You are on page 1of 29

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews


journal homepage: http://www.elsevier.com/locate/rser

Review of Cooperative Game Theory applications in power system


expansion planning
Andrey Churkin a, *, Janusz Bialek a, b, David Pozo a, Enzo Sauma c, Nikolay Korgin d
a
Center for Energy Science and Technology, Skolkovo Institute of Science and Technology (Skoltech), Bolshoy Boulevard 30, bld. 1, Moscow, 121205, Russia
b
School of Engineering, Newcastle University, United Kingdom
c
Industrial and Systems Engineering Department and UC Energy Research Center, Pontificia Universidad Catolica de Chile, Santiago, Chile
d
V.A. Trapeznikov Institute of Control Sciences, Russian Academy of Sciences, Moscow, Russia

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: In recent years, mechanisms of cooperation in power systems have attracted increasing attention from academia
Cooperative Game Theory and industry. Such mechanisms require sharing the benefits of cooperation among participants based on some
Power systems rational and obvious principles. In this regard, Cooperative Game Theory (CGT) provides a rich theoretical
Multi-agent systems
background for the analysis of projects where participants (called players) can make collective actions to obtain
Transmission expansion planning
Electricity markets
mutual benefits. CGT concepts not only solve the subsequent allocation problems but also reveal the bargaining
Cost allocation power of players and estimate the stability of cooperation over a project. In this paper, we aim to classify and
Citation network analysis promote CGT applications in power systems. While covering a broad range of applications (such as cost and
benefit allocation, transmission pricing, projects ranking, allocation of power losses), we pay particular attention
to power system expansion planning. We first introduce an illustrative example of cooperation in transmission
expansion planning and discuss the applicability of CGT solution concepts. To give a complete picture of the state
of the art, we perform a citation network analysis of more than 3000 related studies from 1996 to 2020.
Exploiting the graph layout and modularity algorithms, we identify the main research communities and highlight
their contributions. We found that significant progress has been achieved in developing mechanisms of coop­
eration in power systems based on CGT solution concepts. However, several challenges and limitations of these
concepts still have to be overcome, such as scalability, nonconvexity of cooperative games, coalitions formation
assumption, ex-post game-theoretic analysis, incompleteness and manipulability of information. The overview
presented in this paper and the citation network analysis performed can help scientists and engineers in com­
prehending the CGT solution concepts, discovering novel applications for power systems, and contributing to this
promising multidisciplinary research direction.

1. Introduction game formulations. The main assumption in the noncooperative games


is that players act independently. That is, every player optimizes its own
Modern complex multi-agent power systems pose challenges that can objective function without seeking to increase other players’ benefits.
no longer be addressed by classical methods of centralized planning, Mutual agreements or recommendations are not binding for players. The
operation and control. The need for simulation of interactions among noncooperative formulation represents a competition among players,
power system operators (SO), generation and distribution companies, and it is usually analyzed using equilibrium-based solution concepts. In
independent investors, consumers, prosumers, and microgrids operators power systems research, noncooperative games are widely used for the
forced the power systems research community to develop models under estimation of possible electricity market equilibria [1–4] and modeling
the umbrella of Game Theory. Depending on the interaction assump­ outcomes of competitive investment decisions [5–10].1 The opposite
tions, the models can be classified into noncooperative and cooperative approach considers situations where players conclude binding

* Corresponding author.
E-mail address: andrey.churkin@skolkovotech.ru (A. Churkin).
1
In fact, noncooperative game formulations are much more common in power systems research than cooperative approaches. This is mainly justified by the need
to simulate competitive environments. However, in this paper, we pay less attention to noncooperative formulations and equilibrium-based models. Instead, we focus
on cooperative formulations and present a systematic review of CGT applications in power systems.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2021.111056
Received 22 September 2020; Received in revised form 15 March 2021; Accepted 29 March 2021
Available online 29 April 2021
1364-0321/© 2021 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

agreements to reach mutual benefits. In cooperative games (also called In Section 2, we discuss in detail the role of the cooperative approach
coalitional games), the key questions to address are: what coalitions will in power systems. The subsequent allocation problems are highlighted,
form, and what should be the payoffs to the participants? An important and the applicability of CGT is discussed. In Section 3, we introduce a
assumption is usually made that benefits generated by cooperation may case study of cooperation in cross-border transmission expansion plan­
be easily distributed and shared among the players, for example, in ning. The applicability and advantages of the CGT solution concepts are
monetary terms. This assumption allows formulating cooperation as a illustrated. Section 4 provides a systematic review of existing research
transferable utility game [11] and implementing well-established solu­ based on the citation network analysis. The three major research di­
tion concepts from CGT. rections are identified: multi-agent systems, expansion planning, CGT
Even though power systems have been liberalized and competitive applications in power systems. Within each of the directions, we identify
electricity markets created, there still exist multiple challenges that can research communities and highlight their contributions. We also analyze
be addressed only by means of cooperation. Therefore, in recent years, the bibliometrics of the related studies and identify the most cited au­
mechanisms of cooperation in power systems have attracted increasing thors, top journals in the field, and most popular keywords. Section 5
attention from academia and industry. On the one side, at the macro- provides a discussion of the main challenges and limitations of CGT in
level, there exist opportunities for creating cross-border power in­ power systems applications. Future research directions are indicated.
terconnections for electricity trading and reserves sharing. Multiple Section 6 concludes the paper. Finally, for the sake of completeness, we
studies demonstrated that such cooperation could lead to significant cost introduce the mathematical background of CGT and the main solution
savings, CO2 emissions reduction, decrease in capacity investments, and concepts in the Appendix.
improvement of power systems flexibility and stability [12–17]. There
exist even more ambitious projects of power interconnections that 2. The role of the cooperative approach: allocation problems in
involve entire continents. The European Union launched the e-High­ power systems
way2050 project that aims to develop an optimal European transmission
expansion plan from 2020 to 2050 [18]. The International Council on The main purpose of CGT lies in solving allocation problems where
Large Electric Systems (CIGRE) recently published a report on global cooperating players have to share the cost of a coalition (cost games) or
electricity network feasibility study that shows how the whole world split the benefits of cooperation (value/profit games). Being complex
may cooperate to increase the share renewable energy and reduce CO2 multi-agent systems with capital intensive equipment, power systems
emissions [19]. The similar values are promoted by the Global Energy involve multiple allocation problems. The common tasks include
Interconnection Development and Cooperation Organization (GEIDCO) transmission access pricing, investment cost allocation, reserve sharing,
[20]. The importance of international cooperation in energy is included coordination of microgrids and prosumers. Most of the allocation issues
in the United Nations sustainable development goals [21]. On the other are related to the planning stage, where investment decisions are taken.
side, at the micro-level, microgrids, prosumers, and electricity market There is a need for estimating the consequences of the decisions, sug­
participants may cooperate in local energy exchange, demand response gesting shares of investment, agreeing on payments compensations. We
programs, and peer-to-peer electricity markets to get mutual benefits start with the essential decision-making process in power systems -
[22–28]. Such cooperation is acknowledged as one of the key factors for transmission expansion planning (TEP) [33]. Expanding a network by
reaching large-scale renewable energy integration. building new power lines influences multiple electricity market partic­
Initially, the cooperative game formulations for power systems ipants. Moreover, the physical nature of power flows, counterflows, and
concerned only cost allocation issues, for example in Refs. [29–32], and loop flows makes it hard to suggest a unified approach to transmission
did not attract much attention from the research community. However, cost allocation.2 Over the last decades, numerous studies put effort into
in the last decade, an increasing number of studies have used coopera­ developing transmission cost allocation mechanisms.
tive games to complement the existing planning and operation models. Gil et al. [34] elaborated on the problem of transmission cost allo­
The purpose of this paper is to classify and promote the applications of cation in large networks with interconnected regions or countries. A
CGT in power systems. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first common approach requires an international operator to gather data
paper to provide a systematic review of the existing concepts and the about all the transmission elements as well as generators cost functions
evolution of the research. Specifically, the main original contributions of and demand forecasts. However, such level of data sharing may be
our work are: impractical for many regions. Therefore, a multiarea decoupled trans­
mission allocation scheme was suggested where each region performs its
• We highlight the need for developing new cooperation mechanisms internal cost allocation while an international operator carries out
and allocation rules (as a consequence of the opportunities for region-wise allocations. The equivalent bilateral exchange principle was
cooperation in power systems and the subsequent allocation used as a proxy for cost allocation. A thorough review of other network
problems). cost allocation methods is presented in Ref. [35].
• We introduce the main CGT solution concepts and use a simple case Similar problems arise in setting transmission tariffs and inter-SO
study to illustrate their advantages and applicability in solving cost compensations. Uneven utilization of existing and new transmission
allocation problems. facilities by market participants, existence of transit flows and loop
• To give a complete picture of the state of the art, we identify the main flows requires the development of reasonable mechanisms for
publications in the field and perform the citation network analysis.
The main research communities are classified, and their contribu­
tions highlighted.
2
• To illustrate the citation network analysis, we use graph layout and The transit flows, loop flows, and counterflows are the well-known phe­
modularity algorithms that allow spatial mapping of references. To nomena in transmission systems. The point is that the power purchased does
our knowledge, this is the first attempt to use spatial mapping of not flow according to a contract. Instead, it follows the laws of physics and
citations and research communities in power systems research. flows through available parallel paths, leading to unintended outcomes. Transit
flow is the share of power that is transmitted through a third party’s network.
• We present the bibliometric analysis illustrating time-evolving in­
Such flows cause an additional load of equipment and power losses. In some
terests in particular areas, the most published authors, top journals in
cases, a share of export power can flow back to the exporting power system.
the field, and most popular keywords. This effect is called a loop flow. An increase in generators’ output power at the
• We discuss the main challenges in application of CGT and suggest importing system creates a counterflow that can decrease the amount of inflow
directions for further research. power purchased. We refer to works. [36,37] for the detailed discussion of
unintended flows in transmission systems.

2
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

international transmission tariffs and inter-SO compensations [36]. Southern Electricity Region of India as a cooperative game with trans­
Common compensation approaches include the Marginal Participation ferable utility. Each power system was modeled as an independent
and the Average Participation methods, and the With and Without player who might accept the terms of cooperation or refuse the con­
Transits method [37]. An additional question is the allocation of trans­ struction of interconnections. Gately analyzed possible scenarios of
mission capacity between energy trade and reserve services. Proper cooperation and implemented several CGT solution concepts such as the
capacity allocation and SO coordination in reserves sharing could lead to Shapley value, the Core, and the Kernel. He also introduced an addi­
significant savings for interconnected power systems [38,39]. Yang et al. tional concept of propensity to disrupt to identify allocation solution areas
[40] suggested transmission capacity usage identification. The cost with mutually acceptable shares of gains.
allocation methods were designed taking into account the conditions The new wave of research on CGT applications in TEP began in the
under which the capacity should be used (capacity used in normal nineteen-nineties and the two-thousands. Tsukamoto and Iyoda [30]
conditions, reserves for contingencies, reserves for future use, and suggested a CGT based methodology for allocating transmission fixed
invalid capacity). costs. The MW-mile method was complemented with the Nucleolus so­
Building cross-border power lines requires coordination of regulators lution concept to avoid conflicting outcomes. Contreras dedicated his
and mechanisms for cost-benefit allocation. Gerbaulet and Weber [41] thesis and the subsequent papers to the coalition formation analysis in
illustrated how a lack of coordination might lead to non-fair allocations. TEP [31,44]. A decentralized coalition formation scheme based on
In such cases, a profit-maximizing merchant investor may make sub­ power systems transmission expansion scenarios was considered. The
optimal investment decisions and take the major part of the welfare resulting cost allocation was performed using the backward induction
gain. Konstantelos et al. [15] reported that conventional benefit alloca­ and the bilateral Shapley value approach. In the following work, Con­
tion methods are less suitable for international grids creation. Based on treras and Wu [45] developed a TEP algorithm using the Kernel solution
the North Sea grid example, it was shown that a highly asymmetric concept. The decentralized, negotiation-oriented coalition formation
distribution of costs and benefits could lead to potential issues in algorithm allowed identifying the Kernel-stable cost allocation solu­
achieving political consensus between participating countries. tions. Two years later, several studies on TEP algorithms applied CGT
Several studies exploited complementarity modeling [1] in order to solution concepts. Tan and Lie [46] considered transmission cost allo­
formulate interactions between market participants and different cation among power consumers. The Shapley value was utilized as the
transmission planners. For the Iberian electricity market, Loureiro et al. allocation rule in a centralized manner. Zolezzi and Rudnick [32]
[14] presented investments in cross-border power interconnections as a formulated decisions on building each line in TEP as separate coopera­
Nash bargaining between the regions. The resulting bi-level model with tive games. The Shapley value, the Nucleolus, the marginal participation
embedded investment cost allocation was formulated as a Mathematical method, and the generalized load-distribution factors method were
Program with Equilibrium Constraints (MPEC). Tohidi and Hesamzadeh compared for transmission cost allocation among power consumers. The
[42] also examined multi-regional transmission planning from the idea of transmission expansion plan segmentation was further devel­
non-cooperative decision-making point of view. The multiple-leaders oped in Ref. [47]. Independent cooperative games for each of the
single-follower game was formulated as a bi-level model where each expansion segments were solved through the Kernel concept. Stamtsis
independent transmission planner minimizes its own cost. The results and Erlich [48] formulated a cooperative game in pool markets where
showed that without proper compensation mechanisms, the noncoop­ counterflows may cause transmission capacity savings. The authors
erative transmission planning leads to inefficient results compared to the argued that the Shapley value is a more preferable solution than the
cooperative solution. Conflicting outcomes in multilateral transmission Nucleolus for transmission fixed-cost allocation. In Ref. [49], Ruiz and
planning were observed by Buijs and Belmans [43]. The interactions Contreras incorporated market participants’ influence on TEP decisions
between zonal and supranational planners were formulated as a into the expansion and cost allocation algorithm. Each consumer and
generalized Nash equilibrium in the form of Equilibrium Problem with each producer were allocated weights that measure the influence of each
Equilibrium Constraints (EPEC). As a possible solution, a Pareto-planner firm on the expansion decision. In order to realize a transmission
was proposed. Such a planner maximizes overall welfare while ac­ expansion, all the parties have to be satisfied enough with the allocation.
knowledges that a solution should be acceptable for each zone. Kasina Mathematically, the total weight of the firms that favor the expansion
and Hobbs [10] also highlighted the value of transmission planners must be larger than a known positive parameter. The issues of trans­
cooperation. A bi-level EPEC model was composed to represent a game mission lines investors incentivization were further discussed in
among multiple transmission planners, generators, and consumers. The Ref. [50].
hierarchical model represented the optimization of planning decisions Admitting the probabilistic nature of power systems and players’
by independent regional planners (the upper level) subject to generator behavior, Bhakar [51] suggested extending game approaches for
investments and energy market equilibrium (the lower revel). This network cost allocation. The probability of existence of players, the
noncooperative solution was compared to cooperative centralized probability of coalitions existence, and the probability of players joining
optimization. It was shown that equilibrium transmission plans may a coalition in a particular sequence were introduced into the model. This
differ significantly from the optimal ones. A significant value of coop­ approach may be useful for cooperation stability analysis. However, it
eration was reported, which results from investment in interregional requires reasonable assumptions on the probabilistic characteristic
lines. Moreover, it was found that cooperation among transmission functions.
planners leads to increased competition among generators from As indicated by many studies, the application of the Shapley value
adjoining regions, which in turn leads to more efficient generation in­ becomes computationally prohibitive for realistic systems with multiple
vestments. Huppmann and Egerer [8] composed a three-stage equilibrium players. Therefore, some authors suggested using the Aumann–Shapley
model to represent interactions between a spot market, zonal and su­ extension that allows finding an allocation solution through a set of
pranational planners. It was concluded that zonal planners may have linear optimization programs and reduces the computation effort [52,
incentives to over-invest or intentionally withhold power line upgrades 53].
in their jurisdiction to induce a shift of rents towards them. Nowadays, CGT becomes a prominent tool for addressing issues of
The above-mentioned works emphasize the need for efficient allo­ cooperation and allocation in power systems. Kristiansen et al. [54]
cation and compensation mechanisms in power systems planning. proposed an international transmission mechanism based on a planning
Searching for justified solutions, a number of researchers turned their model that considers generation investments as a response to trans­
attention to CGT. One of the very first studies on cost-benefit allocation mission developments and the Shapley value. The results for the North
in transmission expansion projects was done back in 1974 by Gately Sea Offshore Grid case study showed the benefits allocation among the
[29], who formulated the energy cooperation among states in the countries and possible ways of arranging the side payments (for

3
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Table 1
The three-system case study data.
Parameter System A System B System C

Quadratic cost function ($/h) 1 1 1


10pA + 0.01pA 2 13pB + 0.03p2B 12pC + 0.025p2C
2 2 2
Power demand (MW) 500 1500 1000

the total amount of losses”. Junqueira et al. [52] developed an open


access transmission tariff scheme based on the Aumann-Shapley value. It
was demonstrated that the proposed approach “presents desirable
characteristics in terms of economic coherence and isonomy”. It was also
found that the Aumann-Shapley approach captures the physics of power
systems (the fact that power demands are mainly supplied by local
generators, if any), while other methods require setting the economic
slack bus and may provide unreasonable results.
The discussed studies show that CGT can be applied to power sys­
tems’ allocation problems. The solution concepts could be valuable in
analyzing projects with multiple participants or used as the basis for
mechanisms of cooperation. For instance, in Ref. [22], Saad et al.
reviewed game-theoretic methods for smart grids and concluded,
“Clearly, cooperative games could become a foundation for introducing
Fig. 1. Model of the three-system case power interconnections. local energy exchange between microgrids in future smart grid systems.
This local energy exchange could constitute one of the main steps to­
wards the vision of an autonomous microgrid network.” We, therefore,
example, through power purchase agreements). De Moura et al. [55]
expect more studies and applications of CGT to appear in the near future.
analyzed the perspectives of power systems integration processes be­
In the next sections, we further investigate the state of the art of CGT
tween Brazil and its South American neighboring countries. The Shapley
applications in power systems. We reveal a broad range of challenges
value was used for players’ bargaining power estimation and cost allo­
that CGT is being applied to. We then identify the main research com­
cation. The stability of cooperation over cross-border power in­
munities and highlight their contributions.
terconnections in Northeast Asia was analyzed in Ref. [56] using CGT
solution concepts such as the Shapley value, the Nucleolus, and the Core.
3. An illustrative case study of cooperation in transmission
Du et al. [57] proposed a cooperative game approach for coordinating
expansion planning
the operation of multiple microgrids. The Nucleolus was used as a
feasible cost allocation solution.
In power systems, the CGT solution concepts are commonly used for
One of the main merits of CGT is the applicability of the solution
solving cost allocation problems. One of the main applications was
concepts in power systems. Existing concepts enable to identify
found in transmission expansion planning since the initial study by
reasonable allocation solutions while satisfying some desired properties
Gately [29]. In this section, we illustrate the advantages and applica­
of cooperation. Many authors reported on the successful implementation
bility of the concepts in analyzing expansion planning projects. We
of the solution concepts and suggested using them as the basis for
introduce the case study where three independent power systems
cooperation mechanisms in power systems. In most of the covered ap­
(players) negotiate on building cross-border power lines. The data on
plications, CGT provides intuitive results with explicit incentives for
power systems’ cost functions and demands is given in Table 1. The
participants of cooperation and regulatory or coordinating entities. In
scheme of power interconnections is depicted in Fig. 1. The three
Ref. [49], Ruiz and Contreras suggested using CGT in transmission assets
possible power lines with the maximum capacity of 100 MW each and
investment schemes and argued that such schemes would give market
investment cost 10 $/MWh are a subject of the transmission expansion
participants incentives to support an expansion plan. Faria et al. [58]
discussion. For simplicity reasons, we consider the interconnection of
examined the allocation of firm-energy rights among hydro plants in
electricity markets with perfect competition [61] and inelastic demand.
Brazil. The authors considered several allocation methods and recom­
We also neglect the transmission losses.
mended using the Aumann–Shapley since “it is robust in relation to
The related transmission expansion problem can be formulated using
small variations of a plant’s size and computationally efficient, besides
mathematical programming. We aim to minimize the total generation
originates from an intuitive methodology (Shapley value)”. Bane­
and investment costs while satisfying the linear constraints of power
z-Chicharro et al. [59] used the Aumann-Shapley value for estimating the
balance, generators outputs, and power flows. Thus, our model presents
benefits of transmission expansion projects. Having compared several
the following linearly constrained quadratic optimization problem.
methods, the authors concluded that “the proposed methodology pro­
∑ ( ) ∑
vides regulatory authorities with the most relevant information for the min CGn pn,S + Fl,S ⋅CIl
identification of high-priority expansion projects”.
pn,S ,fl,S ,Fl,S n∈N l∈L (1)
s.t. :
Many authors mentioned that the identification of agents (players)
and formulation of cooperative games is straightforward and clear. ∑
Moreover, the solution concepts adequately consider the key parameters pn,S + Bn,l ⋅fl,S = Dn,S ∀ n, S (2)
l∈L
of cooperation in power systems such as topology, electrical distance,
usage of the network, etc. In Ref. [60], Sharma and Abhyankar used the 0 ≤ pn,S ≤ Pmax ∀ n, S (3)
n
Shapley value for power loss allocation in radial distribution systems.
The authors mentioned that the proposed game-theoretic approach − Fl,S ≤ fl,S ≤ Fl,S ∀ l, S (4)
could be superior to existing methods since “it is easy to understand and
implement”, “it considers the size and location of loads and distributed Fl,S ≤ Flmax ∀ l, S (5)
generations”, “it is based on individual network usages”, and “it recovers
The total generation and investment costs are minimized in the

4
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Table 2 concepts can be applied to models of any degree of complexity.


Scenarios of cooperation for the three-system case. The expansion planning model (1)–(5) was solved several times for
Parameter Scenarios/coalitions of players all possible scenarios of cooperation (coalitions of players). Parameters
of the optimal solutions are listed in Table 2. The nodal prices, λA , λB ,
{A},{B}, or {C} {A,B} {A,B,C} {A,C} {B,C}
and λC , are equivalent to the dual variables for the corresponding bal­
pA (MW) 500 600 700 600 500 ance constraints (2). The cost of the separate operation for Systems A, B,
pB (MW) 1500 1400 1300 1500 1400 and C is 6 250, 53 250, and 24 500 $/h, respectively. It is seen that the
pC (MW) 1000 1000 1000 900 1100 grand coalition, {A,B,C}, leads to the highest cost savings of 4800 $/h.
FAB (MW) – 100 100 – – Systems A and B act as power exporter and importer, while C turns out to
FAC (MW) – – 100 100 – be a transfer system.
FCB (MW) – – 100 – 100 But how stable is this cooperation? And how should the systems
λA ($/MWh) 15 16 17 16 15 allocate the cost savings and share the investment in the cross-border
λB ($/MWh) 58 55 52 58 55 power lines? To address these questions, we formulated the coopera­
λC ($/MWh) 37 37 37 34.5 39.5 tive game with the cost-based characteristic function of coalitions and
Generation cost ($/h) 84 000 79 900 76 200 81 975 82 175 implemented the CGT solution concepts.3 Table 3 shows the obtained
Investment cost ($/h) 1000 3000 1000 1000
solutions indicating the allocation of both costs and savings among the

Total cost ($/h) 84 000 80 900 79 200 82 975 83 175
systems. We also computed the equal sharing solution, which is a
straightforward approach of splitting the savings equally among the
Table 3 participants.
Allocation solutions for the three-system case. The obtained allocations reveal the usefulness and the bargaining
power of the players. For example, both the Nucleolus and the Shapley
Solution concept Allocation of costs (savings) ($/h)
value agree that System C is the less important player. It is therefore
System A System B System C allocated fewer savings than Systems A and B. Indeed, System C has a
The Shapley value 4237.5 (2012.5) 51 337.5 (1912.5) 23 625 (875) medium market price and is neither a power exporter nor importer.
The Nucleolus 4187.5 (2062.5) 51 362.5 (1887.5) 23 650 (850) Thus, without System C, other players are still able to yield significant
Equal sharing 4650 (1600) 51 650 (1600) 22 900 (1600)
cost savings.
To analyze the stability of cooperation, we impose the coalitional
rationality conditions (11) and examine the Core of the game. We
visualize the set of imputations, the Core, and the obtained allocation
solutions using the barycentric coordinate system, as shown in Fig. 2.
The vertices A, B, and C represent the solution points where the corre­
sponding systems get the maximum cost savings, i.e., the minimum
possible cost. For example, System A is allocated 100% of the total
savings at point A. Its cost decreases from 6250 to 1450 $/h. The farther
solution moves from the A point, the fewer savings are allocated to the
system. In the extreme case, solutions that lie on the line BC imply that
System A is allocated zero savings – its cost does not change after the
interconnection. The equal sharing point lies right at the center of mass
of the ABC triangle. The set of coalitionally rational imputations is
depicted by the grey polytope, the Core of the game. We see that all of
the considered solutions meet the rationality conditions and are,
therefore, feasible for the current case study. We should also mention
that not only System C is allocated fewer savings by the Nucleolus and
the Shapley value, but also it is far more distant from the Core’s borders
than other players. This fact signifies that System C has less space for
bargaining in negotiations on the project.
To provide more insights about the allocation solutions, we imple­
mented an additional concept that measures players’ propensity to
disrupt. The concept was introduced by Gately [29], who considered
player’s incentives of breaking an agreement and suggested limiting the
ratio of how much other players would lose if player i refuses to coop­
Fig. 2. The set of imputations and the Core of the cooperative game for the erate to how much player i would lose himself.
three-system case. The values represent the corresponding costs for (A, B, C) in The implementation of this concept requires defining a limit on the
$/h. The allocation solutions are denoted as follows: S - the Shapley value, N - maximum propensity for the players. In our case, we consider the im­
the Nucleolus, E − equal sharing point, PtD - regions constrained by players’ putations limited by the propensities equal to one and two. The corre­
propensity to disrupt. sponding regions are shown by the dashed purple triangles in Fig. 2. The
decrease in the limit makes the regions shrink towards the solution
objective function (1), where CGn represents generators’ cost functions where all the players have equal propensities to disrupt, the Gately point
given in Table 1, and CIl stands for net preset costs of investment. Nodal of the cooperative game. In our case study, the solutions by the Shapley
power balance constraints are imposed by (2), where Bn,l is the incidence value and the Nucleolus are within the region where players’ propensity
matrix that contains the topology of interconnections. Generators’ out­ to disrupt is less than one. We, therefore, might conclude that both of
puts, pn , and power flows, fl , are limited by (3) and (4) respectively.
Equation (5) restricts the power lines’ capacities, Fl . The “S” subscript
indicates the scenario (coalition) under consideration. Current model is 3
We do not introduce the solution concepts in this section to focus on the
equivalent to a transportation problem where power demand should be analysis of the case study. The detailed formulations of cooperative games and
supplied at the lowest possible cost. Nevertheless, the discussed solution solution concepts are given in the Appendix.

5
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

these solutions are reasonable for allocating the savings and sharing the These works extensively applied CGT solution concepts to the TEP
investment cost of the TEP project. cost allocation issues.4 They form the first generation of references in
We should also discuss the properties of the formulated cooperative our network and therefore are denoted “G0- …”. The first generation of
game. Note that we solved the cost minimization problem (1)-(5) for citations “G1- …” contains 245 unique papers. And the second genera­
every coalition of the game. Thus, it is guaranteed that the characteristic tion “G2- …” comprises 3690 articles. Thus, the entire citation network
function cannot increase when more players join a coalition. It follows has 3938 nodes (papers) and 5332 edges (citations). We used the Scopus
that our game satisfies condition (6) and is superadditive. To verify the citation database and Gephi software [62] to collect and visualize the
convexity property of the game, we checked condition (8) for all possible references. The review was actual for February 2020.
contributions of players to the coalitions. We found that the players Note that the three pivot papers selected have been published in the
bring higher cost reduction when joining larger coalitions. Thus, the same journal, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems. This could have
cooperative game satisfies condition (7) and is convex. As discussed in distorted our analysis, causing an inclination of the citation network to
the previous section, convexity is one of the most desired properties of include more papers from this journal. However, as discussed in the
cooperative games. It guarantees the nonemptiness of the Core and the bibliometrics Section 4.4, this inclination seems reasonable since IEEE
rationality of the allocation solutions. One may verify using Fig. 2 that Transactions on Power Systems is practically one of the most influential
the Shapley value of a convex game is the center of gravity of the Core. journals covering CGT applications in power systems. Moreover, the
However, the convexity of cooperative games in TEP projects highly selected papers do not encompass all of the initial CGT applications in
depends on the parameters of the systems and topology of the in­ power systems research. There are even earlier publications. For
terconnections. After a series of experiments, we found case studies with example, in Ref. [63], Hobbs and Kelly used cooperative games to
interconnections among four and six systems that lead to nonconvex analyze electric transmission pricing policies in the United States.
cooperative games with an empty Core. In such cases, one or several Chattopadhyay [64] suggested using the Shapley value to allocate cost
players become underestimated in the grand coalition and, therefore, do savings among utilities participating in the emissions trading system.
not have incentives to join it. The conclusion is that, due to the non­ However, such works do not have a strong focus on TEP or transmission
convexity, CGT solution concepts cannot provide meaningful solutions cost allocation and, therefore, were not included as G0 papers.
to some allocation problems in power systems. In such cases, it would To analyze the citation network, we exploited graph layout algo­
not be possible to suggest an incentive-compatible allocation solution rithms that allow spatial mapping of interconnected groups of nodes,
and persuade players to join the grand coalition. We consider the non­ namely “ForceAtlas2” [65] and “Yifan Hu Proportional” [66]. The
convexity of cooperative games as one of the main limitations of CGT community structure was retrieved by the modularity algorithm [67].
and discuss related issues in Section 5. Twenty distinct communities have been identified in the network. For
In this section, we demonstrated how the CGT solution concept convenience, we set the nodes’ sizes proportional to the number of ci­
might be implemented in TEP projects. By analyzing all possible sce­ tations. Therefore, it may be easily detected which studies eventually
narios of cooperation (coalitions), it becomes possible to suggest a attracted more attention of the communities. The largest node of our
rational allocation rule with desired properties, such as efficiency, network (G1-128) has 772 citations and represents the work by McAr­
symmetry, and the null player property. The considered solution con­ thur et al. [68] on multi-agent systems for power engineering
cepts also enable analyzing players’ bargaining power and estimating applications.
the stability of cooperation. Having established an allocation rule, The overview of the entire network is depicted in Fig. 3.5 The iden­
players may use it to split the shares of investment in the cross-border tified communities are highlighted in corresponding colors. It can be
lines and determine the amount of payment for power exports. In the noticed that the structure of the network resembles clouds of papers in
following section, we discuss and classify the more advanced applica­ the communities. Each cloud has distinguished features that allow
tions of CGT solution concepts in power systems. identifying its research direction. We identified the three main di­
rections and, therefore, split the network into three sectors. The central
4. Citation network analysis cloud of the network is formed around the selected pivot papers G0-1,
G0-2, and G0-3. These works are not distant from each other. The
The citation network analysis is a powerful literature review tool that consequent communities form a highly interrelated sector with a focus
allows visualizing existing studies and their relationship as a directed on cost and benefit allocation issues in power systems and CGT appli­
graph. The graph layout and modularity algorithms enable identifica­ cations. The bottom (blue-green) cloud of papers contains the
tion of the research communities and the most relevant references. In mentioned work G1-128 by McArthur et al. [68] and as well as many
this section, we perform a citation network analysis for the existing other studies on multi-agent approach to power systems. The papers of
research on CGT applications in power systems. this sector have not many connections with the remaining network,
Our network is built chronologically: we identify the relevant papers which signifies that this research direction has not much in common
which have a significant citation history (we denote them as generation with the Game Theory applications and cost allocation issues. Finally,
#0); then, we collect the references that cited the initial ones (genera­ the upper cloud of papers can be characterized as studies that involve
tion #1) and the papers that cited those references (generation #2). The transmission expansion algorithms. One of the most significant nodes of
citation relationship among the references presents the evolution of the this sector, G1-149, represents the review of publications and TEP
topic and the allied research directions. We have selected the following models by Latorre et al. [69]. This paper connects to numerous works in
works as the pivot points of the citation network: the sector and contributes to forming the distinct TEP communities of
the network.
• G0-1: (77 citations) Y. Tsukamoto and I. Iyoda, “Allocation of fixed To provide more details on the mentioned research directions and
transmission cost to wheeling transactions by cooperative game
theory,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 11, no. 2, 1996, [30];
• G0-2: (97 citations) J. Contreras and F. F. Wu, “Coalition formation 4
We avoid including the initial work by Gately [29] in the citation network
in transmission expansion planning,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol.
to keep focused on the topic. The reasoning is that this work has a too long and
14, no. 3, 1999, [31];
wide citation history. It has been cited by many game-theoretic and applied
• G0-3: (132 citations) J. M. Zolezzi and H. Rudnick, “Transmission studies that are not relevant to cost allocation problems in power systems.
cost allocation by cooperative games and coalition formation,” IEEE 5
An interactive version of the citation networks is currently available at http
Trans. Power Syst., vol. 17, no. 4, 2002, [32]. ://materials.andreychurkin.ru/network2/, The citation network data (nodes,
edges, and the Gephi file) can be found in the paper’s supplementary materials.

6
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 3. Citation network overview.

7
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 4. The bottom sector: multi-agent systems.

identify additional relevant papers, we describe each of the three sectors main ideas of this research direction.
separately below. As discussed, the upper and the lower sectors reveal One of the most influential works here is the mentioned review of
the aligned research directions. The central sector contains the most multi-agent systems concepts, approaches, and technical challenges by
relevant works to our paper and, therefore, will be examined especially McArthur et al., G1-128 [68]. The review resonated with the community
accurately. To ease the navigation through the presented analysis, we and was cited by numerous studies that form the blue cloud around
denote only the papers under consideration. These nodes have the G1-128. Many works in the community implement multi-agent concepts
following indicators: reference number (in brackets); citation network for microgrids operation and distributed control systems. Bidram et al.
number reflecting the generation of a paper; author names. [70] proposed a secondary voltage control of microgrids based on the
distributed cooperative control of multi-agent systems (G2-1821).
4.1. Multi-agent systems Similar works on distributed control techniques in microgrids are rep­
resented by nodes G2-1703 [71], G2-1845 [72], and G2-1971 [73].
The bottom sector of the citation network (Fig. 4) comprises the Several studies in this community used Game Theory to model microgrid
studies of multi-agent approaches for power systems. Such approaches market operation (G2-1449 [74], G2-1644 [75]).
consider systems with multiple interacting intelligent agents who make The left green community is formed around the node G1-154 that is
independent decisions and follow a beneficial strategy. The goal of these the study by Nagata and Sasaki [76] on a multi-agent approach to power
studies is to develop the design of multi-agent systems and suggest system restoration. The surrounding nodes mainly represent the studies
operation and control algorithms. The multi-agent approaches have on distribution networks and microgrids control and protection man­
been successfully applied in a broad range of engineering problems such agement based on the multi-agent systems approach. At the top of the
as modeling of cooperation and coordination, distributed optimization, sector, we see several stretched communities (highlighted red and
distributed control, multi-agent learning. The formulations of multi- green) that link the sector with the remaining citation network. The
agent systems overlap with game-theoretic models in terms of interac­ nodes such as G1-156 [77] represent the works on multi-agent systems
tion assumptions and areas of application. We, therefore, review the for energy management and distributed control.

8
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 5. The upper sector: expansion planning.

Finally, there is a separate dark-blue community to the right that is proposed using a set of metrics based on changes in surpluses. In the
formed around the work G1-130 by Ilic [78], who discussed the chal­ related study G1-150, Fang and Hill [81] not only elaborated on TEP
lenges of transition from hierarchical to open access power systems, models for competitive electricity markets but also considered uncer­
particularly in design, monitoring and control. The connected papers tainty in power-flow patterns.
also put effort into solving problems of power systems operation and The related peach-colored nodes represent the studies on different
control. Some of them rely on multi-agent system design principles. features of TEP problems. Zhang et al. [82] proposed a multi-stage MILP
Through the above review, we see that the communities in the bot­ algorithm that embeds N-1 security-constrained verification into the
tom sector form a distinct research direction that can be classified as TEP framework (node G2-2600). Linearization of power losses and
multi-agent systems. The authors of the communities use the multi- generation cost functions was used to make the problem tractable.
agent approaches to address the issues of power systems design, oper­ Sauma and Oren [5] presented a concept of proactive transmission
ation and control. Even though not many studies in the sector used Game planning (node G2-2738). In their framework, the competitive interac­
Theory or considered cost allocation issues, it is still useful to analyze the tion among generation firms was taken into account. The decisions of
methods of this aligned research direction. generation capacity investments and production were affected by the
transmission investments and the congestion management protocols.
The interaction was formulated mathematically by means of equilibrium
4.2. Expansion planning problems. Node G2-2688 is the work by Maghouli et al. [83], where the
authors proposed a multi-objective TEP framework for deregulated
Another important sector of the citation network (Fig. 5) comprises power systems. Investment cost, reliability, and congestion cost were
the communities that address planning issues in power systems. One of included in the objective function. The optimal solutions were found
the largest communities (highlighted in peach color) is formed over the using a fuzzy decision making analysis.
nodes G1-149 [69], G1-136 [79], G1-123 [80], and G1-150 [81]. The Summarizing the above references, we can state that the driving
node G1-149 represents the mentioned review by Latorre et al. [69]. This force for research in this community is power system restructuring and
work classified publications and TEP models and found a broad response deregulation (sometimes called unbundling or liberalization). Most of
within the network. Another review of TEP algorithms by Lee et al. [79] the papers around node G1-149 [69] justify their results by the need for
also tightly interrelates with the main papers of the community and is a new TEP framework in the deregulated and competitive environment.
depicted as G1-136. De la Torre et al. [80] presented a Mixed-Integer The main tools exploited include MILP models, multi-stage program­
Linear Program (MILP) for long-term TEP in a competitive pool-based ming, equilibrium models, and multi-objective optimization.
electricity market (node G1-123). To estimate the expansion effect on A slightly different focus can be observed in the articles surrounding
the generators, demands, and the power system as a whole, the authors

9
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

node G1-150 [81]. The authors in this community make efforts to solve constraints if needed. In G1-93, Tohidi and Hesamzadeh [42] formulated
TEP problems under uncertainties. The main tools applied are scenarios TEP with multiple cost-minimizing transmission planners. The
sampling methods and stochastic programming. Yu et al. [84] proposed non-cooperative solutions were found using the worst-case Nash equi­
a chance-constrained TEP formulation to consider uncertainties in wind librium concept. It was shown that without proper compensation
turbines generation (G2-2841). The probabilistic DC power flow calcu­ mechanisms, the non-cooperative transmission planning is inefficient
lations were performed to include the effects of the uncertainties in compared to the cooperative solution.
transmission planning schemes. Several nodes represent the works on The lavender-colored community at the top of the sector features
robust TEP algorithms. For example, in G2-2809, Jabr [85] presented a studies on finding equilibrium solutions in electricity markets. The
robust optimization approach for TEP under uncertainties of renewable reference node G1-145 represents the work by Contreras et al. [2], who
generation and load. The budget of uncertainty was included in the suggested a numerical method for finding Nash-Cournot equilibrium in
model formulation and the Benders decomposition was used to solve the electricity markets. The equilibrium problem was transformed into an
MILP problem iteratively. optimization problem. Then, a relaxation algorithm of the optimum
Several works in the center of the peach-colored community repre­ response function was utilized to find the equilibrium in a finite number
sent the contribution of R. Baldick’s research group. In G2-1204, Park of iterations. In the nearby node G2-2359, Pozo and Contreras [3]
and Baldick [86] considered transmission planning under uncertainties enhanced the method and analyzed multiple Nash equilibria in
of wind availability and system load. A two-stage stochastic model was pool-based markets. The stochastic EPEC model allowed addressing
used to solve the total cost minimization problem through a sequence of multi-period strategic bidding problems with a stochastic demand
stochastic optimization problems and approximations of random pa­ forecast. Most of the related studies follow the same path and develop
rameters. The model was further improved in Ref. [87] (node G2-1171), Nash equilibrium based solutions for electricity markets. Note that this
where the dependence of electric load and available wind power was community mainly focuses on electricity market equilibrium problems,
simulated as the joint distribution using a Gaussian copula. The neigh­ but not TEP. However, equilibrium models have been found very useful
boring node G2-1017 is the study by Majidi-Qadikolai and Baldick [88], in TEP studies to simulate electricity markets outcome and interactions
who proposed an extension to stochastic TEP to integrate N-1 contin­ among independent participants. Therefore, there exist links with the
gency analysis. A three-level filtering algorithm was designed based on neighboring TEP communities. For example, node G1-145 is connected
the important scenario identification index and similar scenario elimi­ to the dark-green community (generation and transmission expansion
nation technique to decrease the number of reliability constraints in planning) via node G2-749, which is the work by Pozo et al. [92] on
stochastic TEP. bilevel models applications to power systems.
The nearby turquoise blue community is formed around node G1- The last expansion planning community contains the pink-colored
111. In this work, Khodaei et al. [89] proposed embedding trans­ nodes in the center of the sector. These studies focus on TEP algo­
mission switching in TEP algorithms. Is was demonstrated that trans­ rithms application and have much in common with the surrounding
mission switching could add flexibility to expansion plans and reduce communities. As a distinct feature, we may highlight the works on dy­
the total planning cost. The TEP model was decomposed into a master namic multi-stage TEP problems. In G1-109, Aguado et al. [93] formu­
problem and subproblems, where the master problem performs trans­ lated a MILP model of dynamic TEP that explicitly considers a multi-year
mission and generation investments, and the subproblems apply trans­ planning horizon. The authors introduced several efficiency metrics to
mission switching to relieve power flow violations and calculate the analyze the TEP effect on generators and demands. The realistic Spanish
optimal dispatch. Many of the related studies elaborate on transmission power system case study was considered with a ten-year planning ho­
topology control and transmission switching effects on power systems rizon. Since multi-stage TEP problems usually involve large-scale opti­
reliability and power markets operation. mization models, multiple authors relied on metaheuristic algorithms in
The dark-green community to the right contains the studies that solving them. For example, in G1-96, Kamyab et al. [94] considered the
combined both generation and transmission expansion planning. Some N-1 reliability criterion in multi-stage TEP and used particle swarm
of the works discussed expansion planning in a multi-regional context optimization method to solve the large-scale non-linear combinatorial
where two or more transmission planners make independent decisions. problem.
The proposed frameworks are based on multi-level optimization, MILP, The references mentioned in this section show that the development
and equilibrium models. Node G1-104 stands for the work by Pozo et al. and application of TEP algorithms is an important research direction
[6], who proposed a three-level static MILP model for generation and that gained increasing attention in the last two decades. The existing
transmission expansion planning. A pool-based market equilibrium was methods mainly rely on mathematical programming. However, dereg­
represented by the lower-level model. Then, the intermediate level ulation in power systems and the emergence of electricity markets posed
introduced generation capacity expansion as the Nash equilibrium new problems for expansion planning. Therefore, classical mathematical
problem. Finally, the upper-level contained a TEP formulation with programming methods are being augmented with game-theoretic
anticipation of the decisions of the other levels. Many of the related models.
works follow the same logic when formulating multi-level TEP models.
The nearby node G1-102 is another work by Pozo et al. [7] where the 4.3. Cooperative Game Theory applications in power systems
anticipative TEP algorithm was illustrated. It was also shown how the
non-cooperative nature of the model produces a range of equilibrium The central sector of the citation network (Fig. 6) contains the three
solutions. A transmission planner, therefore, should decide on consid­ pivot papers: G0-1 [30], G0-2 [31], and G0-3 [32]. It is characterized by
ering the optimistic or pessimistic outcomes. In G1-105, Munoz et al. extensive use of CGT for solving cost and benefit allocation problems in
[90] analyzed the impact of wind power generation on long-term TEP. power systems. Below, we examine the notable contributions of the
The model incorporated the variability of wind resources and its influ­ communities involved and complement our review of existing research
ence on system security and reserve market. The loss of load expectation with more actual references.
constraint was used to guarantee a minimum system security level. The largest community (highlighted in pink) was formed around the
Several works in the community, such as G1-107 and G1-93, works by Tsukamoto and Iyoda [30] (node G0-1) and by Zolezzi and
considered multi-regional TEP problems. In G1-107, Khodaei et al. Rudnick [32] (node G-03). The surrounding papers adopted and devel­
[91] proposed coordination of long-term and short-term expansion oped the ideas of cooperative game formulation in power systems. Some
planning. The multi-area expansion planning problem was decomposed of the works focus on transmission cost allocation issues, while others
into a planning problem and annual reliability subproblems which verify found different applications such as allocation of power losses. How­
the reliability conditions for transmission plans and impose additional ever, most of the papers in the community did not notice or cite the

10
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 6. The central sector: Cooperative Game Theory applications in power systems.

second pivot paper by Contreras and Wu [31] (node G0-2). The possible Several studies applied CGT solution concepts to allocate power
reasoning is that Contreras and Wu had a shift towards coalitional for­ losses. For example, in G1-185, Sharma and Abhyankar [60] suggested
mation in their work. Less attention was paid to applications of existing power losses allocation in radial distribution systems according to the
CGT solution concepts. Thus, the community better acknowledged the Shapley value. A sequential Shapley value method was proposed to
works G0-1 and G0-3. reduce the computational burden when allocating the losses among
Node G1-32 to the right represents the review of cooperative games distributed generators and loads.
and cost allocation problems by Fiestras-Janeiro et al. [95]. The authors At the top of the community, we see the mentioned works by Evans
considered possible applications of transferable utility cooperative et al. [47] (node G1-66) and by Ruiz and Contreras [49] (node G1-51). In
games in transportation, natural resources, and power industry. The G1-66, a transmission expansion cost assignment model was proposed
review summarizes the main ideas of cost allocation solution concepts in that considers independent cooperative games for each expansion
power systems and refers to other papers in the community. Node G1-61 segment. The Kernel solution concept was used to find individual cost
is the previously mentioned work by Stamtsis and Erlich [48] on CGT allocations. The resulting solution summed up the individual allocations
applications in power system fixed-cost allocation. The authors illus­ for each expansion segment. In G1-51, an allocation scheme was pre­
trated how collective network usage leads to cost savings. The Shapley sented that considers market participants’ incentives to support an
value and the Nucleolus solution concepts were used for cost allocation. expansion plan. In the model, each prosumer and each producer were
Node G1-37 stands for the above-discussed study by Bhakar et al. [51], assigned voting weights that reflect the level of firms’ influence on
who introduced a probabilistic CGT approach to network cost allocation. transmission expansion decisions. Thus, it becomes necessary to suggest
The probabilistic extension of the allocation solutions could be useful for a vector of payments in such a way that the total sum of votes on an
the case studies where it is possible to evaluate the probabilities of co­ expansion plan would be higher than some positive parameter. Other­
alitions formation. wise, market participants would not agree on network expansion. Node
A different application of the CGT solution concepts can be found in G1-86 represents the work by Csercsik [98], who analyzed the effects of
G2-143, where Dabbagh and Sheikh-El-Eslami [96] considered allocation cooperation, asymmetric information, and market regulations on the
of virtual power plant’s profit among its distributed energy resources. In profit of generator companies. A transferable utility game framework
this framework, distributed generators cooperated in the day-ahead and was used for profit estimation. A recent work [56] (represented by node
balancing markets to reach the desired risk-aversion level. The payoffs G2-263) analyzed cross-border power interconnection projects. It dem­
to the generators were calculated based on the Shapley value and the onstrates how CGT solution concepts can be implemented in a
Nucleolus. real-world case study of power interconnections in Northeast Asia.
In G1-35, Rao et al. [97] compared existing approaches for trans­ The second-largest community of the sector is presented by the blue
mission usage cost allocation. The authors suggested a min-max fair colored nodes. These studies also focus on CGT solution concepts ap­
power flow tracing approach and argued that it might be superior to the plications to power systems allocation issues. Notably, many of the
CGT solution concepts, marginal participation method, “with and works in the community exploited the Aumann-Shapley value, which is
without transit”, and other methods. an extension of the Shapley value solution concept to infinite games. The

11
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

two central blue nodes G1-234 and G1-200 represent the earlier sources. Thus, it is necessary to include the flexibility providers in GTEP
mentioned studies on transmission network cost allocation by Junqueira models. The authors suggested evaluating all possible scenarios of
et al. [52] and by Molina et al. [53]. In G1-234, the authors introduced expansion planning and ranking spatially distributed flexibility pro­
an Aumann–Shapley approach for transmission cost allocation and viders according to the Shapley value. The effects of renewables share
compared it with existing pricing mechanisms such as the Average levels on operational costs, CO2 emissions reduction, and marginal
Participation Factors (APF) method and the Long Run Marginal Costs system value of the flexibility providers were illustrated based on the
(LRMC) scheme. It was illustrated that the “infinitesimal agents” idea North Sea Offshore Grid case study.
behind the Aumann–Shapley approach allows avoiding the computa­ The neighboring nodes G1-188, G1-189 are the papers by Banez-
tional feasibility issues of the original Shapley value concept and elim­ Chicharro et al. [59,103] on transmission expansion projects benefits
inates the dependence on the size of the agents. The approach was tested estimation using the Aumann-Shapley approach. In G1-188, the authors
on the Brazilian network case study, for which the transmission tariffs formulated a cooperative game to allocate the benefits of an expansion
distribution was estimated. The authors of G1-200 agree with the dis­ plan to individual expansion projects. The Aumann-Shapley approach
advantages of the Shapley value’s combinatorial nature and suggest a was compared to the existing project evaluation schemes such as “take
similar method based on circuit theory and the Aumann-Shapley value. out one at a time” and “put in one at a time”. It was shown that project
The proposed method considers active and reactive power flows and importance ranking by the Aumann-Shapley value might lead to higher
allows identifying transmission cost allocation among generators and net benefits while satisfying consistency and fairness properties. In
consumers. G1-189, the authors exploited the similar Aumann-Shapley approach to
In G2-3618, Molina et al. [99] used a similar Aumann-Shapley address the issue of transmission expansion projects benefits allocation
approach to power losses allocation. The model included both active among the users of transmission networks.
and reactive losses and allowed allocating them among generators and The distant blue nodes to the right represent a group of studies on
loads. It was illustrated that because of the counter-flows, some partic­ demand-side management. The reference node G1-89 is the work by
ipants may have negative allocations and should be therefore subsi­ Haring et al. [104], who compared centralized and decentralized con­
dized. Many of the related studies at the bottom of the blue community tract designs for demand response programs. The authors formulated the
also elaborate on transmission losses allocation methods. decentralized contract proposal scheme as a heuristic process based on
Srinivasan et al. [100] formulated strategic bidding and cooperation Q-learning. Consumer’s incentives to join the coalitions were expressed
strategies for consumers in power markets (node G2-193). It was shown by means of CGT. It was found that the level of demand response
that because of the network’s physical constraints, consumers might be exploitation depends on information accuracy and coalition formation
able to influence the market by cooperating with each other. The costs.
coevolutionary algorithm was used for market modeling under deter­ We should also mention the citations of the second pivot paper G0-2
ministic and stochastic conditions. The values of the coalitions were by Contreras and Wu [31]. As discussed above, few of the game-theoretic
defined by CGT concepts. works in the pink community did refer to G0-2. Instead, the paper drew
Cooperation can take a multi-level form. This happens when groups much more attention from the expansion planning communities at the
of players cooperate, or there is a hierarchical structure (subordination) top of the network. Many of the key works in TEP and GTEP, such as
between them. Thus, there is a need to consider both the upper-level G1-104 [6], G1-111 [89], G1-123 [80], G1-149 [69], and G1-150 [81],
cooperation and the allocation of value within groups. To this end, referred to the Contreras’ initial paper as one of the first studies on
node G2-3430 is a recent work by Petrosyan and Sedakov [101], who coalition formation and CGT application in power systems. Nonetheless,
proposed an allocation procedure for two-level cooperation in network no significant community was formed around G0-2. The surrounding
games. green colored nodes split into different research directions. Several
The left side of the blue community contains papers with a focus on works elaborate on TEP and allocation issues. In G1-55, Hu et al. [105]
CGT applications in smart grids and microgrids. The large node G2-3541 applied CGT for allocating generators start-up costs among power con­
is the review of game-theoretic methods for smart grids by Saad et al. sumers. A multiperiod unit commitment problem was formulated to
[22]. The authors argue that emerging technologies in communications identify the optimal dispatch of generating units. Then, the estimated
and control make it possible to apply Non-cooperative and Cooperative start-up and no-load costs were allocated by the Nucleolus and the
Game Theory techniques to address the challenges in smart grids. The Shapley value solution concepts. In this manner, the proposed frame­
neighboring node G1-11 represents the work by Du et al. [57], who work allowed the unbundling of fixed and variable operating costs. In
studied the potential advantages of cooperation among multiple G1-38, Xie et al. [106] presented an emission-constrained generation
microgrids with distributed energy resources. In this framework, coop­ scheduling model in which the trading of emission allowance was
erating microgrids could be dispatched in a centralized manner to reach optimized. The resulting cost reduction was allocated among generators
a reduction in operating cost. The Nucleolus solution concept was used according to the Shapley value. A couple of neighboring nodes represent
for cost allocation. To overcome the computational issues, authors the contribution of N. Voropai’s research group to TEP modeling, co­
suggested finding the Nucleolus via Benders decomposition. ordination and allocation methods. In G1-138, Voropai and Ivanova
Another elegant application of the Aumann-Shapley concept can be [107] formulated a game-theoretic approach for the cooperation of
found in G1-225, where Faria et al. [58] examined the allocation of firm power supply companies in expansion planning. The authors examined
energy rights among hydropower plants. It was shown that synergy different criteria of cooperation and used the Shapley value for benefits
benefits could happen in coordinated firm energy production compared allocation. Other green nodes represent not relevant topics (such as
to the separate operation of hydro plants. Such situations are usual for radio resource allocation problems) and therefore are not considered in
plants located in a cascade (in the same river basin). The authors the review.
compared several methods for firm energy rights allocation and argued Lastly, we briefly describe the minor communities of the central
that the Aumann-Shapley approach provides the most reasonable re­ sector. The light brown group of nodes to the right comprises the studies
sults. Several cases of river cascades in Brazil were analyzed to reveal the on transmission management and pricing mechanisms. In G1-74, Mar­
dependence of firm energy rights allocation on the reservoirs of up­ angon Lima and de Oliveira [108] discussed the long-term effect of
stream and downstream power plants. A somewhat similar idea was transmission pricing on generation and transmission expansion plan­
proposed by Kristiansen et al. [102] for power system flexibility analysis ning. The adjoint node G2-550 is the review of the transmission man­
(node G1-82). It was discussed that flexibility providers such as agement methods in deregulated power systems by Christie et al. [109].
fast-ramping gas turbines or demand-side management are needed to Most of the related works focused on transmission pricing, wheeling of
accommodate a significant amount of variable renewable energy power, and congestion management.

12
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

The issues of transmission tariffs and charges are also addressed by G0-3 and feature overlapping issues in coalition formation. For example,
the works in the light red colored community. In G1-220, Olmos and in G1-219, Zhang et al. [118] used particle swarm optimization to
Perez-Arriaga [110] proposed a transmission charges method based on identify overlapping coalitions formation in multiple project tasks (sit­
average participation factors and argued that it might complement the uations where a player can participate in several coalitions
existing locational marginal pricing (LMP) approach. Another discussion simultaneously).
of tariff design methodologies in distribution networks was presented by At this point, we have reviewed most of the existing relevant studies
Rodrıguez Ortega et al. [111] in node G1-122. There is still an ongoing on CGT applications in power systems. We found that the topic signifi­
interest in transmission network tariffs research. Modern studies suggest cantly evolved since the initial works G0-1 [30], G0-2 [31], and G0-3
using more sophisticated approaches such as multi-level and equilib­ [32]. The allocation concepts have been applied from a variety of an­
rium modeling. In the recent study G2-3566, Grimm et al. [112] gles, and the models complexified considerably. The identified appli­
analyzed subsidization schemes effect on locational choices of genera­ cations can be classified into essential and specific approaches. The
tion investment in electricity markets. Regionally differentiated network essential approaches involve the straightforward modeling of player
fees were introduced in the model as a component of payment by gen­ interactions in power markets and expansion planning projects. We
erators. It was found that the proposed scheme influences investment include the following applications here:
and decommissioning decisions and might lead to welfare gains.
The orange community below features the studies on transmission • Allocation of costs (usually operating) or benefits (cost savings or
loss allocation. In G1-124, Lima et al. [113] analyzed loss allocation to welfare gains) among the power market participants (generators and
generators and demands using CGT principles. Equivalent bilateral ex­ demands) [95,98,100];
changes were considered as independent players of the game. The • Allocation of transmission costs among electricity market partici­
related studies further elaborate on loss allocation methods using pants (development of new transmission pricing mechanisms) [48,
multidisciplinary approaches. For example, Dev Choudhury and Goswami 52,53,97,108];
[114] suggested combining CGT and artificial neural networks for • Solving the mentioned allocation issues as a part of TEP or GTEP [47,
solving transmission loss allocation problems (node G1-205). The au­ 49,50,59,103,107,115];
thors considered bilateral contracts in electricity markets and argued • Development of transmission investment mechanisms (incentive
that loss allocation by the Shapley value might be intractable for real schemes to encourage transmission investments in the competitive
power systems. Thus, an artificial neural network was trained on a large electricity market environment) [49,50];
amount of generated sample cases and then tested on IEEE 14 and 30 bus • Identification of beneficiaries in expansion projects [103] and
systems. ranking projects within an expansion plan [59];
In the minor black colored community to the left, the significant • Multi-regional expansion planning (usually, cross-border power
contribution was made by K. N. Hasan to CGT applications in power interconnection projects) [54–56];
systems. In G1-97, Hasan et al. [115] considered TEP for renewables • Cooperation among microgrids [22,28,57];
integration in remote areas of the Australian grid. Such • Allocation of benefits within virtual power plants [96].
location-constrained projects require building long capital intensive
interconnections. Under the existing transmission pricing mechanisms, Other approaches suggest unique ways of cooperative game formu­
the transmission fee for the newly built renewable generation could be lation. Sometimes, these formulations are not straightforward (for
unreasonably high. The authors discussed the issues in transmission example, players of a game can hardly be called players in the usual
pricing policies and suggested using the Shapley value for transmission sense). We mention the following specific applications:
cost allocation among market participants. In G1-179, Hasan et al. [116]
presented a unique CGT application to power system stability analysis. • Allocation of power losses (instead of the total cost, the allocation of
The authors formulated small uncertain disturbances as players of the losses among the agents, sometimes, among bilateral contracts) [60,
cooperative game and used several allocation concepts to rank the most 99,113,114];
influential parameters. It was shown that the suggested game-theoretic • Using probabilistic game approaches for cost allocation (requires
probabilistic power system analysis tool might be superior to common additional data on probabilities of coalitions) [51];
sensitivity analysis methods. • Allocation of firm-energy rights or emission allowances [58];
A small dark brown colored community at the top of the sector also • Ranking of flexible generation projects to accommodate renewable
features CGT applications in electricity markets and TEP. Node G1-116 energy sources [102];
is the earlier mentioned work by Contreras et al. [50], who suggested an • Cost allocation in unit commitment (for example, mechanisms for
incentive-based mechanism for transmission investment. A decentral­ start-up costs allocation) [105,106];
ized investment model was suggested considering each investor as an • Power system stability analysis (contingency ranking based on CGT
independent player. Then, the rewarding procedure iteratively evalu­ principles) [116].
ated possible welfare gains and allocated them among the investors
using the Shapley value. The expansion plan was considered settled once Below, we summarize the citation network analysis, highlight the
all the investors decided on the rationality of their TEP projects (no more most notable contributions by the authors, rank the journals that
investors were willing to build additional transmission assets). In the covered the field, and analyze the frequent keywords of the research.
linked node G2-1066, Lo Prete and Hobbs [28] examined incentives for
market participants to cooperate in microgrid forming. A CGT frame­ 4.4. Bibliometrics and summaries
work was used to quantify cost and benefit allocation among the market
participants. It was reported that market failure could lead to the The citation network analysis revealed the structure of the existing
misalignment between the social and private objectives and inefficient research and allowed us to locate the most relevant works in the field.
scale and types of microgrid installations. We found several communities (mainly related to nodes G0-1 [30] and
The far-left purple community has very few connections with the G0-3 [32]) that extensively apply CGT in power system research. There
remaining citation network (only with G0-2 and G0-3 directly) and is ongoing work on improving the existing approaches to allocation
represents the studies on coalition formation. In G1-129, An et al. [117] problems and finding novel applications of the solution concepts.
proposed dynamic coalition formation algorithms and referred to the In this section, we provide more details on the identified research
work by Contreras (node G0-2) as an example of coalition formation directions and highlight the relevance of our work. To analyze the
analysis in TEP. The neighboring purple nodes refer to Zolezzi’s work evolution of the research, we collected data on the annual number of

13
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 7. Analysis of the publications evolution: the cumulative number of published works.

Fig. 8. Analysis of the publications evolution: annual changes in the number of published works.

publications included in the citation network. A total of 3938 works agent systems. But, since 2015, there emerged a clear upward trend in
were considered in the period from 1996 till the first quarter of 2020. the research on CGT applications. As a result, in 2019 and the first
Fig. 7 shows the cumulative number of publications per year. The quarter of 2020, Cooperative Game Theory applications covered in our
resulting curve resembles exponential growth. Thus, we may conclude, citation network surpass the aligned research directions in the number
while acknowledging the limited selection of papers in the citation of new publications. We see the following possible reasoning for the
network, that the topic evolves and gains more attention from the power upward trend. While being useful for finding optimal (for example, least-
systems research community. We also plot the three identified research cost) decisions, classical expansion planning approaches are not able to
directions separately. At first glance, it seems that the sectors are almost fully address the modern issues of deregulated power systems. There is a
balanced in the number of publications and the development pace. need for novel methods applicable to the multi-agent environment that
In Fig. 8, we plot the annual changes in the number of published include allocation mechanisms and can provide effective economic in­
works. It is seen that between 2010 and 2018, CGT applications in power centives to independent participants. Even in the presence of the plan­
systems were gaining less attention than expansion planning and multi- ning and coordinating entities such as regional transmission

14
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 9. Analysis of publications evolution: most published authors.

organizations and ENTSO-E, it is still necessary to develop rational cost contributions by the authors and the most influential journals consid­
and benefit allocation rules and inter-PSO compensation mechanisms. In ered in the citation network. Fig. 9 presents a list of the authors with the
Ref. [47], Evans et al. said, “A network expansion can generate multiple highest number of publications covered by the citation network. The
effects, such as load flow changes, relief of congested lines, etc., as well associated topics are placed to the right of the author names. The chart is
as a variation of the benefit of the connected agents, depending on headed by R. Romero, who significantly contributed to TEP algorithms,
existing expansion plans. Game theory, and Cooperative Game Theory in MIP and metaheuristic methods for power systems. Even though not
particular, arises as an appealing tool to deal with the matter, with ad­ mentioned directly in the analysis, Romero is a co-author of multiple
vantages over other cost assignment methods, given it considers inter­ papers in the expansion planning sector, especially around node G1-150
action by the agents and their rationality in decision making.” In [81]. Next, we should mention the contribution by J. Contreras, who is
Ref. [48], Stamtsis and Erlich mentioned, “In the modern deregulated the author of one of the earliest papers on CGT applications in power
electricity markets the issue of network fixed-cost allocation is of great systems, G0-2 [31]. In the subsequent studies, Contreras focused on
significance. The reason for this is that the fixed-costs are the largest part expansion planning issues and made a significant contribution to TEP
of transmission charges. Therefore, it becomes obvious that there is a big algorithms and power market analysis methods. He actively used MIP
demand for a fair and effective allocation of the costs among the market [80], multi-level optimization [6,7], equilibrium models [2,3], and CGT
participants. Discrimination policies, by assigning unreasonably high solution concepts [49,50,113]. E. Sauma also elaborated on TEP and
use-of-network charges, could be applied in order to prevent some GTEP problems and has published a number of works in the expansion
market participants accessing a part or even the whole network. Several planning sector, mainly in the dark-green community around G1-104
methods have been proposed for a proper allocation of fixed-costs. [6], G1-102 [7], G1-105 [90]. Another influential author in the expan­
Although these methods are well established from an engineering sion planning research is M. J. Rider, who focused on TEP with security
point of view, some of them may fail to send the right economical sig­ constraints and uncertain parameters. He is a co-author of many works
nals.” The authors then concluded that Cooperative Game Theory could in the peach-colored community around nodes G1-149 [69] and G1-150
be a good basis for reasonable and economically efficient allocations. In [81]. Other notable authors in the expansion planning research are M. R.
Ref. [49], Ruiz and Contreras also referred to the restructured market Hesamzadeh, M. Rashidinejad, Z.-Y. Dong, M. Shahidehpour, J. Choi, B.
environment. They justified the need for using Cooperative Game The­ F. Hobbs, D. Pozo, H. Cheng, A. J. Conejo, R. Baldick.
ory in the following way, “In this multi-player setting, the lack of Stephen McArthur is the author of the influential work G1-128 [68].
appropriate incentives has resulted in investments in transmission not He found numerous applications of the multi-agent systems in power
keeping pace with load growth and investments in generation. As a engineering and published multiple papers in the bottom sector of the
result, the network is being frequently used at its maximum limits, citation network. C. Rehtanz also used multi-agent systems approach for
leading to economic inefficiencies and reduced reliability. Hence, new, power system planning and control. He contributed to multiple works
effective incentive schemes are needed for transmission network located around node G1-128 [68] and G1-154 [76]. Moreover, he is a
expansion. The incentives have to take into account both the prospective co-author of several TEP papers related to G1-149 [69], in particular,
investors and the prospective users of the new assets.” To solve the studies on FACTS devices investment. D. Srinivasan wrote several highly
above cooperation and cost allocation issues, more scientists turn cited papers on multi-agent system applications, mostly in microgrids
attention to Cooperative Game Theory and other multidisciplinary (G2-1971 [73]). Srinivasan also contributed to analysis of cooperative
approaches. behavior and bidding strategies in power markets G2-193 [100]. Other
At the end of the analysis, we discuss the most significant notable authors in the multi-agent systems research direction are P. H.

15
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 10. Analysis of publications evolution: the author-level citation network.

Nguyen, A. Monti, T. Nagata, F. Ponci, W. L. Kling, S. Lehnhoff. Padhy is a co-author of several works related to G1-74 [108] and the
In the central sector of the network we should mention H. Rudnick, mentioned paper on probabilistic game-theoretic approach G1-37 [51].
who has published one of the pioneer works G0-3 [32] on CGT solutions L. Olmos studied transmission expansion issues related to cost and
to transmission cost allocation. In the next decades, Rudnick continued benefit allocation, transmission pricing, and compensation mechanisms.
studying cooperation and coordination issues in power systems and He is the author of several papers in the central blue colored community.
contributed to many works in expansion planning research and Game In the mentioned works G1-188 [59] and G1-189 [103], Olmos imple­
Theory applications. F. Li published multiple works on transmission mented an Aumann-Shapley approach for benefits allocation in trans­
pricing mechanisms. Most of these works are located in the light brown mission expansion projects.
community near node G1-74 [108]. F. Wen is a co-author of a number of For the sake of visibility, we composed an author-level network
papers on transmission fixed costs allocation methods and transmission representing interrelation between the most published authors, as
tariffs. N. P. Padhy contributed to transmission cost allocation methods. shown in Fig. 10. Each author is depicted as a node which size is

16
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 11. Analysis of publications evolution: most influential journals.

proportional to the number of publications in the initial citation “Shapley value”) AND TITLE-ABS-KEY (“Power System” OR “Trans­
network. The links between authors represent citations or co- mission expansion” OR “Expansion planning”). This query produced
authorships. Thus, thick lines indicate strong ties between authors. We 1054 documents published from 1970 up to the present. Sorting these
displayed only the authors who have published not less than ten papers publications reveals the following two most influential journals: Dianli
included in the initial citation network, which results in 144 nodes. We Xitong Zidonghua/Automation of Electric Power Systems, with 87 pa­
used a heat map with three colors to illustrate the authors’ degree of pers in the query; IEEE Transactions on Power Systems with 79 papers in
involvement in the research directions: TEP; CGT applications in power the query. The remaining journals have much fewer publications on
systems; Multi-agent systems. Game Theory, power systems, and TEP. The ranking of the journals re­
We see that a number of authors have put effort into solving cost sembles the results presented in Fig. 11. Thus, we can state that our
allocation issues in power systems. Some of them relied on CGT solution analysis of the most influential journals is reasonable.
concepts and founded the novel multidisciplinary research direction. Finally, we present a keyword analysis of the papers covered in the
Figs. 9 and 10 allow identifying the leading authors in the field, as well citation network to distinguish the main indicators of the research. Each
as authors’ interrelation. However, the presented analysis does not node of the citation network (paper) has been split into several nodes
reveal the overall impact of the authors. It cannot be used as a metric to (related keywords). Then we merged the repeating keywords and
compare author productivity or importance. Our ranking is based on the launched the modularity algorithm [67] to highlight the research di­
relevance to CGT applications in power system expansion planning, i.e., rections based on those keywords. The initial keyword network con­
how close the authors are to the selected G0 papers [30–32]. tained more than 7000 unique words and 90 000 links between them,
We also show the list of the most influential journals of the citation which is impossible to display. Therefore, we removed most of the
network in Fig. 11. There is a significant shift in the number of publi­ keywords and kept only the frequent ones (that are mentioned in more
cations towards the IEEE Transactions on Power Systems journal. The than ten papers). The Fruchterman-Reingold graph drawing algorithm
reasoning could lie in the computational aspects of power systems [119] was used to locate the remaining keywords. For the sake of con­
modeling. There is a need to use advanced computational techniques sistency, we selected the same color scheme as in the author-level
and analytical methods for power systems planning, operations and citation network. The resulting scheme presented in Fig. 12 turned out
control. Many authors in the citation network work on developing new to be highly intuitive.
algorithms for electricity market mechanisms, stability control, TEP and The keyword analysis confirms our classification of the research di­
GTEP, and therefore prefer to publish in the journal with engineering rections. Indeed, the considered studies can be grouped into game-
and mathematical audience. Other journals in the list not only focus on theoretic works, research on expansion planning, and multi-agent sys­
power systems modeling and algorithms development but also case tems application. We also used the identified keywords to look for the
study applications, energy economics and policies. missing contributions and suggest them as a future research trajectory.
Such an imbalance in the distribution of papers by journals could In the following sections, we discuss the main challenges and limitations
also be caused by our selective collection of the G0 papers. The three of the CGT applications in power systems and conclude the review.
pivot papers selected have been published in IEEE Transactions on
Power Systems. This could have caused an inclination of the citation 5. Discussion of the main challenges, limitations, and future
network to include more papers from this journal. However, we argue work
that this inclination is not artificial or mistaken. To prove this, we per­
formed additional analysis of publications using the Scopus database. In this section, we discuss the applicability of the CGT solution
We created the following query: TITLE-ABS-KEY (“Game Theory” OR concepts to power systems allocation problems. We also consider the

17
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 12. Keyword analysis.

main challenges and limitations of these concepts and identify the possible to estimate the Shapley value for such a high number of players.
missing research directions. The section highlights the main issues The authors also mentioned the computational efficiency of the Core of
future research should be focused on. the game, “the major difficulty in the calculation of the Core in realistic
situations is the exponential increase of the Core constraints with the
number of plants: a system with ten plants would have 1000 constraints,
5.1. Scalability and the modeling of 40 plants would require about one trillion
constraints.”
One of the most challenging limitations of CGT is the scalability of Under such circumstances, several studies exploited the Aumann-
the solution concepts. Most of the covered studies considered a moder­ Shapley value, which provides an analytical solution to allocation
ate number of players in the cooperative game formulations, which is problems where each agent could be divided into infinitesimal parts.
two - six participants of a project. It was reported that the imple­ This solution has a decreased computational burden and can be applied
mentation of the solution concepts for realistic systems with more to cooperative games with dozens and hundreds of players. Additionally,
players would be computationally infeasible. Indeed, the number of many authors praised the isonomy of the Aumann-Shapley value. This
scenarios to consider (coalitions) grows exponentially with the number property makes the allocation solution irrelevant to the size or capacity
of players. The number of possible orderings in the Shapley value grows of the players since only infinitesimal shares of their capacities are
factorially. In Ref. [58], Faria et al. examined the Brazilian power sys­ considered. Studies as [31,60] proposed using the allocation rules in a
tem, which has around one hundred hydro plants. It is practically not

18
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

sequential manner, which also allows decreasing the computational algorithms and mechanisms that avoid nonconvex cooperative games
complexity. would be highly useful for practical applications.
Certainly, there is a need for developing new cooperative game
formulations that would enable accounting for more players. Such for­ 5.3. Coalition formation and other assumptions
mulations might include decomposition techniques and approximations
of the allocation rules, coalitional structure, etc. We found that several CGT introduces several assumptions that might not hold in power
studies ran into scalability issues while implementing CGT solution systems. The main assumption is that the grand coalition will form. In
concepts in power systems. Freire et al. [120] and later Du et al. [57] reality, players, say generating companies, investors, or independent
used Benders decomposition to compute the Nucleolus for cooperative SOs, might not be necessarily obliged to join the coalitions. In this case,
games with a large number of players. In Ref. [120], the authors sug­ they might refuse to join the grand coalition if it is not incentive
gested an approach for sharing quotas of a renewable energy sources compatible for them. Therefore, to correctly implement the CGT solu­
pool among different companies. Pools with up to fifty companies have tion concepts, there is a need to establish a coordinating entity and
been studied, which led to cooperative games with up to 1.1⋅1015 co­ protocols of cooperation.
alitions. An optimization model similar to (24)–(28) failed to compute Moreover, CGT considers the coalitions of players as equally
the Nucleolus for such games. However, the proposed decomposition possible. In Ref. [30], Tsukamoto and Iyoda compared the coalitions with
procedure was able to find it through a series of Benders cuts. In player’s cards in the negotiation process. They mention that “the sub­
Ref. [57], the authors considered the coordination of multiple micro­ coalition is never actually realized, but is presented as a basis of an
grids to minimize total operation cost. They followed the same decom­ assertion in the negotiation”. Such logic could be controversial for some
position logic and effectively allocated the cost in a cooperative game applications. In practice, it might be necessary to add corrections to the
among thirty microgrids. We consider these works as reference points coalition formation assumptions. For example, Bhakar et al. [51] sug­
for further research on cooperative games decomposition. Alternating gested modeling the probability of the existence of players, the proba­
direction method of multipliers [121] and other decomposition methods bility of the existence of coalitions, and the probability of players joining
might also be applied to decompose the problem by coalitions. Appli­ a particular coalition.
cations of machine learning techniques in the field could be rather Choosing an appropriate single-valued solution concept is also a
promising, as demonstrated by Dev Choudhury and Goswami [114]. disputable task. Many authors mentioned that the definition of the
Note that cooperative games with a high number of players may fairness of a solution concept is controversial. Therefore, it is not clear
provide hardly-interpretable results. It might be problematic to under­ whether the Shapley value is an adequate solution for certain problems
stand why and how certain players affect others. Moreover, such for­ or not. The Nucleolus is also open to criticism, as discussed in the Ap­
mulations imply that numerous participants, sometimes irrelevant to pendix. Set solution concepts as the Core definitely make sense for the
each other, agree on joining the grand coalition, which might not analysis of cooperation. However, the Core, if nonempty, provides a
happen in practice. In such cases, it would make sense to consider variety of solutions, which may not be useful in practical applications.
several separate cooperative games with a moderate number of players. Some authors mentioned the transferable utility assumption as a
crucial one. The point is that in practice, it may not be possible to fully
5.2. Nonconvex cooperative games represent the worth of cooperation in transferable units, say monetarily.
Moreover, the outcome of cooperation could be multi-valued. For
The discussed concepts, such as the Shapley value and the Nucleolus, example, electricity trade could lead to cost reduction, CO2 emissions
are guaranteed to provide rational solutions only for the class of convex reduction, and an increase in power losses.
games. However, technical limitations of power systems (topology of In this regard, the future research trajectory could focus on the
interconnections, maximum capacity of lines and generators) could lead relaxation of the mentioned assumptions. It is also worth developing the
to nonconvex cooperative games. In such cases, marginal contribution mechanisms of cooperation that would enable cooperation in power
by certain players to subcoalitions could be higher than to the grand systems while keeping the CGT assumptions actual. Note that current
coalition. As an extreme example of this violation, the Core of the game CGT applications consider static problems, where a single snapshot of a
could become an empty set. Other examples include cooperative games system and proposed cooperation (usually at the planning stage) is
with the Core that could be rather small in volume or be very distant analyzed. However, it is worth addressing the dynamic nature of
from some players. Even the Shapley value could fall out of the Core, cooperation. For example, in the first stage, players may cooperate in
which signifies that contribution by some players is underestimated in planning and building assets. Then, several stages of operation follow.
the grand coalition. The decreased volume of the Core indicates issues During the operation, some players may change their initially declared
with the stability of cooperation. The point is that there are not many strategy or refuse cooperation at all.
rational allocation solutions to consider. Under some changes in data
provided by the players, the Core could become an empty set, and the 5.4. Ex-post game-theoretic analysis
cooperation would no longer be rational for the players.
Even though some of the authors formally verified that their models Existing works on CGT applications in power systems exploit the
lead to convex cooperative games, there is no proof that the entire class solution concepts in an ex-post manner, in a similar way that we
of proposed games is convex. That is, under specific changes in pa­ demonstrated in Section 3. The common approach is first to solve a
rameters, the mechanisms of cooperation would fail. For example, in model for all possible scenarios of cooperation (coalitions) and formu­
Ref. [56], we considered a transmission expansion case with six players late the characteristic function. Then, the solution concepts are used to
and hybrid topology of interconnections. We found that the cooperative allocate the value of cooperation. This approach enables analyzing the
game over the optimal expansion plan is nonconvex. We then tuned the optimal plan (calculated in a centralized manner), estimating the sta­
parameters of the system and were able to identify cooperative games bility of cooperation and the bargaining power of players.
with an empty Core. However, some players may have additional expectations or re­
Definitely, arranging cooperation over nonconvex games could be a quirements on their minimal share of benefits or levels of usefulness in
practical issue since solution concepts might fail to provide rational the coalition. A coordinating entity may also want to reach a coopera­
results. In the light of this, there is a need for producing proofs of con­ tion with a desired level of stability. Therefore, a more promising
vexity for cooperative game formulations in power systems. Alterna­ approach would be incorporating CGT principles into planning and
tively, it is necessary to identify the weak points of cooperation and operation algorithms. Such an approach would enable identification of
parameters that may cause nonconvexity. The development of decisions in an anticipating manner to obtain a cooperative game with

19
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

desired properties. Specifically, the convexity condition or limits of Algorithmic Mechanism Design has been implemented in various
players’ bargaining power can be imposed. We believe that the inclusion studies, which include auctions, markets, routing games, resource allo­
of the CGT principles can be done by means of bilevel programming [1]. cation, network formation games, and scheduling problems. In
The upper-level of the program should contain optimization of possible Ref. [127], Grosu and Chronopoulos presented an algorithmic mechanism
coalitions of players, while the lower-level would state the characteristic design for load balancing in distributed systems. A computational grid
function of the cooperative game and impose game-theoretic with selfish agents (computers) was considered, where each agent was
constraints. supposed to misreport information on its processing rate to get addi­
The inclusion of CGT principles into the existing planning and tional payment. The authors proved that the optimal allocation algo­
operating models might provide additional insights into the structure of rithm can be used with the truthful payment scheme and analyzed
cooperation. Moreover, it would allow a coordinating entity to produce performance degradation and fairness index under the proposed
a “menu” of possible decisions and modify the coalitions if needed. We mechanism.
consider the idea of the anticipating application of CGT highly prom­ However, in power systems, there is almost no research on the
ising and outline it as a future research direction. manipulation of allocation rules. In Ref. [128], we demonstrated how
the Shapley value could be manipulated by players in cross-border
5.5. Incomplete information and manipulability of allocation rules transmission expansion projects. Unfortunately, it is not clear how to
prevent such manipulations. We believe that Algorithmic Mechanism
Another crucial assumption of CGT is that cooperation happens Design would be a promising extension to existing game-theoretic
under complete information: parameters of the power system and each models. The previously discussed model with an anticipating applica­
player are known to other players and the coordinating entity. In tion of CGT might also be useful in preventing data manipulations.
Ref. [47], Evans et al. used the Kernel for transmission expansion cost Many of the covered studies used rather simple models in simulating
allocation and mentioned that “the coalition creation in the Kernel re­ power systems and interactions among players. The reasoning lies in the
quires perfect information between the agents that will form the coali­ nature of cooperative games modeling: the models have to be solved
tion”. In reality, it may be hard to collect accurate information from multiple times for all possible coalitions, which increases the compu­
several independent participants. Moreover, players may have in­ tational burden. Therefore, a possible extension to existing studies could
centives to misreport their data and manipulate the allocation rule. be the complexification of game-theoretic models (for example, detailed
Evans et al. continued, “If that information is not perfect (information AC modeling of power systems, formulating stochastic optimization
asymmetry), the assignment will be biased. Information becomes a models), which may reveal additional insights.
competitive advantage within an environment of cooperation.” Summing up the section, we see that there exist several obstacles to
The idea that an allocation mechanism could be manipulated by CGT application in power systems. Most of the challenges are related to
players because of their personal interest has been formulated in the last game-theoretic assumptions that might not hold in practical cases.
century and thoroughly studied in Game Theory and economics. The Nonetheless, significant progress has been achieved in developing al­
concept of strategyproofness was introduced to describe games where a gorithms and mechanisms based on CGT solution concepts. We believe
dominant (optimal) strategy for every player is to reveal his private that future studies would overcome the mentioned obstacles and enable
information [122]. Several decision rules were proved to be strategy­ consistent application of CGT in power systems.
proof. For example, the majority voting system implies that players
submit their votes truthfully to select the desired decision among al­ 6. Conclusions
ternatives. There exists no strategy to manipulate the decision rule by
misreporting the players’ preferences. The system is, therefore, strat­ Power systems are facing new challenges that can no longer be
egyproof. Other examples of strategyproof mechanisms include the addressed by classical methods of centralized planning, operation and
second-price auction (Vickrey auction) and the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves control. Moreover, some of the challenges can be overcome only by
(VCG) mechanism [122]. Unfortunately, it was discovered that most means of cooperation. In this paper, we demonstrate that CGT concepts
of the allocation rules are not strategyproof: revealing private infor­ can be effectively used in cooperation mechanisms to solve the alloca­
mation is not a dominant strategy for every player in a cooperative tion problems that arise in power systems.
game. The notable contribution was made by Thomson [123–125], who The earliest applications of CGT in power systems concern expansion
investigated how unilateral misrepresentation of information affects the planning problems. We identify several original studies and perform a
allocation of value under different mechanisms. It was demonstrated citation network analysis of their citations to track the evolution of the
that if more than one player attempt to manipulate, the resulting research. Using the graph layout and modularity algorithms, we perform
cooperative game transforms into a manipulation game, whose out­ the spatial mapping of references and discover the research commu­
comes can be analyzed by calculating the equilibrium allocation solu­ nities. The related studies fall into three major research directions:
tions. Unfortunately, such manipulations not only affect the allocation multi-agent systems, expansion planning, CGT applications in power
of value among players but also degrade the overall efficiency of systems. We thoroughly examine the latter group of publications and
cooperation. This effect of players’ selfish behavior is often referred to as highlight the contributions of the communities. The identified CGT ap­
the price of anarchy or performance degradation. plications can be classified into essential and specific approaches. The
To better understand the interactions among players in a strategic essential approaches involve the straightforward modeling of player
environment and develop strategyproof mechanisms, the new fields of interactions in power markets and expansion planning projects. Such
study emerged at the intersection of Game Theory, economics, and models are typically used for cost and benefit allocation among partic­
computer science: Algorithmic Game Theory and Algorithmic Mecha­ ipants of cooperation. Specific approaches suggest unique ways of
nism Design. While the former area focuses on implementing existing cooperative game formulation and do not necessarily concern cost and
algorithms and analyzing game properties (equilibria solutions, the benefit allocation problems. Such formulations can be used to allocate
price of anarchy, best-response dynamics), the latter designs games with power losses and firm-energy rights, perform project ranking and sta­
desired game-theoretic and algorithmic properties. It is worth bility analysis. The citation network analysis performed allows to cap­
mentioning the contribution by Nisan [122,126], who studied algo­ ture the current progress of CGT applications in power systems.
rithms for self-interested participants and introduced the term Algo­ Moreover, we develop an interactive version of the network, which can
rithmic Mechanism Design. The essence of the designed mechanisms is be helpful in exploring particular applications and research
to ensure that a reasonable social choice would be achieved if all par­ communities.
ticipants (called agents) act rationally in a game-theoretic sense. The paper also contains the bibliometric analysis that shows growing

20
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

interests in the identified research directions. The most published au­ algorithms and mechanisms of cooperation based on CGT solution
thors, top journals in the field, and most popular keywords are identi­ concepts. The research communities involved form an independent
fied. Many authors praise the applicability of the CGT solution concepts. interdisciplinary direction. Even though the first related work appeared
It is reported in multiple studies that the implementation of the concepts more than forty years ago [29], the topic is not depleted yet. Moreover,
is intuitive, which makes them suitable for mechanisms of cooperation. the research evolves over time. On the one hand, the game-theoretic
Yet, there still exist challenges and limitations that prevent CGT appli­ models become more reasonable and complex, and case studies more
cations in real-world projects. Scalability issues of the CGT concepts do realistic than before. On the other hand, there are several ongoing works
not allow modeling cooperative games with a high number of players. on finding new approaches to using the CGT concepts in solving power
Several studies suggest using decomposition techniques to overcome the systems problems.
problem. However, further research is needed to model cooperative The overview presented in this paper and the citation network
games in realistic case studies. Another challenge is the nonconvexity of analysis performed can help scientists and engineers in comprehending
cooperative games. Arranging cooperation over nonconvex games could the CGT solution concepts, discovering novel applications for power
be a practical issue since solution concepts might fail to provide rational systems, and contributing to the state of the art of this promising
results. multidisciplinary research direction.
Moreover, existing works on CGT applications in power systems
exploit the solution concepts in an ex-post manner. Such an approach
does not allow to include additional expectations or requirements of Declaration of competing interest
players on their minimal share of benefits or levels of usefulness in the
coalition. In this regard, we suggest incorporating CGT principles into The authors declare that they have no known competing financial
planning and operation algorithms to obtain cooperative games with interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence
desired properties in an anticipating manner. Finally, we highlight the the work reported in this paper.
issues related to the incompleteness and manipulability of information.
There is a need for developing novel strategyproof mechanisms of Acknowledgments
cooperation that prevent data manipulation by players. We believe that
Algorithmic Mechanism Design would be a promising extension to This work was partially funded by the Skolkovo Institute of Science
existing game-theoretic models. and Technology (Skoltech) as a part of the Skoltech NGP Program
To conclude, we see that CGT has a strong potential to provide (Skoltech-MIT joint project). It was also partially funded by ANID/
reasonable solutions to existing issues of cooperation and allocation in FONDECYT-Regular/1190253 grant and by ANID/FONDAP-SERC-
power systems. Significant progress is achieved in developing Chile/15110019 grant.

Appendix A. Cooperative Game Theory: background and solution concepts

For the sake of completeness, we provide the mathematical background of CGT and introduce the most important solution concepts. We rely on the
above-mentioned papers on CGT applications and the book by Maschler et al. [11], which provides a comprehensive introduction to Game Theory.

Definition and properties of cooperative games

Consider a setting where several agents (players) agree on jointly performing a project to reach mutual benefits or savings. Before introducing
cooperative games, it is important to state what parameter we choose to describe the coalitions. There exist two approaches. If a value v(S) associated
with a coalition S represents some profit or gain that players obtain together, then a cooperative game is called a profit (or value) game. In profit
games, players achieve mutual benefits and allocate collective payoff. Conversely, if a value v(S) associated with a coalition S represents a cost that
players should pay together, then a cooperative game is called a cost game.6 In cost games, players achieve synergy in cost reduction and allocate the
total cost that their coalition must pay. In this work, we are interested in cost games, which is consistent with the aforementioned TEP models. Thus, in
the following definitions, we imply that the value of coalitions is formulated in terms of costs.7
If the outcome of cooperation can be expressed in monetary units and then allocated among the participants, the strategic interaction over the
project can be described by the following transferable utility game formulation.
Definition 1. A cooperative game with transferable utility specifies a cost for every possible coalition S by setting a pair (N; v) such that:

• N = {1, 2, …, n} is a finite set of players (agents who are potential users of the project). A subset of N is called a coalition. The largest possible
coalition containing all players is called the grand coalition. The collection of all the coalitions is denoted by 2N . A partition of the set of players, N,
is called a coalitional structure, B. It is a collection of disjoint and nonempty sets whose union is N.
• v : 2N →R is a function associating every coalition S with a real number v(S), satisfying v( ∅) = 0. This function is called the characteristic (also
coalitional or utility) function of the game.
The objective of the cooperative game formulation is to suggest a reasonable solution for allocating the cost of the grand coalition, v(N), among the
agents in N. It follows from Definition 1 that to analyze a cooperative game, it is necessary to consider all subsets of N (coalitions). That is, all possible
scenarios of cooperation should be modeled and included in the characteristic function. But what should we focus on when analyzing cooperative
games? To clarify this, we introduce several important properties of cooperative games that are useful for analyzing the merits and applicability of the

6
For the sake of consistency, values of coalitions in cost games can be noted as c(S) instead of v(S). However, in this work, we keep the common notation and use
v(S) to denote the costs of coalitions.
7
Note that value games can be translated to cost games and vice versa. Thus, all the concepts presented in this chapter can be applied to value games by
considering the values as negative costs.

21
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 13. Example of disjoint coalitions in a superadditive cooperative game.

Fig. 14. Example of intersecting coalitions in a convex cooperative game.

solution concepts.
Definition 2. A cooperative game (N; v) is called superadditive if for any pair of disjoint coalitions S and T holds:
v(S ∪ T) ≤ v(S) + v(T) (6)
Superadditivity implies that every two disjoint coalitions (S ∩ T = ∅) that choose to merge can obtain the same or lower cost they could get if
working separately. We visualize this property of cooperative games in Fig. 13. Coalitions S and T are represented by the two disjoint ellipses, which
signifies that they do not have any players or coalitions in common. The grand coalition is depicted by the large ellipse N. Equation (6) states that there
is some synergy of cooperation among S and T. Thus, the union S ∪ T can get an equal or lower cost than the two separate coalitions. Superadditivity is
a useful property that reveals a “positive pressure” to form the grand coalition N and serves as a justification for solution concepts implementation.
However, the superadditivity condition is not strong enough since it considers only disjoint coalitions. The following definition introduces the class
of convex games where similar restrictions hold for every pair of coalitions.
Definition 3. A cooperative game (N; v) is called convex if for every pair of coalitions S and T holds:
v(S ∪ T) + v(S ∩ T) ≤ v(S) + v(T) (7)
The above definition states that two coalitions that have some players in common should obtain together less or equal cost than the two separate
coalitions minus the cost of their intersection. We present an example of intersecting coalitions in Fig. 14. It follows that every convex game is
superadditive. Thus, the set of convex games is a subset of the superadditive games. We are interested in the convexity property since it characterizes
games where players have clear incentives for forming large coalitions. Note that in cost games, the property of superadditivity is sometimes referred
to as subadditivity, and convex games are called concave. However, we find it more common to use terms superadditive and convex for describing the
synergy properties of cooperation. The same terms are also used by Maschler et al. in Ref. [11].
Equation (7) may not always be convenient for verifying game convexity based on intersecting coalitions. Therefore, we present the following
equivalent formulation, which depends on players’ marginal contributions.
Definition 4. In a convex game, the following equivalent formulation of convexity holds for every S⊆T⊆N and every player i ∈ N\T:
v(S ∪ {i}) − v(S) ≥ v(T ∪ {i}) − v(T) (8)
The equivalent formulation considers cases where coalition S is a subset of T, as shown in Fig. 15. Equation (8) states that the game is convex if and
only if the marginal contribution of any fixed player i to coalition S increases as more players join the coalition. In our cost game formulation, the
contributions are the differences in costs before and after cooperation. Convex cooperative games have a “snowballing” effect where large coalitions
become more beneficial for players.
The mentioned properties are useful in analyzing the structure of cooperation. Moreover, they are used to classify special families of cooperative
games, such as market games, flows games [11], and justify the applicability of allocation solutions.
The main assumption in CGT solution concepts is that the grand coalition N will be formed. Numerous solution concepts have been developed to
allocate the cost, v(N), among its members in the most reasonable way. Before introducing the solution concepts, it is worth discussing their features
and desired properties. First, we distinguish single-valued (point) and set solution concepts:
Definition 5. A solution concept is called a single-valued (point) solution of a cooperative game (N; v) if it assigns a single vector, x(N; v), indicating
the amount each player receives.

22
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Fig. 15. Example of coalition subsets in a convex cooperative game.

Single-valued solution concepts provide unique answers to cost allocation problems, and, therefore, are of particular interest for practical ap­
plications. On the contrary, set solution concepts define a set of possible allocation solutions, which is useful for further analysis of cooperation. We
should also notice that there exist games with an empty vector of possible payoffs, x(N; v) = ∅. It is obvious, that in such cases, players will not agree
on forming the grand coalition.
Next, we define the desired properties of solution concepts. These properties impose the following restrictions on the vector x(N; v).
Definition 6. A vector x ∈ RN is called efficient for a cooperative game (N; v) if:

xi = v(N) (9)
i∈N

In words, the allocation exactly splits the total cost among the players. Players cannot divide more or less cost than they obtain in the grand
coalition.
Definition 7. A vector x ∈ RN is called individually rational if for every player i ∈ N:
xi ≤ v(i) (10)
This condition means that no player obtains a higher cost than what he could get on his own. In our analysis, we are interested in the set of possible
allocation solutions satisfying equations (9) and (10), which form the set of imputations.
Definition 8. Let (N; v) be a cooperative game, and let B be a coalitional structure, that is a partitioning of the set of players N. Then, the set of all
possible payoff vectors x ∈ RN that are efficient and individually rational for the coalitional structure B is called the set of imputations X(N; v).
Efficiency and individual rationality are essential properties that allow estimating the possibility of cooperation in a particular game. However,
they do not fully represent the rationality constraints imposed by the coalitional structure of a game. Therefore, we need to define the coalitional
rationality.
Definition 9. An imputation x ∈ X(N; v) is called coalitionally rational if for every coalition S⊆N:

xi ≤ v(S) (11)
i∈S

This definition states that every coalition has to be awarded less or equal cost in the grand coalition than it could get on its own. Coalitional
rationality is an essential property exploited in numerous solution concepts.

The Core

Having described the rationality properties of allocation solutions, we are now ready to define one of the main solution concepts in CGT, the Core of
the game.
Definition 10. The Core of a cooperative game C(N; v) is the collection of all coalitionally rational imputations.
Thus, the allocation solutions within the Core must satisfy conditions (9), (10), and (11). The Core is the intersection of a finite number of half-
spaces, which means that it is a convex compact set. Every solution within the Core satisfies all players. For this reason, the Core is often referred to as a
metric for evaluating the stability of cooperation. That is, a game with a large set of rational imputations can be considered more stable compared to a
game with fewer rational imputations. Moreover, the Core of a game (or its projections) can be easily visualized using the barycentric coordinate
system, as we demonstrate in Section 3.8 Such a visualization could indicate potential stability issues of cooperation. For example, if the Core is very
distant from certain players or is small enough compared to the set of imputations, this would alert about potential tendency against cooperation.
A logical question arises: in which cases the Core is not an empty set? In this paper, we omit the necessary and sufficient conditions for the
nonemptiness of the Core of a cooperative game (proved in the Bondareva–Shapley theorem). Instead, we introduce the following theorem that is of
particular interest for practical implementation.
Theorem 1. The Core of a convex game is nonempty.
As discussed earlier, in convex games, players have clear incentives to form large coalitions. Moreover, it is proved that convex cooperative games
have nonempty Core, which signifies that cooperation should be theoretically possible. However, only certain classes of games, such as market games,

8
Note that the barycentric coordinate system is usually used to visualize 3-player and 4-player cooperative games. Visualization of games with more players can
hardly be interpretable.

23
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

always have nonempty Core. Many real-world appications lead to nonconvex games, where it may not be possible to suggest an allocation that satisfies
all players. As we discuss in Section 5.2, nonconvexity is a major obstacle to the practical application of CGT solution concepts.
The Shapley value

The Shapley value is one of the two most important single-valued solution concepts for cooperative games. It assigns a unique vector x with several
desired solution properties based on players’ marginal contributions to possible coalitions. We have already discussed the efficiency and the ratio­
nality properties of allocation solutions. Before defining the Shapley value formula, it is useful to describe a few more desired properties of solution
concepts.
Definition 11. Players i and j are symmetric players in a cooperative game (N; v) if for every coalition S⊆N\{i, j}:
v(S ∪ {i}) = v(S ∪ {j}) (12)

Definition 12. A solution concept satisfies the symmetry property if for every cooperative game (N; v) and every pair of symmetric players i and j in
the game:
xi (N; v) − v(i) = xj (N; v) − v(j) (13)

Symmetry is an essential property that implies equal treatment for players who give the same marginal contribution to every coalition. This
property requires a solution concept to be independent of the names and order of the players.

Definition 13. A player i is called a null player in a game (N; v), if for every coalition S⊆N, it holds:
v(S) = v(S ∪ {j}) (14)

Definition 14. A solution concept satisfies the null player property if for every cooperative game (N; v) and every null player i in the game:
xi (N; v) = v({i}) (15)
A null player contributes nothing to a coalition he could join. Thus, the desired property of solution concepts is to allocate no benefits (cost savings)
to such players.
Finally, we are ready to define the Shapley value, which is the unique solution concept satisfying the efficiency, symmetry, and null player
properties. The explicit Shapley value formula is given by the following equation.
Definition 15. The Shapley value is the solution concept Sh defined as follows:
∑ |S|!(|N| − |S| − 1)!
Shi (N; v) = (v(S ∪ {i}) − v(S)) (16)
S⊆N\{i}
|N|!

The above equation is a linear function of the worths of the various coalitions, where |N| is the total number of players in a game, and |S| is the
number of players in coalition S, which is a subset of N. The number of different ways that the players in S can be ordered is |S|!, and the number of
different ways that the remaining players in N\(S ∪{i}) can be ordered is (|N| − |S| − 1)!. It follows that the number of permutations in the ordering of
joining the coalition S is |S|!(|N| − |S| − 1)!, and the number of all possible orderings in joining all possible coalitions in |N|!. Thus, the allocation xi to
player i is a weighted sum of its marginal contributions v(S ∪{i}) − v(S) to coalitions he could join.
The Shapley value is widely recognized as an effective concept for its axiomatic properties and the ability to capture players’ marginal contri­
butions. It is frequently used in economic studies not only for cost allocation but also for estimating the bargaining power of players. For example, the
Shapley value is used in the Shapley–Shubik power index [129] to measure the power of members in a decision-making process. Unfortunately, there
is no guarantee that the Shapley value would be within the Core of a game and, therefore, be a rational solution. Only certain cooperative games have
this property, as stated by the following theorem.
Theorem 2. If (N; v) is a convex game, then the Shapley value is in the Core of the game.
Once again, we see the merits of convex cooperative games. Not only they have the nonempty Core, but also it is guaranteed that the Shapley value
is a part of it. However, many practical cases of cooperation cannot be formulated as convex cooperative games. Therefore, the Shapley value should
be used with caution not to violate the rationality constraints.

The Aumann–Shapley value

Another drawback of the Shapley value formula (16) is the need to account for all possible permutations of players in coalitions. Due to its
combinatorial nature, the problem size grows exponentially with N, and the method becomes computationally infeasible for games with dozens of
players. In this regard, Aumann and Shapley [130] extended the concept of the Shapley value to infinite games. An assumption has been made that
players have a non-atomic nature. That is, every player can be divided into infinitesimal sub-players.9 Each infinitesimal sub-player can be considered
as an individual player. The idea behind the Aumann-Shapley value is to reflect the average marginal contributions to the coalition for all players,
making the problem insensitive to the order of entry.

9
Note that division of a player in this context can correspond to partitioning of its size, capacity, amount of service provided, etc. For example, in power systems, a
generator (player) can be represented by infinitesimal shares of its capacity (sub-players).

24
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

It might seem that breaking up players into sub-players should create even greater computational difficulties for the Aumann-Shapley approach.
However, it was demonstrated that the fact that players are split into infinitesimal parts allows the Aumann-Shapley value to have an analytical
expression. Suppose that C(b) is a cost function that depends on the vector of players’ resources, b. We can consider a fraction of the resources, λb,
where λ belongs to the interval [0,1]. Then, the cost allocated to each player, ASi , can be expressed as:
∫1
∂C(λb)
ASi = bi dλ (17)
∂bi
0

Equation (17) can be solved analytically or iteratively depending on the cost function. Note that if C(b) is obtained from an optimization problem,
then the Aumann-Shapley allocation becomes a parametric programming problem.
It follows that implementation of the Aumann-Shapley value highly depends on the case study and cooperative game formulation. We refer to
studies [52,53,58,59,103] that successfully adapted the Aumann-Shapley approach for power system allocation problems.

Coalitional excess theory: the Nucleolus and the Kernel

Several important solution concepts are based on the coalitional excess theory, which involves the following additional metric.
Definition 16. For every imputation x ∈ RN and every coalition S⊆N, the excess of the coalition is defined as:

e(S; x) : = v(S) − xi (18)
i∈S

For cost games, the excess is a measure of how satisfied a coalition is with the imputation x(N; v).10 The larger the excess of S, the more satisfied
coalition S is. The Nucleolus, a solution concept first introduced by Schmeidler [131], suggests searching for an allocation that maximizes the excess of
the most dissatisfied coalitions. To formally define the Nucleolus, we need to compose a vector, θ, that computes the excesses of all the coalitions at x
and arranges them in increasing order: θ(x) = (e(S1 ; x),e(S2 ; x),…,e(S2n ; x)), where e(S1 ; x) ≤ e(S2 ; x) ≤ … ≤ e(S2n ; x). This vector is needed to perform
a lexicographical comparison with other possible vectors of excesses. We say that vector a = (a1 , a2 , …, am ) is lexicographically greater than another
vector b = (b1 , b2 , …, bm ) if either a = b or there exists h ∈ {1, …, m} such that ah ≥ bh and ai = bi ∀i < h. We annotate this lexicographical comparison
as a≿b. Now we are ready to define the Nucleolus, the imputation x which lexicographically maximizes the excess vector, θ, for all possible impu­
tations x.11

Definition 17. Let (N; v) be a cooperative game and let K ∈ RN be a set of possible imputations. The Nucleolus of the game (N; v) relative to K is the
solution concept N defined as follows:
N (N; v; K) = {x ∈ K : θ(x)≿θ(x), ∀x ∈ K} (19)

To find the Nucleolus of a cooperative game, it is necessary to solve a series of linear programming models. We refer to the paper by Guajardo and
Jörnsten [132], who presented an algorithm for computing the Nucleolus and discussed common mistakes that appear in its applications. The first
linear program in the sequence maximizes the excess of the most dissatisfied coalition and can be formulated as follows.

max ε (20)
x


s.t. ε + xj ≤ v(S) ∀S⊂N, S ∕
=∅ (21)
j∈S


xj = v(N) (22)
j∈N

ε ∈ R, xj ∈ R, ∀j ∈ N (23)

The objective function (20) maximizes the value ε, which is constrained by the excesses of all possible coalitions in (21). Thus, (20) and (21)
together provide that ε is exactly equal to the minimum excess. Constraint (22) refers to the efficiency property (9). Constraint (23) states the nature of
the variables. The solution to (20)–(23) may not necessarily be unique. It may occur that more than one allocations x lead to the optimal objective
value. Moreover, formulation (20)–(23) provides an allocation that maximizes the lowest excess, but not necessarily the second or the subsequent
lower excesses. To find the unique solution, the Nucleolus, it is necessary to solve a series of k linear programs formulated as follows.
max εk (24)
x


s.t. εk + xj ≤ v(S) ∀S⊂N : S ∕
∈F k (25)
j∈S

10
Note that for value games, the formulation of excess (18) shows how dissatisfied the members of S are with the vector x. If the excess is positive, the members of S
are not satisfied with x, because they could form S together, obtain v(S), and then divide that sum in such a way that each member of S receives more than he receives
under x. In our work, we formulate cost games, for which excess of a coalition means the opposite.
11
For value games, the Nucleolus lexicographically minimizes the excess vector arranged in decreasing order.

25
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056


εi + xj = v(S) ∀ S ∈ Fi i ∈ {1, …, k − 1} (26)
j∈S


xj = v(N) (27)
j∈N

εk ∈ R, xj ∈ R, ∀j ∈ N (28)
th
Similarly to (20) and (21), the objective function (24) and constraints (25) provide that the minimum excess of the k program is maximized.
Constraints (26) consider the results obtained in the previous linear programs and state that the excess of coalitions in the set Fi must be equal to the
optimal objective value εi of ith program. The set F k then is the union of all the coalitions for which the excess has already been fixed in previous linear
programs of the sequence. Constraints (27) and (28) state conditions for the efficiency and nature of the variables, respectively. The model (24)–(28)
should be solved k times unless the unique allocation solution is obtained. The definition of Fi sets between the iterations can be done by means of dual
linear programming, as it was shown in Ref. [132]. The imputation vector at the last interaction is the unique single-valued solution N (N; v), the
Nucleolus of a cooperative game. The above procedure shows that the Nucleolus lexicographically maximizes the excess vector for all possible
imputations.
The Nucleolus solution concept is widely used for solving allocation issues, particularly bankruptcy problems. The merit of this concept lies in the
following properties.
Theorem 3. If the Core of a cooperative game (N; v) for the coalitional structure B is nonempty, then the Nucleolus for B is in the Core.
This remarkable property of the Nucleolus makes it a universal tool for solving allocation issues: whenever it is possible to prove that the Core of a
game is not empty, the Nucleolus can be used to find a solution within the Core. Moreover, the Nucleolus satisfies the efficiency, symmetry, and null
player properties.
Theorem 4. Let (N; v) be a cooperative game with coalitional structure B, and let i and j be symmetric players who are the members of the same
coalition in B. Then the Nucleolus satisfies the symmetry property:
N i (N; v; B) − v(i) = N j (N; v; B) − v(j) (29)

Theorem 5. Let i ∈ N be a null player in a cooperative game (N; v). Then the Nucleolus satisfies the null player property:
N i (N; v) = v(i) (30)

It may seem that the Nucleolus is the absolute best choice of the solution concept since it not only satisfies almost all of the desired properties that
the Shapley value does (efficiency, symmetry, null player) but also reduces the dissatisfaction of the most dissatisfied coalitions and guarantees the
stability of cooperation. However, the implementation of the Nucleolus is still open to criticism. The idea of allocating more savings to the most
dissatisfied coalition is questionable. The point is that more dissatisfied coalitions may have fewer players than the less dissatisfied ones. Thus, it may
be not fair to create an allocation mechanism that cares most about a few of the players. In this regard, the Nucleolus is classified as an egalitarian
concept, while the Shapley value considers the contribution of players and is, therefore, a utilitarian concept.
Lastly, we define the Kernel, the solution concept first introduced by Davis and Maschler [133]. The Kernel is based on a similar excess metric that is
called the maximum surplus of player i over player j.
Definition 18. For any cooperative game (N; v) and any distinct pair of players i, j ∈ N, i ∕
= j the maximum surplus of player i over player j with
respect to the imputation x(N; v) is defined by:
sij (x) := min e(S; x) where G ij : = {S | i ∈ S, j ∕
∈ S} (31)
S∈G ij

It is again important to note that we consider cost games. Thus, the maximum surplus sij (x) describes the minimal cost that player i can get without
cooperating with player j. In other words, this is the maximum amount player i can gain (or the minimum amount he may lose) if withdrawing from the
grand coalition without the consent of player j and joining a coalition that does not include j.
Because of its nature, the maximum surplus of player i over player j is often called a bilateral threat. Thus, if sij (x) is lower than sji (x), we can say
that player i outweighs player j. The idea of the Kernel is to equalize all bilateral threats and reach a multi-bilateral bargaining equilibrium.
Definition 19. The set of imputations X(N; v) that balances the maximum surpluses for each distinct pair of players is called the Kernel of the game
(N; v) and is defined by:
{ ⃒ }
K (N; v) : = x ∈ X(N; v) ⃒ sij (x) = sji (x) ∀ i, j ∈ N, i ∕
=j (32)

As follows from the definition, the Kernel is a set solution concept. Not only the Kernel interprets a bargaining process among players, it also has
some valuable properties. It is important to mention that the Kernel always contains the Nucleolus. Moreover, it was proven by Maschler et al. [134]
that for the class of convex games, the Kernel and the Nucleolus coincide.
Unfortunately, there is no straightforward way of computing the Kernel. For example, in Ref. [135], Meinhardt suggested an algorithm for
computing the Kernel through a series of linear programs based on the bisection property of the Kernel elements.

26
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

Other solution concepts

There exist multiple other CGT solution concepts such as the ε-Core [136,137], τ-value [138,139], etc. Each of these concepts has some useful
properties and merits, which can be exploited in solving power systems’ allocation problems. Note that some concepts beyond CGT can also solve the
allocation problems effectively. For example, solution concepts for bargaining games such as the Nash solution [140] and Kalai–Smorodinsky solution
[141] could be applied to cooperative games.
Below we introduce the concept of players’ propensity to disrupt introduced by Gately in Ref. [29]. We have already discussed this concept in Section
3 and applied it to the illustrative three-system case study. The propensity to disrupt is defined as follows.
Definition 18. Let (N; v) be a cooperative game, and let x(N; v) be the imputation. Then, the propensity of player i to disrupt the cooperation is
defined by:

υ(N\{i}) − =i xj
(33)
j∕
di (N; v; x) = ∀i, j ∈ N
υ({i}) − xi

The interpretation of this concept is highly intuitive. If a player does not receive any share of savings, its propensity to disrupt is infinite.
Contrariwise, a player who gets most of the savings could have zero or even negative propensity to disrupt the agreement. The initial formulation by
Gately included gains of cooperation. We modified the formulation to suit cost games and considered the difference between the cost of coalitions and
cost imputations of players. In an extreme case, if one player gets most of the savings, other players would receive more savings in a subcoalition rather
than in the grand coalition. Thus, the numerator of (33) would be a negative value. The player with most of the savings would have a negative
propensity to disrupt. Note that in a setting with superadditive games and coalitional rationality conditions, such extreme cases become infeasible. As
demonstrated in Section 3, by defining the upper bounds of players’ propensity to disrupt, it becomes possible to suggest a region of reasonable
allocation solutions and verify the stability of cooperation.
In this appendix, we covered the background of CGT and the main solution concepts. The presented list of concepts is by no means complete.
However, we limited ourselves to the Core, the Shapley value (and the Aumann-Shapley extension), the Nucleolus, and the Kernel since these concepts
found the wide application in power systems research.

Appendix B. Supplementary data

Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2021.111056.

References [15] Konstantelos I, Pudjianto D, Strbac G, De Decker J, Joseph P, Flament A, et al.


Integrated North Sea grids: the costs, the benefits and their distribution between
countries. Energy Pol 2017;101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.11.024.
[1] Gabriel SA, Conejo AJ, Fuller JD, Hobbs BF, Ruiz C. Complementarity modeling
[16] Gorenstein Dedecca J, Lumbreras S, Ramos A, Hakvoort RA, Herder PM.
in energy markets. Springer, Int Ser Oper Res Manag Sci 2013;180. https://doi.
Expansion planning of the North Sea offshore grid: simulation of integrated
org/10.1007/978-1-4419-6123-5.
governance constraints. Energy Econ 2018;72. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
[2] Contreras J, Klusch M, Krawczyk JB. Numerical solutions to nash-cournot
eneco.2018.04.037.
equilibria in coupled constraint electricity markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2004;
[17] Figueroa-Acevedo AL, Jahanbani Ardakani A, Nosair H, Venkatraman A,
19. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2003.820692.
McCalley JD, Bloom A, et al. Design and valuation of high-capacity HVDC
[3] Pozo D, Contreras J. Finding multiple Nash equilibria in pool-based markets: a
macrogrid transmission for the continental US. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2020.
stochastic EPEC approach. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2011;26. https://doi.org/
https://doi.org/10.1109/tpwrs.2020.2970865.
10.1109/TPWRS.2010.2098425.
[18] European network of transmission system operators for electricity ENTSO-E. e-
[4] Huppmann D, Siddiqui S. An exact solution method for binary equilibrium
Highway2050 project, https://www.entsoe.eu/outlooks/ehighways-2050/;
problems with compensation and the power market uplift problem. Eur J Oper
2020.
Res 2018;266. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2017.09.032.
[19] CIGRE. Global electricity network feasibility study. 2019.
[5] Sauma EE, Oren SS. Proactive planning and valuation of transmission
[20] Global energy interconnection development and cooperation organization
investments in restructured electricity markets. J Regul Econ 2006;30. https://
(GEIDCO). 2020. https://en.geidco.org/.
doi.org/10.1007/s11149-006-9003-y.
[21] UN. Sustainable development goals. https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopmen
[6] Pozo D, Sauma EE, Contreras J. A three-level static MILP model for generation
t/energy/; 2018.
and transmission expansion planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2013;28:202–10.
[22] Saad W, Han Z, Poor HV, Başar T. Game-theoretic methods for the smart grid: an
https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2012.2204073.
overview of microgrid systems, demand-side management, and smart grid
[7] Pozo D, Contreras J, Sauma E. If you build it, he will come: anticipative power
communications. IEEE Signal Process Mag 2012;29. https://doi.org/10.1109/
transmission planning. Energy Econ 2013;36. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
MSP.2012.2186410.
eneco.2012.12.007.
[23] Sorin E, Bobo L, Pinson P. Consensus-based approach to peer-to-peer electricity
[8] Huppmann D, Egerer J. National-strategic investment in European power
markets with product differentiation. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2019;34. https://
transmission capacity. Eur J Oper Res 2015;247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2018.2872880.
ejor.2015.05.056.
[24] Burger S, Chaves-Ávila JP, Batlle C, Pérez-Arriaga IJ. A review of the value of
[9] Taheri SS, Kazempour J, Seyedshenava S. Transmission expansion in an oligopoly
aggregators in electricity systems. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2017;77. https://
considering generation investment equilibrium. Energy Econ 2017;64. https://
doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2017.04.014.
doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2017.03.003.
[25] Parag Y, Sovacool BK. Electricity market design for the prosumer era. Nat Energy
[10] Kasina S, Hobbs BF. The value of cooperation in interregional transmission
2016;1. https://doi.org/10.1038/nenergy.2016.32.
planning: a noncooperative equilibrium model approach. Eur J Oper Res 2020;
[26] Acuña LG, Ríos DR, Arboleda CP, Ponzón EG. Cooperation model in the electricity
285. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2020.02.018.
energy market using bi-level optimization and Shapley value. Oper Res Perspect
[11] Maschler M, Solan E, Zamir S. Game theory. Cambridge University Press; 2013.
2018;5. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.orp.2018.07.003.
[12] Lumbreras S, Ramos A, Banez-Chicharro F. Optimal transmission network
[27] Long C, Zhou Y, Wu J. A game theoretic approach for peer to peer energy trading.
expansion planning in real-sized power systems with high renewable penetration.
Energy Procedia 2019;159. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.egypro.2018.12.075.
Elec Power Syst Res 2017;149:76–88. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
[28] Lo Prete C, Hobbs BF. A cooperative game theoretic analysis of incentives for
epsr.2017.04.020.
microgrids in regulated electricity markets. Appl Energy 2016;169. https://doi.
[13] Otsuki T, Mohd Isa AB, Samuelson RD. Electric power grid interconnections in
org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.01.099.
Northeast Asia: a quantitative analysis of opportunities and challenges. Energy
[29] Gately D. Sharing the gains from regional cooperation: a game theoretic
Pol 2016;89:311–29. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.11.021.
application to planning investment in electric power. Int Econ Rev 1974;15.
[14] Loureiro MV, Claro J, Fischbeck P. Coordinating cross-border electricity
[30] Tsukamoto Y, Iyoda I. Allocation of fixed transmission cost to wheeling
interconnection investments and trade in market coupled regions. Int J Electr
transactions by cooperative game theory. IEEE Trans Power Syst 1996;11.
Power Energy Syst 2019;104. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijepes.2018.07.003.
https://doi.org/10.1109/59.496131.

27
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

[31] Contreras J, Wu FF. Coalition formation in transmission expansion planning. IEEE [59] Banez-Chicharro F, Olmos L, Ramos A, Latorre JM. Estimating the benefits of
Trans Power Syst 1999;14. https://doi.org/10.1109/59.780946. transmission expansion projects: an Aumann-Shapley approach. Energy 2017;
[32] Zolezzi JM, Rudnick H. Transmission cost allocation by cooperative games and 118. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2016.10.135.
coalition formation. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2002;17. https://doi.org/10.1109/ [60] Sharma S, Abhyankar AR. Loss allocation of radial distribution system using
TPWRS.2002.804941. Shapley value: a sequential approach. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 2017;88.
[33] Hesamzadeh MR, Rosellón J, Vogelsang I. Transmission network investment in https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijepes.2016.11.015.
liberalized power markets. Springer International Publishing, Lecture notes in [61] Kirschen D, Strbac G. Fundamentals of power system economics. John Wiley &
energy book series, volume vol. 79; 2020. Sons; 2004. https://doi.org/10.1002/0470020598.
[34] Gil HA, Galiana FD, Conejo AJ. Multiarea transmission network cost allocation. [62] Bastian M, Heymann S, Jacomy M. Gephi: an open source software for exploring
IEEE Trans Power Syst 2005;20:1293–301. https://doi.org/10.1109/ and manipulating networks. Third Int AAAI Conf Weblogs Soc Media; 2009.
TPWRS.2005.851951. https://doi.org/10.1136/qshc.2004.010033.
[35] Lima DA, Padilha-Feltrin A, Contreras J. An overview on network cost allocation [63] Hobbs BF, Kelly KA. Using game theory to analyze electric transmission pricing
methods. Elec Power Syst Res 2009;79. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. policies in the United States. Eur J Oper Res 1992;56. https://doi.org/10.1016/
epsr.2008.10.005. 0377-2217(92)90219-Y.
[36] Sabolić D. On economic inefficiency of European Inter-TSO compensation [64] Chattopadhyay D. An energy brokerage system with emission trading and
mechanism. Energy Pol 2017;110:548–58. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. allocation of cost savings. IEEE Trans Power Syst 1995;10. https://doi.org/
enpol.2017.08.047. 10.1109/59.476061.
[37] Olmos L, Pérez-Arriaga IJ. Evaluation of three methods proposed for the [65] Jacomy M, Venturini T, Heymann S, Bastian M. ForceAtlas2, a continuous graph
computation of inter-TSO payments in the internal electricity market of the layout algorithm for handy network visualization designed for the Gephi
European Union. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2007;22. https://doi.org/10.1109/ software. PloS One 2014. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0098679.
TPWRS.2007.907118. [66] Hu Y. Efficient, high-quality force-directed graph drawing. Math J 2005;10.
[38] Delikaraoglou S, Pinson P. Optimal allocation of HVDC interconnections for [67] Blondel VD, Guillaume JL, Lambiotte R, Lefebvre E. Fast unfolding of
exchange of energy and reserve capacity services. Energy Syst 2019;10. https:// communities in large networks. J Stat Mech Theor Exp 2008;10. https://doi.org/
doi.org/10.1007/s12667-018-0288-6. 10.1088/1742-5468/2008/10/P10008.
[39] Baldursson FM, Lazarczyk E, Ovaere M, Proost S. Cross-border exchange and [68] McArthur SDJ, Davidson EM, Catterson VM, Dimeas AL, Hatziargyriou ND,
sharing of generation reserve capacity. Energy J 2018;39. https://doi.org/ Ponci F, et al. Multi-agent systems for power engineering applications - Part I:
10.5547/01956574.39.4.fbal. concepts, approaches, and technical challenges. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2007;22.
[40] Yang Z, Zhong H, Xia Q, Kang C, Chen T, Li Y. A structural transmission cost https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2007.908471.
allocation scheme based on capacity usage identification. IEEE Trans Power Syst [69] Latorre G, Darío Cruz R, Areiza JM, Villegas A. Classification of publications and
2016;31:2876–84. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2015.2464108. models on transmission expansion planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2003;18.
[41] Gerbaulet C, Weber A. When regulators do not agree: are merchant https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2003.811168.
interconnectors an option? Insights from an analysis of options for network [70] Bidram A, Davoudi A, Lewis FL, Guerrero JM. Distributed cooperative secondary
expansion in the Baltic Sea region. Energy Pol 2018;117. https://doi.org/ control of microgrids using feedback linearization. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2013;
10.1016/j.enpol.2018.02.016. 28. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2013.2247071.
[42] Tohidi Y, Hesamzadeh MR. Multi-regional transmission planning as a non- [71] Yazdanian M, Mehrizi-Sani A. Distributed control techniques in microgrids. IEEE
cooperative decision-making. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2014;29. https://doi.org/ Trans Smart Grid 2014;5. https://doi.org/10.1109/TSG.2014.2337838.
10.1109/TPWRS.2014.2312021. [72] Kumar Nunna HSVS, Doolla S. Multiagent-based distributed-energy-resource
[43] Buijs P, Belmans R. Transmission investments in a multilateral context. IEEE management for intelligent microgrids. IEEE Trans Ind Electron 2013;60. https://
Trans Power Syst 2012;27. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2011.2162593. doi.org/10.1109/TIE.2012.2193857.
[44] Contreras J. A cooperative game theory approach to transmission planning in [73] Logenthiran T, Srinivasan D, Khambadkone AM. Multi-agent system for energy
power systems. Univ. California at Berkeley; 1997. resource scheduling of integrated microgrids in a distributed system. Elec Power
[45] Contreras J, Wu FF. A kernel-oriented algorithm for transmission expansion Syst Res 2011;81. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.epsr.2010.07.019.
planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2000;15. https://doi.org/10.1109/59.898124. [74] Karavas CS, Arvanitis K, Papadakis G. A game theory approach to multi-agent
[46] Tan X, Lie TT. Application of the Shapley Value on transmission cost allocation in decentralized energy management of autonomous polygeneration microgrids.
the competitive power market environment. IEE Proc Generat Transm Distrib Energies 2017;10. https://doi.org/10.3390/en10111756.
2002;149:15–20. https://doi.org/10.1049/ip-gtd:20020005. [75] Cintuglu MH, Martin H, Mohammed OA. Real-time implementation of
[47] Evans F, Zolezzi JM, Rudnick H. Cost assignment model for electrical multiagent-based game theory reverse auction model for microgrid market
transmission system expansion: an approach through the kernel theory. IEEE operation. IEEE Trans Smart Grid 2015;6. https://doi.org/10.1109/
Trans Power Syst 2003;18. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2003.810903. TSG.2014.2387215.
[48] Stamtsis GC, Erlich I. Use of cooperative game theory in power system fixed-cost [76] Nagata T, Sasaki H. A multi-agent approach to power system restoration. IEEE
allocation. IEE Proc Generat Transm Distrib 2004;151:401–6. https://doi.org/ Trans Power Syst 2002;17. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2002.1007918.
10.1049/ip-gtd:20040156. [77] Tolbert LM, Qi H, Peng FZ. Scalable multi-agent system for real-time electric
[49] Ruiz PA, Contreras J. An effective transmission network expansion cost allocation power management. Proc. IEEE Power Eng. Soc. Transm. Distrib. Conf. 2001.
based on game theory. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2007;22:136–44. https://doi.org/ https://doi.org/10.1109/pess.2001.970327.
10.1109/TPWRS.2006.888987. [78] Ilic MD. From hierarchical to open access electric power systems. Proc IEEE 2007;
[50] Contreras J, Gross G, Arroyo JM, Muñoz JI. An incentive-based mechanism for 95. https://doi.org/10.1109/JPROC.2007.894711.
transmission asset investment. Decis Support Syst 2009;47. https://doi.org/ [79] Lee CW, Ng SKK, Zhong J, Wu FF. Transmission expansion planning from past to
10.1016/j.dss.2008.12.005. future. In: 2006 IEEE PES power syst. Conf. Expo. PSCE 2006 - proc.; 2006.
[51] Bhakar R, Sriram VS, Padhy NP, Gupta HO. Probabilistic game approaches for https://doi.org/10.1109/PSCE.2006.296317.
network cost allocation. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2010;25. https://doi.org/ [80] de la Torre S, Conejo AJ, Contreras J. Transmission expansion planning in
10.1109/TPWRS.2009.2032189. electricity markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2008;23. https://doi.org/10.1109/
[52] Junqueira M, da Costa LC, Barroso LA, Oliveira GC, Thomé LM, Pereira MV. An TPWRS.2007.913717.
Aumann-Shapley approach to allocate transmission service cost among network [81] Fang R, Hill DJ. A new strategy for transmission expansion in competitive
users in electricity markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2007;22:1532–46. https://doi. electricity markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2003;18. https://doi.org/10.1109/
org/10.1109/TPWRS.2007.907133. TPWRS.2002.807083.
[53] Molina YP, Saavedra OR, Amaris H. Transmission network cost allocation based [82] Zhang H, Vittal V, Heydt GT, Quintero J. A mixed-integer linear programming
on circuit theory and the Aumann-Shapley method. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2013; approach for multi-stage security-constrained transmission expansion planning.
28:4568–77. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2013.2278296. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2012;27. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2011.2178000.
[54] Kristiansen M, Muñoz FD, Oren S, Korpås M. A mechanism for allocating benefits [83] Maghouli P, Hosseini SH, Buygi MO, Shahidehpour M. A multi-objective
and costs from transmission interconnections under cooperation: a case study of framework for transmission expansion planning in deregulated environments.
the North Sea offshore grid. Energy J 2018;39:209–34. https://doi.org/10.5547/ IEEE Trans Power Syst 2009;24. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2009.2016499.
01956574.39.6.mkri. [84] Yu H, Chung CY, Wong KP, Zhang JH. A chance constrained transmission network
[55] de Moura GNP, Legey LFL, Howells M. A Brazilian perspective of power systems expansion planning method with consideration of load and wind farm
integration using OSeMOSYS SAMBA – South America Model Base – and the uncertainties. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2009;24. https://doi.org/10.1109/
bargaining power of neighbouring countries: a cooperative games approach. TPWRS.2009.2021202.
Energy Pol 2018;115. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2018.01.045. [85] Jabr RA. Robust transmission network expansion planning with uncertain
[56] Churkin A, Pozo D, Bialek J, Korgin N, Sauma E. Can cross-border transmission renewable generation and loads. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2013;28. https://doi.org/
expansion lead to fair and stable cooperation? Northeast Asia case analysis. 10.1109/TPWRS.2013.2267058.
Energy Econ 2019;84. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2019.104498. [86] Park H, Baldick R. Transmission planning under uncertainties of wind and load:
[57] Du Y, Wang Z, Liu G, Chen X, Yuan H, Wei Y, et al. A cooperative game approach sequential approximation approach. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2013;28. https://doi.
for coordinating multi-microgrid operation within distribution systems. Appl org/10.1109/TPWRS.2013.2251481.
Energy 2018;222. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2018.03.086. [87] Park H, Baldick R, Morton DP. A stochastic transmission planning model with
[58] Faria E, Barroso LA, Kelman R, Granville S, Pereira MV. Allocation of firm-energy dependent load and wind forecasts. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2015;31. https://doi.
rights among hydro plants: an Aumann-Shapley approach. IEEE Trans Power Syst org/10.1109/TPWRS.2014.2385861.
2009;24. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2009.2016376.

28
A. Churkin et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 145 (2021) 111056

[88] Majidi-Qadikolai M, Baldick R. Stochastic transmission capacity expansion [113] Lima DA, Contreras J, Padilha-Feltrin A. A cooperative game theory analysis for
planning with special scenario selection for integrating N-1 contingency analysis. transmission loss allocation. Elec Power Syst Res 2008;78. https://doi.org/
IEEE Trans Power Syst 2016;31. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2016.2523998. 10.1016/j.epsr.2007.02.008.
[89] Khodaei A, Shahidehpour M, Kamalinia S. Transmission switching in expansion [114] Dev Choudhury NB, Goswami SK. Transmission loss allocation using combined
planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2010;25. https://doi.org/10.1109/ game theory and artificial neural network. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 2012;
TPWRS.2009.2039946. 43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijepes.2012.05.017.
[90] Muñoz C, Sauma E, Contreras J, Aguado J, De La Torre S. Impact of high wind [115] Hasan KN, Saha TK, Chattopadhyay D, Eghbal M. Benefit-based expansion cost
power penetration on transmission network expansion planning. IET Gener, allocation for large scale remote renewable power integration into the Australian
Transm Distrib 2012;6. https://doi.org/10.1049/iet-gtd.2011.0552. grid. Appl Energy 2014;113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2013.08.031.
[91] Khodaei A, Shahidehpour M, Wu L, Li Z. Coordination of short-term operation [116] Hasan KN, Preece R, Milanović J. Application of game theoretic approaches for
constraints in multi-area expansion planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2012;27. identification of critical parameters affecting power system small-disturbance
https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2012.2192507. stability. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 2018;97. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
[92] Pozo D, Sauma E, Contreras J. Basic theoretical foundations and insights on ijepes.2017.11.027.
bilevel models and their applications to power systems. Ann Oper Res 2017;254. [117] An B, Shen Z, Miao C, Cheng D. Algorithms for transitive dependence-based
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2453-z. coalition formation. IEEE Trans Ind Informatics 2007;3. https://doi.org/10.1109/
[93] Aguado JA, De La Torre S, Contreras J, Conejo AJ, Martínez A. Market-driven TII.2007.902255.
dynamic transmission expansion planning. Elec Power Syst Res 2012;2. https:// [118] Zhang G, Jiang J, Su Z, Qi M, Fang H. Searching for overlapping coalitions in
doi.org/10.1016/j.epsr.2011.09.001. multiple virtual organizations. Inf Sci 2010;180. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
[94] Kamyab GR, Fotuhi-Firuzabad M, Rashidinejad M. A PSO based approach for ins.2010.04.028.
multi-stage transmission expansion planning in electricity markets. Int J Electr [119] Fruchterman TMJ, Reingold EM. Graph drawing by force-directed placement.
Power Energy Syst 2014;54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijepes.2013.06.027. Software Pract Ex 1991;21. https://doi.org/10.1002/spe.4380211102.
[95] Fiestras-Janeiro MG, García-Jurado I, Mosquera MA. Cooperative games and cost [120] Freire L, Street A, Lima DA, Barroso LA. A hybrid MILP and Benders
allocation problems. Top 2011;19. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11750-011-0200-1. decomposition approach to find the nucleolus quota allocation for a renewable
[96] Dabbagh SR, Sheikh-El-Eslami MK. Risk-based profit allocation to DERs energy portfolio. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2015;30. https://doi.org/10.1109/
integrated with a virtual power plant using cooperative Game theory. Elec Power TPWRS.2014.2374532.
Syst Res 2015;121. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.epsr.2014.11.025. [121] Boyd S, Parikh N, Chu E, Peleato B, Eckstein J. Distributed optimization and
[97] Rao MSS, Soman SA, Chitkara P, Gajbhiye RK, Hemachandra N, Menezes BL. Min- statistical learning via the alternating direction method of multipliers. Found
max fair power flow tracing for transmission system usage cost allocation: a large Trends Mach Learn 2011;3.
system perspective. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2010;25. https://doi.org/10.1109/ [122] Nisan N, Roughgarden T, Tardos É, Vazirani VV. Algorithmic game theory.
TPWRS.2010.2040638. Cambridge University Press; 2007. https://doi.org/10.1017/
[98] Csercsik D. Competition and cooperation in a bidding model of electrical energy CBO9780511800481.
trade. Network Spatial Econ 2016;16. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-015- [123] Thomson W. The manipulability of resource allocation mechanisms. Rev Econ
9310-x. Stud 1984;51.
[99] Molina YP, Prada RB, Saavedra OR. Complex losses allocation to generators and [124] Thomson W. The manipulability of the Shapley-value. Int J Game Theor 1988;17.
loads based on circuit theory and aumann-shapley method. IEEE Trans Power https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01254542.
Syst 2010;25. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2010.2044425. [125] Velez RA, Thomson W. Let them cheat! Game Econ Behav 2012;75. https://doi.
[100] Srinivasan D, Trung LT, Singh C. Bidding and cooperation strategies for electricity org/10.1016/j.geb.2012.01.001.
buyers in power markets. IEEE Syst J 2016;10. https://doi.org/10.1109/ [126] Nisan N, Ronen A. Algorithmic mechanism design. Game Econ Behav 2001;35.
JSYST.2014.2329314. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1999.0790.
[101] Petrosyan L, Sedakov A. Two-level cooperation in network games. Lect Notes Inst [127] Grosu D, Chronopoulos AT. Algorithmic mechanism design for load balancing in
Comput Sci Soc Telecommun Eng LNICST 2019;277. https://doi.org/10.1007/ distributed systems. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern B Cybern 2004;34. https://doi.
978-3-030-16989-3_5. org/10.1109/TSMCB.2002.805812.
[102] Kristiansen M, Korpås M, Svendsen HG. A generic framework for power system [128] Churkin A, Pozo D, Bialek J, Korgin N, Sauma E. Manipulability of cost and
flexibility analysis using cooperative game theory. Appl Energy 2018;212. benefit allocation in cross-border electrical interconnection projects. IEEE PES
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2017.12.062. PowerTech conf 2019. https://doi.org/10.1109/ptc.2019.8810685.
[103] Banez-Chicharro F, Olmos L, Ramos A, Latorre JM. Beneficiaries of transmission [129] Shapley LS, Shubik M. A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a
expansion projects of an expansion plan: an Aumann-Shapley approach. Appl committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 1954;48. https://doi.org/10.2307/1951053.
Energy 2017;195. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2017.03.061. [130] Aumann RJ, Shapley LS. Values of non-atomic games. Princeton University Press;
[104] Haring TW, Mathieu JL, Andersson G. Comparing centralized and decentralized 1974.
contract design enabling direct load control for reserves. IEEE Trans Power Syst [131] Schmeidler D. The nucleolus of a characteristic function game. SIAM J Appl Math
2016;31. https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2015.2458302. 1969;17. https://doi.org/10.1137/0117107.
[105] Hu Z, Chen L, Gan D, Chattopadhyay D. Allocation of unit start-up costs using [132] Guajardo M, Jörnsten K. Common mistakes in computing the nucleolus. Eur J
cooperative game theory. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2006;21. https://doi.org/ Oper Res 2015;241:931–5. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2014.10.037.
10.1109/TPWRS.2006.873046. [133] Davis M, Maschler M. The kernel of a cooperative game. Nav Res Logist Q 1965;
[106] Xie J, Wei X, Lu Y, Gan D. Emission-constrained optimal generation scheduling 12. https://doi.org/10.1002/nav.3800120303.
incorporating equity principles. IET Gener, Transm Distrib 2010;4. https://doi. [134] Maschler M, Peleg B, Shapley LS. The kernel and bargaining set for convex games.
org/10.1049/iet-gtd.2008.0576. Int J Game Theor 1971;1. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01753435.
[107] Voropai NI, Ivanova EY. Shapley game for expansion planning of generating [135] Meinhardt H. An LP approach to compute the pre-kernel for cooperative games.
companies at many non-coincident criteria. IEEE Trans Power Syst 2006;21. Comput Oper Res 2006;33. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cor.2004.06.020.
https://doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2006.873053. [136] Shapley LS, Shubik M. Quasi-cores in a monetary economy with nonconvex
[108] Marangon Lima JW, De Oliveira EJ. The long-term impact of transmission pricing. preferences. Econometrica 1966;34. https://doi.org/10.2307/1910101.
IEEE Trans Power Syst 1998;13. https://doi.org/10.1109/59.736299. [137] Maschler M, Peleg B, Shapley LS. Geometric properties of the kernel, nucleolus,
[109] Christie RD, Wollenberg BF, Wangensteen I. Transmission management in the and related solution concepts. Math Oper Res 1979;4. https://doi.org/10.1287/
deregulated environment. Proc IEEE 2000;88. https://doi.org/10.1109/ moor.4.4.303.
5.823997. [138] Tijs SH. An axiomatization of the τ-value. Math Soc Sci 1987;13. https://doi.org/
[110] Olmos L, Pérez-Arriaga IJ. A comprehensive approach for computation and 10.1016/0165-4896(87)90054-0.
implementation of efficient electricity transmission network charges. Energy Pol [139] Calvo E, Tijs SH, Valenciano F, Zarzuelo JM. On the axiomatization of the τ-value.
2009;37. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.07.051. Top 1995;3. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02574802.
[111] Rodríguez Ortega MP, Pérez-Arriaga JI, Abbad JR, González JP. Distribution [140] Nash JF. The bargaining problem. Econometrica 1950;18. https://doi.org/
network tariffs: a closed question? Energy Pol 2008;36. https://doi.org/10.1016/ 10.2307/1907266.
j.enpol.2008.01.025. [141] Kalai E, Smorodinsky M. Other solutions to Nash’s bargaining problem.
[112] Grimm V, Rückel B, Sölch C, Zöttl G. Regionally differentiated network fees to Econometrica 1975;43. https://doi.org/10.2307/1914280.
affect incentives for generation investment. Energy 2019;177. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.energy.2019.04.035.

29

You might also like