.4 1.0 1989-90 to 1995-96. The aggregate results are worth noting. As
25 Rubber and plastic products 1.7 1.8 3.1 2.6 3.0 3.7 we can see in Figure 2, while output grew by more than five
36 Furniture, manufacturing nec 1.2 0.8 0.9 0.9 1.4 2.1 times, the total emoluments paid to employees (wages to work-
33 Medical, precision and ers and supervisory staff combined) grew only by a little more
optical instruments 1.1 0.8 0.4 0.4 0.9 0.7
than two and three quarter times (i e, 277%). This means that a
19 Leather tanning and dressing 0.7 1.0 0.9 1.5 0.5 1.8
good part of the productivity increase – a doubling of labour
18 Wearing apparel, dressing and
dyeing of fur 0.4 0.7 1.5 2.0 1.7 5.4 productivity measured by GVA per employee – was retained by
Total of A 61.9 54.3 67.6 56.6 77.2 63.8 employers. The increase in total emoluments being less than the
B Job displacing growth increase in output resulted in a sharp decline in the share of
16 Tobacco products 1.6 5.8 1.8 6.4 1.7 5.7 wages from 41% in 1981-82 to around 32% in 1991-92 and then to
17 Textile 14.4 22.4 10.7 18.2 6.7 16.6 around 25% in 2004-05.
20 Wood and products of wood and cork 0.8 1.0 0.4 0.9 0.2 0.6
There is a sub-text in this story of a steady decline in the share
22 Publishing, printing, etc 4.0 2.3 1.6 2.0 1.2 1.4
of wages. As we noted above the total emoluments paid called
29 Machinery and equipment 6.4 5.0 6.3 6.6 5.1 5.3
share of wages can be split into two categories, i e, share of wages
30 Office, accounting and
computing machinery 0.1 0.1 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.3 to workers and the share of wages to the supervisory (including
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 5.3 3.4 4.9 3.3 2.9 2.9 managerial) staff. Two things seem to have happened. First, the
32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 0.7 0.8 2.6 1.6 1.6 1.2 share of wages of workers declined from around 27% in 1981-82
35 Other transport equipment 5.0 4.7 3.1 4.0 2.9 2.2 to 21% in 1991-92 and to 12% 2004-05. Second, the share of wages
Total of B 38.3 45.5 32.4 43.5 22.8 36.2 of supervisors declined from 14.5 in 1981-82 to 12% in 1991-92
Total manufacturing 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 and remained at that level up to 2004-05 (Figure 3). What this
Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10 85
speciAl article

tells us is that the decline in the share of wages of workers has semi-skilled or skilled but generally with lower educational
been far in excess of the decline in the share of wages to super­ attainments and engaged in manual work relating to production,
visors. The workers’ share went down by half whereas the super- transportation, etc.
visors’ share went down by less than one-fourth. The share of
supervisory (including managerial) staff in total employees Increasing Capital Intensity
remained more or less constant around 22 to 23% throughout the Having found that employment elasticity is very close to zero in
whole period. On the whole the evidence suggests that much of organised manufacturing in India despite a trend rate of growth
the decline in the share of wages has been at the expense of the of output of over 7% during the last quarter century, what
low paid blue-collar workers. emerges is the indisputable fact that there has been a consistent
The industry-wise details of the fall in share of wages to all increase in labour productivity. We now investigate the extent of
employees as well as workers are a generalised phenomenon the increase in labour productivity during the two periods for the
across industries during the whole period. The only exception different industry groups and go into the factors behind such an
seems to be Wearing Apparel, Dressing and Dyeing of Fur where increase. When capital is substituted for labour, it leads to an
the sharp decline during the first period has been reversed during increase in labour productivity. However, if the growth in labour
the second period. This could be due to the dismantling of the productivity is equal to the growth in capital labour ratio (capital
Multi Fibre Agreement governing the export of apparels. The intensity) and no decline in capital productivity then the situa-
sharpest fall has been in six industry groups, viz, Coke, tion is characterised as technological upgradation. If there is
Refined Petroleum Products and Nuclear Fuel, Basic Metals, positive growth in capital productivity, then part of the growth
Other Transport Equipment, Tobacco Products, Other Non- in labour productivity is due to substitution of capital for labour
Metallic Minerals, and Office, Accounting and Computing as another part due to increased efficiency arising out of techno-
Machinery, in that order. logical upgradation. What we find here is a case of sustained
The industry-wise picture also show that the fall in share of increase in capital intensity that has resulted in substitution of
wages to workers has been much faster than share of wages to capital for labour as well as technological upgradation for organ-
supervisors across industries. The picture emerging is one ised manufacturing as a whole. However, there are notable varia-
that is loaded against the interests of workers who are either tions when we examine the 22 industrial groups.
This takes us first and foremost to the question of measure-
Table 7: Share of Emoluments to Employees, Wages to Workers and Wages to
Supervisors in Gross Value Added (in %) ment of capital. In economic theory, the measurement of capital
NIC Description Total Emoluments/GVA Total Wages of Worker/ has been a controversial theme. Measuring capital stock poses
Code GVA
1981-82 1991-92 2004-05 1981-82 1991-92 2004-05 too many inherent problems such as the age-composition, tech-
15 Food products and beverages 38.7 33.7 29.1 24.3 21.6 16.2 nological changes embodied in newer capital equipments and so
16 Tobacco products 55.2 31.6 19.6 45.0 27.9 15.4 on. However, scholars engaged in empirical research have to
17 Textile 56.7 48.0 36.0 45.8 38.3 24.3 resort to some measurement of capital by choosing from feasible
18 Wearing apparel, dressing and alternatives. While examining the performance of organised
dyeing of fur 44.8 21.8 44.3 30.7 14.9 27.6
manufacturing in India, Ghose (1994) adopted a method by using
19 Leather tanning and dressing 51.8 36.3 41.8 38.2 25.8 26.8
20 Wood and products of wood and cork 40.3 32.9 37.9 28.7 24.0 22.2
the estimates of net capital stock prepared by the Central Statistical
21 Paper and paper products 38.9 29.1 30.1 24.8 19.5 17.4 Organisation (CSO) for broad sectors of the economy at 1980-81
22 Publishing, printing, etc 58.9 47.7 34.8 36.4 30.0 12.6 prices. The estimates for the ASI sectors “Aggregate Industry” and
23 Coke, refined petroleum products “Manufacturing” were available for the year 1973-74. The esti-
and nuclear fuel 15.7 13.2 4.4 8.8 8.3 2.4 mates for individual industries were derived for the year 1973-74
24 Chemicals and chemical products 30.3 24.1 17.8 15.2 13.4 7.0 by using the ratio of book value of net fixed capital of the industry
25 Rubber and plastic products 38.5 24.7 24.3 23.2 15.0 12.7
to the total book value of all the industries in the manufacturing
26 Other non-metallic mineral products 42.1 20.8 19.1 28.9 14.1 10.6
sector. The estimates of capital consumption computed by the
27 Basic metals 36.2 29.1 12.5 23.8 18.4 6.8
CSO for the years 1980-81 to 1988-89 were then regressed against
28 Fabricated metal products 41.1 36.0 34.5 19.3 21.8 18.3
29 Machinery and equipment 42.1 41.0 32.0 23.7 24.2 14.1
the corresponding values of gross capital stock and the coefficient
30 Office, accounting and 6.05 was taken to measure the standard rate of depreciation.
computing machinery 54.5 21.8 25.5 31.2 8.2 6.6 The NCS for subsequent years were then estimated by using the
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 37.8 34.9 28.9 20.8 18.6 13.5 following formula
32 Radio, TV and
communication equipment 50.2 25.2 28.4 26.8 12.5 9.6 NCSt+1 = d[NCSt + (NCS*t+1 – NCS*t) + DPt+1]
33 Medical, precision and
optical Instruments 41.6 38.9 26.5 20.8 20.8 10.9 where NCS = net capital stock
34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 37.3 35.9 21.5 22.1 22.7 11.1 NCS* = book value of net fixed capital reported in ASI
35 Other transport equipment 67.9 55.5 23.2 47.4 37.8 12.1 deflated by GDP deflator for Gross Fixed Capital Formation
36 Furniture, manufacturing nec 47.7 34.7 31.5 31.6 24.4 19.0 (1980-81=100)
All manufacturing 42.4 32.3 22.7 27.5 21.0 11.8 DP = Value of depreciation reported in ASI deflated by the
40+ Non-manufacturing 34.7 27.8 16.4 22.1 17.8 7.8 same deflators
Total ASI 41.1 31.6 22.6 26.6 20.5 11.7 d = estimated standard rate of depreciation
86 march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10   EPW   Economic & Political Weekly
special article

The NCS employed in any particular year is then taken as the sector. Further, the gross fixed capital formation for each year
average of the preceding and the current year from 1979-80 was obtained by adding the share of depreciation
of fixed capital addition during the year to the net fixed capital
(NCSt+1 + NCSt)
NCSt+1 = formation. For the years prior to 1979-80, gross fixed capital for-
2 mation was computed by using the total depreciation and depre-
The limitation of his method is that the industry-wise net ciation rates of 1980-81. The wholesale price indices of manufac-
capital stock for 1973-74 was derived by using the share of book turing sector were used for obtaining the estimates of gross fixed
value of net fixed capital which is a crude approximation. Fur- capital formation at 1993-94 prices. The depreciation rates for
ther, the depreciation rate has been derived externally for all the different years as computed from ASI data were used for obtain-
industries taken together by using a regression analysis of the ing net fixed capital stock for different years. The methodology
data sets of just eight years. It has nothing to do with the actual that we have used is given in the Appendix.
depreciation provided by specific industry groups. We discuss the results, given in Tables 8, 9 and Table 10 (p 88),
Goldar (2004) adopted the perpetual inventory method in by keeping the broad division of industries as between “Employ-
which he constructed the series of gross investment in fixed ment Creating Growth” and “Employment Displacing Growth”.
capital for the entire manufacturing sector at constant prices of During the first period there has been a modest growth in NCS of
1981-82. It was done by subtracting the book value of fixed assets around 1%. However this has resulted in an impressive growth
in the previous year from that in the current year and adding to in labour productivity (O/L) of 5.8% largely contributed by an
that the reported depreciation in fixed assets in the current year. equally impressive growth in capital productivity (O/K). Capital
The implicit price deflators of gross fixed capital formation in intensity (K/L) increased by around 4.3% per year. Given the limited
registered manufacturing sector were used for converting gross and internal economic reforms, it could be hypothesised that the
investment to constant prices. A constant depreciation of 5% was impressive growth in labour productivity could be due to a better
assumed for obtaining net fixed capital. and higher utilisation of capital and additional capital infusion.
In this paper, we have used a similar methodology, at the This might have also been accompanied by better management
2-digit industry level rather than for the aggregate manufacturing and related internal efficiency. This period in fact witnessed
the creation of 7,76,000 new jobs and displacement of 4,95,000
Table 8: Growth Rate of Net Capital Stock (NCS), Labour Productivity (O/L), Capital
jobs resulting in a net employment creation of just 2,81,000
Productivity (K/L) and Capital Intensity (O/K) in the Organised Manufacturing during
1983-84 and 1991-92
Table 9: Growth Rate of Net Capital Stock (NCS), Labour Productivity (O/L), Capital
NIC Description 1991-92 to 1983-84 Productivity (K/L) and Capital Intensity (O/K) in the Organised Manufacturing during
2- Digit NCS O/L K/L O/K 1992-93 and 2004-05
A Employment creating growth NIC Description 2004-05 to 1992-93
16 Tobacco products 9.5 5.84 7.68 -1.71 2- Digit NCS O/L K/L O/K
18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur 17.8 14.57 6.02 8.07 A Employment creating growth
19 Leather tanning and dressing -1.4 1.99 -7.49 10.25 15 Food products and beverages 6.02 4.62 5.52 -0.86
21 Paper and paper products -0.2 7.10 -1.07 8.25 18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur 15.16 0.93 5.09 -3.96
23 Coke, refined petroleum products 19 Leather tanning and dressing 9.70 1.19 7.26 -5.66
and nuclear fuel -2.1 16.63 -4.64 22.30 21 Paper and paper products 16.84 3.29 15.54 -10.60
24 Chemicals and chemical products 8.4 5.92 5.93 -0.01 23 Coke, refined petroleum products and
25 Rubber and plastic products 8.3 7.70 5.11 2.46 nuclear fuel 15.48 7.81 13.97 -5.40
26 Other non-metallic mineral products 7.0 10.43 6.08 4.10 24 Chemicals and chemical products 7.24 4.21 5.83 -1.53
27 Basic metals 6.6 5.00 10.46 -4.94 25 Rubber and plastic products 10.55 5.27 6.69 -1.33
28 Fabricated metal products -1.8 3.07 -3.19 6.46 26 Other non-metallic mineral products 9.53 6.89 8.46 -1.45
29 Machinery and equipments 5.8 2.75 2.80 -0.05 28 Fabricated metal products 7.16 2.82 6.12 -3.11
30 Office, accounting and computing machinery 12.7 17.01 -6.05 24.54 33 Medical, precision and optical instruments 5.39 8.34 0.34 7.98
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 2.7 4.69 2.28 2.36 34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 8.64 9.00 4.00 4.80
32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 11.1 11.89 5.23 6.33 36 Furniture, manufactured nec 12.80 3.13 4.40 -1.21
34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 6.7 4.64 5.34 -0.67 Total of A 10.23 5.20 7.99 -2.59
36 Furniture, manufactured nec 5.2 5.16 2.04 3.05 B Employment displacing growth
16 Tobacco products 4.74 5.43 5.10 0.31
Total of A 5.2 6.15 3.88 2.18
17 Textile 6.67 5.50 6.83 -1.25
B Employment displacing growth
15 Food products and beverages 6.4 3.52 5.59 -1.96 20 Wood and products of wood and cork 2.41 2.52 4.66 -2.05
17 Textile -1.3 5.62 0.80 4.78 22 Publishing, printing, etc 11.50 4.06 14.10 -8.80
20 Wood and products of wood and cork 1.7 6.18 4.10 2.00 27 Basic metals 5.00 10.20 6.26 3.70
35 Other transport equipment 0.1 2.81 1.26 1.54 29 Machinery and equipments 1.56 8.64 2.80 5.68
Total of B 1.6 4.50 2.52 1.94 30 Office, accounting and computing machinery 16.13 10.00 19.06 -7.61
C Neither growth nor employment 31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 3.77 6.85 4.36 2.39
22 Publishing, printing, etc -1.8 1.17 -0.18 1.35 32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 13.37 11.43 15.24 -3.31
33 Medical, precision and optical instruments 23.4 -0.89 36.73 -27.51 35 Other transport equipment 6.97 15.40 11.58 3.42
Total of C 4.7 0.76 8.42 -7.06 Total of B 5.59 8.42 6.58 1.73
Total manufacturing 4.5 5.78 4.26 1.46 Total manufacturing 7.94 6.72 7.26 -0.50
Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Summary Results for Factory Sector. Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Summary Results for Factory Sector.

Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10 87


speciAl article

(an annual average of 28,000) against an annual output growth Figure 4: Index of Total Capital Stock and Capital Intensity (K/L) in the Organised
Manufacturing Sector during 1983-84 and 2004-05
rate of close to 7%. Hence the employment elasticity that is closer 500
500
to zero (0.06).
The situation in the second period (i e, since the beginning of 400
400

wide ranging reforms) has been quite different except the overall
jobless growth performance (see Table 9). First of all the growth 300
300

in NCS at 7.9% per annum is close to double of that in the earlier


200
200
period. This gave rise to a high growth in capital intensity of Total capital stock

2.3% per annum and resulting in the growth of labour produc- 100
100
tivity at 6.72%. The growth in capital productivity has been K/L
negative. What this suggests is that the growth in capital stock 00
1983-84 1986-87 1989-90 1992-93 1995-96 1998-99 2001-02 2004-05
has been, on the whole, to replace labour without the kind of 1983-84 1986-87 1989-90 1992-93 1995-96 1998-99 2001-02 2004-05

technological upgradation of the previous period. This could be This overall picture, while quite instructive to understand the
due to the fact that the scope for further technological upgrada- broad trends in the organised manufacturing, has to be further
tion was not so pronounced. But the output growth increased to probed in terms of what we call “Employment Creating Growth”
around 7.4%. New employment of a little more than a million industries and “Employment Displacing Growth” industries.
was created but around 4,02,000 jobs was destroyed thus creat-
ing net employment of around 6,04,000. Given the high growth Wage as Cost to Employers and Income to Workers
in output, employment elasticity remained closer to zero but The distribution of surplus generated in a production system
increased to 0.09. between workers and capitalists is a classical problem because of its
For the whole period of 24 years, the picture (Table 10) is one of implications on the long-term development of capitalism in gen-
sustained increase in NCS followed by an impressive increase in eral and the welfare of the workers in particular. As far as the per-
labour productivity (6.3%) that saw replacement of labour with formance of the organised manufacturing sector in India is con-
capital through a continuous increase in capital intensity (6% cerned, we have seen that the impressive growth performance has
growth in K/L) along with minimal technological upgradation (a been achieved by increasing labour productivity and a correspond-
growth rate of 0.30% in capita productivity, i e, O/K). ing increase in capital intensity. We have also seen that a higher
Table 10: Growth Rate of Net Capital Stock (NCS), Labour Productivity (O/L), Capital
proportion of the incremental surplus has gone to capital resulting
Productivity (K/L) and Capital Intensity (O/K) in the Organised Manufacturing during in a declining share of wages to all employees in general (except
1983-84 and 2004-05
perhaps a thin layer of managerial staff) and workers in particular.
NIC Description 2004-05 to 1983-84
2- Digit NCS O/L K/L O/K There are two aspects of wages here. When expressed in terms
A Employment creating growth of product prices (i e, share of wages in value added) it represents
16 Tobacco products 7.99 5.22 6.77 -1.45 the cost to the employers and a declining share means a declining
18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur 17.88 5.49 5.83 -0.32
cost of labour. When expressed in purchasing power terms, or
19 Leather tanning and dressing 6.32 2.06 2.22 -0.16
what is usually referred to as real wages, it represents the income
21 Paper and paper products 9.53 3.69 7.68 -3.70
to the workers. These two dimensions of wages along with output
23 Coke, refined petroleum products
and nuclear fuel 8.46 12.34 5.40 6.58 growth are given in Table 11. Real wages were derived by deflating
24 Chemicals and chemical products 7.91 5.47 5.34 0.12 money wages with the Consumer Price Index for Industrial Workers.
25 Rubber and plastic products 11.30 6.29 6.84 -0.52
Table 11: Growth Rates in Labour Productivity, Product Wage and Real Wage
26 Other non-metallic mineral products 8.37 6.74 7.01 -0.25 (Annual average growth in %)
28 Fabricated metal products 4.38 2.63 3.10 -0.45 Period Output Product Wage Real Wage
29 Machinery and equipments 4.02 5.82 3.02 2.72 Workers Supervisors All Employees

30 Office, accounting and computing machinery 15.15 12.53 7.53 4.65 Period I 6.54 3.68 3.46 2.58 3.26
32 Radio, TV and communication equipment 12.38 11.22 10.24 0.89 Period II 6.72 3.69 0.27 3.79 1.60
Whole period 6.58 3.73 1.55 3.86 2.50
33 Medical, precision and optical instruments 12.95 5.07 12.57 -6.67
34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 8.60 6.74 4.75 1.90
36 Furniture, manufactured nec 9.71 1.76 2.62 -0.84
The implications of the findings are quite significant. The
Total of A 8.42 6.10 5.69 0.39 growth rate in product wage was a little more than half during
B Employment displacing growth both the periods. However, the real wage increase was only
15 Food products and beverages 6.92 3.53 5.49 -1.85 around half of the growth in output during the first period that
17 Textile 4.14 5.43 4.70 0.70 declined to around one-third during the second period when all
20 Wood and products of wood and cork 1.79 0.61 3.39 -2.69 employees are taken into account. But the losers in this scenario
22 Publishing, printing, etc 6.23 2.02 7.83 -5.38
are the workers. While their real wage growth was less than but
27 Basic metals 6.44 8.95 7.80 1.07
closer to the product wage during the first period, it declined
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 3.46 5.94 3.38 2.48
sharply to one-fourth of a per cent in the second period. In actual
35 Other transport equipment 3.44 10.03 6.21 3.60
Total of B 5.75 6.12 5.98 0.13
terms, workers hardly experienced an increase in real wages
Total manufacturing 7.11 6.29 5.97 0.30 during the second period (post-reform) while the supervisory and
Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Summary Results for Factory Sector. managerial staff experienced a 3.8% increase in real wages. This
88 march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10   EPW   Economic & Political Weekly
special article

has resulted in a long-term annual growth of 3.9% in real wages covering a period of close to a quarter of a century has shown
for supervisors and just 1.6 for workers. Given the fact that the per that at the 2-digit level there have been two opposing trends.
capita earnings of supervisory staff is two times higher than the One set of industries showing employment creating growth
workers in early 1980s, such an uneven growth meant a widen- and another set showing employment displacing growth. It is the
ing of inequality in the earnings as between supervisory staff and net effect of these two opposing forces that have led to a near
workers. The ratio of earnings at the end of the period was 3.3:1. absence of employment growth. This shows that labour market
Table 12: Industry-wise Growth in Average GVA and Emoluments Per Employee rigidity does not seem to operate across the board, if at all it is a
(% growth per year) major factor. It is also important to note that the so-called labour
NIC Description GVA Per Employee Emolument Per Employee
Code Period I Period II Whole Period I Period II Whole market rigidity argument in the Indian context boils down to a
Period Period particular clause in the Industrial Disputes Act – Chapter VB –
15 Food products and beverages 10.64 4.62 6.57 9.11 2.59 5.26
that mandates prior permission of the government for an enter-
16 Tobacco products 7.63 5.43 6.05 1.79 1.23 1.38
prise with more than 100 workers if it wants to retrench its workers.
17 Textile 5.79 5.50 5.52 4.02 2.93 3.46
In case permission is granted, the employer is required to give
18 Wearing apparel, dressing
and dyeing of fur 11.79 0.93 5.12 4.00 5.73 5.07 a three-month notice to the worker providing reasons for the
19 Leather tanning and dressing 4.82 1.19 3.27 1.17 2.30 2.32 proposed retrenchment. However, such a provision is not appli-
20 Wood and products of wood cable to a number of categories of workers such as (a) managerial
and cork 7.64 2.52 1.69 5.49 2.53 1.42
or supervisory staff or to staff in administrative responsibili-
21 Paper and paper products 3.76 3.29 2.56 0.82 2.69 1.43
ties, (b) casual or temporary workers including badli workers,
22 Publishing, printing, etc 0.88 4.06 1.82 -1.22 1.85 -0.49
23 Coke, refined petroleum products
and (c) workers who have not yet completed one year of continu-
and nuclear fuel 8.15 7.81 9.06 6.31 1.69 3.25 ous service. Further a wage ceiling is applied to workers who
24 Chemicals and chemical products 7.18 4.21 6.06 4.76 2.33 3.62 are subjected to this provision which is Rs 6,500 per month (as
25 Rubber and plastic products 9.17 5.27 7.04 4.42 4.87 4.92 on 2005). All these have restricted the applicability of the provi-
26 Other non-metallic mineral sion under Chapter VB to a narrow segment of workers.
products 10.43 6.89 7.05 2.91 3.52 3.43
Despite such a restricted application, there is so much heat
27 Basic metals 1.97 10.20 7.23 -0.23 2.25 2.37
28 Fabricated metal products 3.11 2.82 2.69 1.76 1.93 1.91 generated over this provision especially by those who are seen
29 Machinery and equipments 4.18 8.64 6.19 3.90 6.32 4.94 as the advocates of economic liberalisation and globalisation.
30 Office, accounting and Employers, despite their opposition to the clause, do not seem to
computing machinery 18.31 10.00 13.45 7.95 10.21 9.76 bother too much about when it comes to investment decisions or
31 Electrical machinery and apparatus 6.19 6.85 6.49 5.33 5.55 5.24 are confident of dealing with it. It is quite possible that the con-
32 Radio, TV and communication
testation is more ideological than a practical hindrance to invest-
equipment 14.23 11.43 12.28 6.63 12.25 9.54
33 Medical, precision and
ment and increasing employment. Capital is certainly interested
optical instruments 2.59 8.34 6.12 1.90 5.22 4.06 in unhindered control of labour that would give them much flexi­
34 Motor vehicles, trailers, etc 5.17 9.00 6.79 4.78 4.29 4.26 bility and discretion in the manner and pace of accumulation.
35 Other transport equipment 2.98 15.40 9.46 0.92 7.74 4.47 Therefore their position could be one of a strategy of labour
36 Furniture, manufacturing nec 6.35 3.13 2.55 3.02 1.36 0.72 control. On the other hand, labour in organised manufacturing,
All manufacturing 6.54 6.72 6.58 3.68 3.69 3.73
especially in the bigger establishments, are unionised and see
The declining share of wages as well as a slow growth in real this as an ideological threat to their very existence, let alone
wages of workers would suggest a declining power of workers functioning within a framework of collective bargaining in which
and their organisations. The support for economic liberalisation trade union participation is a legitimate activity. In the Indian
and globalisation from employers and higher paid supervisory context, this takes political overtones since trade unions are
and managerial staff and the opposition to it from the workers affiliated to political parties. Such an ideological contestation
and their organisations seem to be grounded in the distribution cannot be resolved through empirical verification of employment
of benefits to these groups. The workers as a class lost in terms of and output growth performance of organised industries. We
both additional employment as well as real wages. therefore move to two other plausible explanations.

Understanding Jobless Growth: Plausible Hypotheses Has Capital Become Cheaper?


This section suggests some hypotheses for the phenomenon of The second set of explanation for the jobless growth in organised
jobless growth. manufacturing relates to the wide range of measures that helped
reduce the cost of capital such that the employers found it more
The Argument about Labour Market Rigidity attractive to continuously increase capital intensity of production
In the beginning of this paper we dealt with the argument about for maximising output growth. In a recent paper Chandrasekhar
labour market rigidity as the prime cause for the absence any (2008) calculated the cost of capital and compared it with the cost of
perceptible increase in employment elasticity in the organised labour3 and concluded that there is a “negative shift in the price
manufacturing sector. The opinion, as we saw earlier, is divided of capital relative to labour” which “points to a major bias in prices
along those who continue to advance labour market rigidity as that favours capital intensity”. He also points out that there are
the prime factor and those who contest it. The analysis here additional incentives encouraging capital intensity offered by
Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10 89
speciAl article

central and state governments in the form of cash subsidy based on “job-displacing” groups of industries. Since early 1990s the process
level of investment, interest subsidies and a range of other incentives of capital intensification has accelerated as compared to the 1980s.
such as exemption from payment of electricity in several cases.
For an earlier period of analysis, Ghosh (1994) had also attributed Demand Side Explanation: Changing Nature of Demand
the increase in real cost of labour as a reason for capital deepening We now move to another set of explanations that may be clubbed
in the organised manufacturing sector. As mentioned earlier, such a as demand-side explanations. It would appear that there is a strong
view was then contested by both Papola (1994) and Nagaraj (1994). case to move away from cost of production and problems in labour
Given the fact that we Table 13: Cost of Capital and Cost of Labour hiring explanations to those which are related to the changing
have covered almost a Per Unit of Value Added and Their Ratios nature and composition of demand for manufactured products
Year Interest/GVA (%) Wage/GVA (%) Ratio of (2)/(1)
quarter of a century and both in the domestic and foreign markets. Chandrasekhar (2008)
1981-82 12.2 41.9 3.4
have shown the differ- 1982-83 12.1 41.8 3.4 has dealt with this demand side effects as an added reason for the
ential performance of the 1983-84 13.0 41.5 3.2 jobless growth in organised manufacturing. We feel that this is
organised manufacturing 1984-85 14.3 42.3 3.0 perhaps the dominant factor that has pushed India’s organised
sector in terms of indus- 1985-86 15.7 40.4 2.6 manufacturing to a situation of jobless growth arising out of
tries that are “job creat- 1986-87 17.1 41.0 2.4 economic reform policies.
1987-88 14.9 39.8 2.7
ing growth” and “job We have already seen how the distribution of the value added
1988-89 13.5 34.5 2.6
displacing growth”, we in organised manufacturing has shifted in favour of capital and
1989-90 13.2 33.7 2.6
think it is important to 1990-91 13.0 32.0 2.5 to the managerial class of employees. Given the same logic, similar
further examine the the- 1991-92 15.9 32.4 2.0 shifts might also have occurred in the organised segment of the
sis of re­lative cheapness 1992-93 15.2 32.2 2.1 service sector. In fact this has been the experience in most coun-
of capital vis-à-vis labour. 1993-94 16.8 28.7 1.7 tries that have embarked on the path of economic liberalisation
While the WPI for ma- 1994-95 16.6 27.1 1.6 and globalisation. In the Indian case, the shift in demand takes
1995-96 13.7 27.1 2.0
chinery and index of place in favour of those goods demanded by the newly rich
1996-97 12.6 24.3 1.9
money wages could rep- classes, which has been made easy by a rather aggressive pursuit
1997-98 17.9 27.9 1.6
resent the cost of capital 1998-99 18.0 25.7 1.4 by banks expanding personal finance loans. This satisfied the
and labour, respectively, 1999-2000 18.6 25.3 1.4 demand for products that are similar to “foreign goods” that were
we would argue that we 2000-01 22.3 28.5 1.3 not earlier satisfied. Since the enterprises also have to compete in
need to find out the cost 2001-02 24.3 28.0 1.2 an open economy context, they have to produce goods, which
of capital and labour in- 2002-03 19.7 25.9 1.3 would be similar to those that could now be imported. If they are
2003-04 17.1 23.7 1.4
curred by the firms. This export-oriented, then they have to produce goods that are de-
2004-05 12.4 20.9 1.7
ex-post data would then manded in the world market, produced with modern technology,
show the relative cost of capital vis-à-vis labour as experienced packaging, branding and so on. As Chandrasekhar points out,
by the firms. For this we have taken the share of interest paid in opening the domestic market for transnational enterprises also
gross value added to represent cost of capital and share of wages results in high import intensity of domestic manufacturing that
in gross value added to represent cost of labour. These are shown will in turn reduce the employment elasticity of growth in manu-
in Table 13 and Figure 5. factures. In a nutshell, what we are witnessing is a drastic change
Figure 5: Relative Cost of Capital and Labour (in %) in the quality of products characterised by high capital intensity,
50
50 branding, import intensity and so on that results in slowing down
both the absorption of direct labour as well as backward and for-
40
40
Wage/GVA ward linkages within the domestic economy.
Trade policies especially import duties and special incentives
30
30
for export, credit policies that push up the personal finance for
Interest/GVA middle- and high-income segments, technology acquisition poli-
20
20
cies that are capital-intensive modern technologies, and fiscal
10
10 policies that favour a reduced rate of taxation and special incen-
Wage share/Interest share
tives for capital-intensive projects in fact work in favour of such a
00 qualitative shift in the composition and structure of demand.
1981-82
1981-82 1984-85
1984-85 1987-88
1987-88 1990-91
1990-91 1993-94
1993-94 1996-97
1996-97 1999-2000
1999-00 2002-03 2004-05
2002-03
This has manifested in several countries in terms of jobless
Clearly the cost of capital here has been showing an increasing growth in organised manufacturing. This leaves the vast informal
trend except for the latest year (2004-05) when it came down to sector in manufacturing in India where around 71% of the total
the level of the initial year (1981-82). However, the share of wages workforce in manufacturing are engaged, to cater to the demand
in value added shows a more or less secular decline to such an ex- for goods that are low value (arising out of the low-income of the
tent that it is exactly half that of the initial years. The ratio of these households), low productivity and low quality. Employment in
two shows that it is the cost of labour that has cheapened over time this sector is mostly by default in the form of self-employment
vis-à-vis cost of capital. The puzzle here then is to explain the con- since many workers have no opportunities for wage employment,
tinuous increase in capital intensity for both “job-creating” and let alone regular wage employment.
90 march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10   EPW   Economic & Political Weekly
special article

As we have noted earlier, jobless growth is not all pervasive However, employment elasticity has remained within a narrow
across all industries. Our analysis shows that a set of industries has range of 0.26 to 0.28 between the two periods analysed here.
been able to grow with some net job creation. However, there is While there has been reference to a “hollowing” of the small-
another set of industries that grew largely by shedding employ- scale sector of Indian industry, what we have found is an increasing
ment perhaps to stay on course with the changing nature of the divide between the formal and informal segments of Indian manu-
product market and domestic competition. The interaction of these facturing. In another study (NCEUS 2008), we have reported that the
two trends resulted in jobless growth over nearly a quarter of a informal segment of manufacturing registered an annual growth
century. While growth has been high, it has not been high enough rate of 4.9% between 1999-2000 and 2004-05, the formal segment
to generate additional employment to come out of the syndrome has grown by 7%. What this points to is the relative decline of the
of “jobless growth”. Examining Table 6, one might be tempted to share of informal segment since the growth rate differential is so
say that there is some streak of hope in favour of employment since huge. If this persists, there is sufficient reason to worry about
industries that are “job creating growth” sectors have increased increasing inequality and its attendant economic and social reper-
their share of employment from 54% in 1981-82 to 64% in 2004-05 cussions. The jobless growth performance of India’s organised manu-
with a corresponding increase in share of output from 62% to 77%. facturing sector is indeed a matter of serious concern.

Notes – (2004): “Indian Manufacturing: Productivity Trends of 1978-79 and 1973-74 was notionally estimated
in Pre- and Post-Reform Periods”, Economic & to be the net capital formation after depreciation
1 The sectoral wholesale price indices used for dif-
Political Weekly, 20 November, pp 5033-43.
ferent industry groups are given in the Appendix. during each of the above years. The net fixed
Kannan, K P (1994): “Levelling Up or Levelling Down?
2 These are: Goa, Himachal Pradesh, Jammu and capital at the end of 1973-74 and net depreciation
Labour Institutions and Economic Development
Kashmir, Manipur, Meghalaya, Nagaland, Tripura,
Andaman and Nicobar Islands, Chandigarh,
in India”, Economic & Political Weekly, 23 July, during each of the years up to 2004-05 were then
pp 1938-45. converted into 1993-94 prices by using wholesale
Dadra and Nagar haveli, Daman and Diu and
Pondicherry. Nagaraj, R (1994): “Wages and Employment in Manu-
facturing Industries: Trends, Hypothesis and Evi-
prices indices for machinery and equipments.
3 “The ‘cost of investment’ is captured not just by Thus NCF*74-75 = (NFC78-79 – NFC73-74)/5
dence”, Economic & Political Weekly, Vol 29, No 4,
trends in the prices of capital goods, but also by the
22 January. where NCF* is Net Capital Formation after
opportunity cost of capital as captured by the pre-
vailing rate of interest. One way to represent the – (2000): “Organised Manufacturing Employment”,
Economic & Political Weekly, 16 September, depreciation
combined effect of these two elements is to apply
the rate of interest on an index of the price of capital pp 3445-48. NFCR73-74 = NFC73-74 × (WPI93-94 /WPI73-74)
goods, say the wholesale price index of machinery, – (2004): “Fall in Organised Manufacturing Em- NCFRt = NCFt × (WPI93-94 / WPIt)
and build an index of the resulting values. This is ployment: A Brief Note”, Economic & Political
Weekly, 24 July, pp 3387-90. where NFCR is net fixed capital at constant
what has been done to construct the index of cost of
capital, also presented in Chart 6. What is interest- NCEUS (2008): “Contribution of the Unorganised prices
ing is that when we consider this composite index, Sector to GDP Report of the Sub Committtee of a WPI is wholesale price index for ma-
the trend has been more complex than revealed NCEUS Task Force”, Working Paper 2, New Delhi. chinery and equipments and
merely by the relative movements of the prices of Papola, T S (1994): “Structural Adjustment, Labour
capital goods and money wages. The high interest Market Flexibility and Employment”, Indian
NCFRt is net capital formation at con-
rate regime that kicked in after the crisis of 1991-92, Journal of Labour Economics, Vol 37, No 1. stant prices.
and remained in place till the second half of the World Bank (1989): “India: Poverty, Employment and In the next step the rate of depreciation for each
1990s meant that the ‘cost of capital’ rose sharply Social Services: A World Bank Country Study” year from 1979-80 was estimated by dividing
during the first half of the 1990s, often at a rate (Washington DC: World Bank).
much faster than the rate of rise in money wages. the depreciation at current prices with the sum
However, after the government managed to engi- of the Net Fixed Capital of the previous and net
neer a low interest rate regime starting from the Appendix: Methodology to Calculate capital formation of the current year
late 1990s, movements in money wages and the
cost of capital diverged with the former rising at
Total Capital Stock RDt = Dt /(NFCt-1 + NCFt)
fast rate while the latter stagnated or declined” The estimation of capital stock employed in the where RDt is the rate of depreciation in the
(Chandrasekhar 2008: 10). production process in any year is generally year t and
based on a number of reasonable assumptions. Dt is the amount of depreciation in the
Given the data sets available from different year t.
References sources, there exists no ideal method. Neverthe- The capital stock for each of the years from
Bhalotra, S R (1998): “The Puzzle of Jobless Growth in less, the perpetual inventory method is considered 1973-74 to 1978-79 is then estimated by using
Indian Manufacturing”, Oxford Bulletin of Eco- to be useful and realistic in the estimation of the formula
nomics and Statistics, 60, 1.
capital stock. The method has been used in this NCS*t+1 = NFC*t + NCF*t+1
Chandrasekhar, C P (2008): “Revisiting the Policy En-
vironment for Engendering Employment Inten- study for the estimation of 2-digit level industry- where NCS*t+1 is the net capital stock at the end
sive Growth”, Background Paper prepared for the wise capital stock in the manufacturing sector of year t+1, at constant prices
International Labour Office, New Delhi. at 1993-94 prices. The time series data released NFC*t is the net fixed capital at the end
Dutta Roy, S (1998): “Lags in Employment Adjustment of year t and
by the Central Statistical Organisation contain
and Inter-industry Differentials: An Analysis Us-
ing Dynamic Inter-Related Factor Demand Func- information on Net Fixed Capital at the end of each NCF*t+1 is net capital formation during
tion”, Discussion Paper No 149 (Mumbai: Indira accounting year and net fixed capital formation the year t+1, both at constant prices.
Gandhi Institute of Development Research). and depreciation since 1979-80. During the The capital stock for each of the years from
Fallon, P R and R E B Lucas (1993): “Job Security Reg- period from 1973-74 to 1978-79, data on year- 1979-80 was estimated by using the formula
ulations and the Dynamic Demand for Industrial
Labour in India and Zimbabwe”, Journal of Devel- wise depreciation and net capital formation are NCS*t+1 = (NCS*t + NCF*t+1)×RDt
opment Economics, Vol 40, pp 241-75. not available though net fixed capital data are Since these capital stock estimates relate to the
Ghose, A K (1994): “Employment in Organised Manu- available. The net fixed capital estimates are end of the production year, the average of the
facturing in India”, Indian Journal of Labour Eco- book values after depreciation and net capital previous year and the current year was taken to
nomics, Vol 37, No 2.
formation estimates are at current prices. reflect the mean capital stock during the year.
Goldar, B (2000): “Employment Growth in Organised
Manufacturing in India”, Economic & Political In this exercise, one-fifth of the difference Thus
Weekly, 1 April, pp 1191-95. between the net fixed capital estimates at the end NCS*t(mean) = (NCS*t-1 + NCS*t)/2

Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   march 7, 2009  vol xliv no 10 91

You might also like