You are on page 1of 67

Principles of Microeconomics: A

Streamlined Approach, 4e ISE - eBook


PDF
Visit to download the full and correct content document:
https://ebooksecure.com/download/principles-of-microeconomics-a-streamlined-appro
ach-4e-ise-ebook-pdf/
This International Student Edition is for use outside of the U.S.

fourth edition

Principles of
Microeconomics
A Streamlined Approach

Frank
Bernanke
Antonovics
Heffetz
FOURTH EDITION

Principles of
MICROECONOMICS
A STREAMLINED APPROACH
THE McGRAW HILL SERIES IN ECONOMICS
SURVEY OF ECONOMICS Samuelson and Nordhaus Frank
Economics, Microeconomics, and Microeconomics and Behavior
Brue, McConnell, and Flynn
Macroeconomics Tenth Edition
Essentials of Economics
Nineteenth Edition
Fourth Edition ADVANCED ECONOMICS
Schiller and Gebhardt
Guell Romer
The Economy Today, The Micro
Issues in Economics Today Advanced Macroeconomics
Economy Today, and
Ninth Edition Fifth Edition
The Macro Economy Today
Mandel Sixteenth Edition MONEY AND BANKING
M: Economics, The Basics Slavin Cecchetti and Schoenholtz
Fourth Edition Economics, Microeconomics, and Money, Banking, and Financial
Macroeconomics Markets
Schiller and Gebhardt
Twelfth Edition Sixth Edition
Essentials of Economics
Eleventh Edition ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL ISSUES URBAN ECONOMICS
PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Guell O’Sullivan
Issues in Economics Today Urban Economics
Asarta and Butters Ninth Edition Ninth Edition
Connect Master Principles of
Economics Register and Grimes LABOR ECONOMICS
Economics of Social Issues
Colander Borjas
Twenty-First Edition
Economics, Microeconomics, and Labor Economics
Macroeconomics DATA ANALYTICS FOR Eighth Edition
Eleventh Edition ECONOMICS McConnell, Brue, and Macpherson
Prince Contemporary Labor Economics
Frank, Bernanke, Antonovics, Predictive Analytics for Business Twelfth Edition
and Heffetz Strategy
Principles of Economics, Principles of PUBLIC FINANCE
First Edition
Microeconomics, Principles of Rosen and Gayer
Macroeconomics MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS Public Finance
Eighth Edition Baye and Prince Tenth Edition
Frank, Bernanke, Antonovics, Managerial Economics and
ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS
and Heffetz Business Strategy
Tenth Edition Field and Field
A Streamlined Approach for:
Environmental Economics: An
Principles of Economics, Principles of Brickley, Smith, and
Introduction
Microeconomics, and Principles of Zimmerman
Eighth Edition
Macroeconomics Managerial Economics and
Fourth Edition Organizational INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS
Architecture Appleyard and Field
Karlan and Morduch
Seventh Edition International Economics
Economics, Microeconomics, and
Macroeconomics Thomas and Maurice Ninth Edition
Third Edition Managerial Economics Pugel
Thirteenth Edition International Economics
McConnell, Brue, and Flynn
Economics, Microeconomics, and INTERMEDIATE ECONOMICS Seventeenth Edition
Macroeconomics Bernheim and Whinston
Twenty-Second Edition Microeconomics
McConnell, Brue, and Flynn Second Edition
Brief Editions: Microeconomics and Dornbusch, Fischer, and Startz
Macroeconomics Macroeconomics
Third Edition Thirteenth Edition
FOURTH EDITION

Principles of
MICROECONOMICS
A STREAMLINED APPROACH
ROBERT H. FRANK
Cornell University

BEN S. BERNANKE
Brookings Institution [affiliated]
Former Chair, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

KATE ANTONOVICS
University of California, San Diego

ORI HEFFETZ
Cornell University and Hebrew University of Jerusalem
PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS: A STREAMLINED APPROACH
Published by McGraw Hill LLC, 1325 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10121. Copyright ©2022
by McGraw Hill LLC. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this
publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or
retrieval system, without the prior written consent of McGraw Hill LLC, including, but not limited to,
in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or broadcast for distance learning.
Some ancillaries, including electronic and print components, may not be available to customers outside
the United States.
This book is printed on acid-free paper.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 LWI 26 25 24 23 22 21
ISBN 978-1-264-37060-3
MHID 1-264-37060-1
Cover Image: Miroslava Hlavacova/Shutterstock

All credits appearing on page or at the end of the book are considered to be an extension of the
copyright page.
The Internet addresses listed in the text were accurate at the time of publication. The inclusion of a
­website does not indicate an endorsement by the authors or McGraw Hill LLC, and McGraw Hill
LLC does not guarantee the accuracy of the information presented at these sites.

mheducation.com/highered
D E D I C AT I O N

For Ellen
R. H. F.

For Anna
B. S. B.

For Fiona and Henry


K. A.

For Katrina, Eleanor, Daniel, and Amalia


O. H.
A BOUT THE AUTHOR S

ROBERT H. FRANK BEN S. BERNANKE


Robert H. Frank is the H. J. Professor Bernanke received
Louis Professor of Management his B.A. in economics from
and Professor of ­Economics, Harvard University in 1975
emeritus, at Cornell’s Johnson and his Ph.D. in economics
School of Management, where from MIT in 1979. He taught at
he taught from 1972 to 2020. the Stanford Graduate School
After receiving his B.S. from of Business from 1979 to 1985
Georgia Tech in 1966, he and moved to Princeton Uni-
taught math and science for versity in 1985, where he was
©Robert H. Frank
two years as a Peace Corps Vol- ©Ben S. Bernanke named the Howard Harrison
unteer in rural Nepal. He re- and ­Gabrielle Snyder Beck Pro-
ceived his M.A. in statistics in 1971 and his Ph.D. in fessor of Economics and Public Affairs and where he served
economics in 1972 from The University of ­California at as chair of the Economics Department. Professor Bernanke
Berkeley. He also holds honorary doctorate degrees from is currently a Distinguished Fellow in Residence with the
the University of St. Gallen and ­Dalhousie University. Dur- Economic Studies Program at the Brookings Institution.
ing leaves of absence from ­Cornell, he has served as chief Professor Bernanke was sworn in on February 1, 2006, as
economist for the Civil Aeronautics Board (1978–1980), a chair and a member of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Fellow at the Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Reserve System—his second term expired January 31, 2014.
Sciences (1992–1993), Professor of American Civilization at Professor Bernanke also served as chair of the Federal Open
l’École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales in Paris Market Committee, the Fed’s principal monetary policymaking
(2000–2001), and the Peter and Charlotte Schoenfeld Visit- body. Professor Bernanke was also chair of the President’s
ing Faculty Fellow at the NYU Stern School of Business in Council of Economic Advisers from June 2005 to January 2006.
2008–2009. His papers have appeared in the American Professor Bernanke’s intermediate textbook, with ­Andrew
­Economic Review, Econometrica, the Journal of Political Econ- Abel and Dean Croushore, Macroeconomics, Ninth Edition
omy, and other leading professional journals, and for more ­(Addison-Wesley, 2017), is a best seller in its field. He has
than two decades, his economics columns appeared regu- ­authored numerous scholarly publications in macroeconomics,
larly in The New York Times. macroeconomic history, and finance. He has done significant
Professor Frank is the author of a best-selling intermedi- research on the causes of the Great Depression, the role of
ate economics textbook Microeconomics and Behavior, Tenth ­financial markets and institutions in the business cycle, and
Edition (McGraw Hill, 2021). His research has focused on ri- measurement of the effects of monetary policy on the economy.
valry and cooperation in economic and social behavior. His Professor Bernanke has held a Guggenheim Fellowship
books on these themes include Choosing the Right Pond and a Sloan Fellowship, and he is a Fellow of the Economet-
­(Oxford, 1985), Passions Within Reason (W. W. Norton, 1988), ric Society and of the American Academy of Arts and Sci-
What Price the Moral High Ground? (Princeton, 2004), Falling ences. He served as director of the Monetary Economics
Behind (University of California Press, 2007), The Economic Program of the National Bureau of Economic Research
Naturalist (Basic Books, 2007), The Economic Naturalist’s Field (NBER) and as a member of the NBER’s Business Cycle Dat-
Guide (Basic Books, 2009), The Darwin Economy (Princeton, ing Committee. From 2001 to 2004 he served as editor of
2011), Success and Luck (Princeton, 2016), and Under the Influ- the American Economic Review, and served as the president
ence (Princeton, 2020), which have been translated into 24 of the American Economic Association in 2019. Professor
languages. The Winner-Take-All Society (The Free Press, 1995), ­Bernanke’s work with civic and professional groups
co-authored with Philip Cook, received a Critic’s Choice ­includes having served two terms as a member of the
Award, was named a Notable Book of the Year by The New ­Montgomery Township (N.J.) Board of Education.
York Times, and was included in BusinessWeek’s list of the 10
best books of 1995. Luxury Fever (The Free Press, 1999) was KATE ANTONOVICS
named to the Knight-Ridder Best Books list for 1999.
Professor Frank is a co-recipient of the 2004 Leontief Professor Antonovics received
Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought. He her B.A. from Brown University
was awarded the Johnson School’s Stephen Russell Distin- in 1993 and her Ph.D. in eco-
guished Teaching Award in 2004, 2010, 2012, and 2018, and nomics from the University of
the School’s Apple Distinguished Teaching Award in 2005. Wisconsin in 2000. Shortly
His introductory microeconomics course has graduated thereafter, she joined the faculty
more than 7,000 enthusiastic economic naturalists over the in the Economics Department at
years. the University of California, San
©Kate Antonovics
vi
PR EFAC E

Diego. Professor Antonovics is also currently serving as the A LESS IS MORE FOCUS
Provost of UC San Diego’s Seventh College.
Professor Antonovics is known for her excellence in
Our fourth streamlined edition arrives in the midst of
teaching and her innovative use of technology in the class- some of the most dramatic upheavals ever witnessed,
room. Her popular introductory-level microeconomics courses both in the economy generally and in higher educa-
have regularly enrolled over 900 students each fall. She also tion in particular. The COVID-19 pandemic has pro-
teaches labor economics at both the undergraduate and gradu- duced levels of unemployment not seen since the
ate level. She has received numerous teaching awards, includ- Great Depression and has created dramatic changes
ing the UCSD Department of Economics award for Best in the ways we teach across educational institutions at
Undergraduate Teaching, the UCSD Academic Senate Distin- every level.
guished Teaching Award, and the UCSD Chancellor’s Associ- These developments have reinforced our confi-
ates Faculty Excellence Award in Undergraduate Teaching. dence in the instructional philosophy that motivated
Professor Antonovics’s research has focused on racial
us to produce our first edition—the need to strip away
discrimination, gender discrimination, affirmative action,
intergenerational income mobility, learning, and wage dy-
clutter and focus more intensively on central con-
namics. Her papers have appeared in the American Economic cepts. This approach, we believe, is especially well
Review, the Review of Economics and Statistics, the Journal of suited for the new environment.
Labor Economics, and the Journal of Human Resources. She is In earlier editions, we noted that although many
a member of both the American Economic Association and millions of dollars are spent each year on introductory
the Society of Labor Economists. economics instruction in American colleges and uni-
versities, the return on this investment has been dis-
ORI HEFFETZ turbingly low. Studies have shown, for example, that
several months after having taken a principles of eco-
Professor Heffetz received his
B.A. in physics and philosophy nomics course, former students are no better able to
from Tel Aviv University in answer simple economics questions than others who
1999 and his Ph.D. in econom- never even took the course. Most students, it seems,
ics from Princeton University leave our introductory courses without having learned
in 2005. He is an Associate even the most important basic economic principles.
Professor of Economics at the Such dismal performance, never defensible, has be-
Samuel Curtis Johnson Gradu- come even more difficult to justify in the face of loom-
ate School of Management at ing resource shortages in higher education.
©Ori Heffetz
Cornell University, and at the The problem, in our view, has almost always been
Economics Department at the
that courses try to teach students far too much. In the
Hebrew University of ­Jerusalem.
process, really important ideas get little more coverage
Bringing the real world into the classroom, Professor
Heffetz has created a unique macroeconomics course that than minor ones, and everything ends up going by in
introduces basic concepts and tools from economic theory a blur. The human brain tends to ignore new informa-
and applies them to current news and global events. His tion unless it comes up repeatedly. That’s hardly sur-
popular classes are taken by hundreds of students every prising, since only a tiny fraction of the terabytes of
year on Cornell’s Ithaca and New York City campuses and information that bombard us each day is likely to be
via live videoconferencing in dozens of cities across the relevant for anything we care about. Only when some-
United States, Canada, and Latin America. thing comes up a third or fourth time does the brain
Professor Heffetz’s research studies the social and cul- start laying down new circuits for dealing with it. Yet
tural aspects of economic behavior, focusing on the mecha- when planning their lectures, many instructors ask
nisms that drive consumers’ choices and on the links between
themselves, “How much can I cover today?” And be-
economic choices, individual well-being, and policymaking.
cause modern electronic media enable them to click
He has published scholarly work on household consumption
patterns, individual economic decision making, and survey through upwards of 100 PowerPoint slides in an hour,
methodology and measurement. He was a visiting researcher they feel they better serve their students when they
at the Bank of Israel during 2011, is currently a Research As- put more information before them. But that’s not the
sociate at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), way learning works! Professors should instead be ask-
and serves on the editorial board of Social Choice and Welfare. ing, “How much can my students absorb?”

vii
viii PREFACE

Our approach to this text was inspired by our con- approach increases both student satisfaction and student
viction that students will learn far more if we attempt to learning.
cover much less. Our basic premise is that a small num- A second adaptation, more pronounced in the wake
ber of basic ideas do most of the heavy lifting in econom- of the COVID-19 lockdowns of March 2020, has been the
ics, and that if we focus narrowly and repeatedly on move to remote instruction. The streamlined approach
those ideas, illustrating and applying them in numerous of this text is well suited for the goals of both the flipped-
familiar contexts, students can actually master them in classroom and remote-instruction models. Rather than
just a single semester. The enthusiastic reactions of users trying to bombard students with information they can
of previous editions of our textbook affirm the validity of easily access online, our book seeks to promote a deeper
this premise. Our emphasis throughout is on active understanding of economics by focusing on core con-
learning. We ask students to apply basic economic ideas cepts. In addition, one of our central goals has been to
themselves to answer related questions, exercises, and create resources to help instructors promote student en-
problems. gagement outside the classroom. Some instructors may
find these resources useful in completely overhauling the
way they teach, while others may be interested in using
ADAPTING TO CLASSROOM TRENDS them to make a few minor changes to their current
Baumol’s cost disease refers to the tendency for costs to courses.
rise more rapidly for goods and services for which In other words, this edition is intended to support a
growth in labor productivity is either slow or nonexis- variety of teaching styles (and, indeed, our team of au-
tent. It is thus no surprise that the cost of traditional thors varies considerably in our pedagogical approach).
methods of delivering classroom instruction has been The traditional approach has been to ask students to
rising so much faster than the cost of producing most read the relevant sections from the textbook before com-
manufactured goods. ing to class. But instructors report that today’s students
Largely as a result of Baumol’s cost disease, tuition are far less likely than their predecessors to complete
increases have far exceeded even the rapid growth in the such assignments. Stronger incentives can boost compli-
cost of health care. This is what we would expect if the ance. One effective approach assigns SmartBook chap-
dominant teaching model remains as it was a century ters with adaptive questioning built in. Another
ago, in which a learned instructor stands in front of a administers brief tests at the start of class. These might
class reciting truths cataloged in an assigned text. But as involve two or three simple multiple-choice questions on
the late Herb Stein once remarked, “If something cannot the assigned material that are administered and graded
go on forever, it will stop.” And so it is with rising tu- electronically via audience response tools using smart-
itions. Universities are already facing strong pressure to phone apps.
moderate their rates of tuition growth, pressure that has Perhaps the biggest hurdle to effective implementa-
been greatly exacerbated by the COVID-19 pandemic. tion of the new teaching approaches has been a dearth of
One result has been that much of the content that effective pre-class concept-delivery materials. To help fill
professors have traditionally delivered in live lecture will this gap, we have created a library of short videos that
instead be delivered electronically. Indeed, technological focus on basic economic concepts. Many students have
advances have given today’s students an unparalleled found these videos and animations engaging enough to
ability to access information via the Internet, YouTube, watch even if they’re not going to be tested on them, but
and social media. we’ve also provided easily administered in-class ques-
If early experience is any indication, the “flipped- tions that can boost compliance still further.
classroom” model is one of the most promising adapta- A big payoff in both the flipped-classroom and
tions to this new environment. In this approach, students ­remote-instruction models comes from being able to use
are expected to study basic concepts before coming to limited class time to discuss the concepts that students
class and then deepen their understanding of them have studied before class. One approach begins by ask-
through structured classroom exercises and discussion. ing students to answer a multiple-choice question requir-
The logic of the flipped classroom is compelling because ing application of a concept, and then reporting the
under this approach, students have access to instructors frequencies with which students selected the various
precisely when students are engaged in those activities multiple-choice options. Students are then given a few
that students find the most challenging (for example, moments to discuss the question—either with their
problem solving and policy evaluation). Indeed, numer- neighbors in traditional classroom settings, or with fel-
ous studies have found that the flipped-classroom low students in Zoom breakout rooms—before having an
PREFACE ix

opportunity to change the answers they originally sub- ● Test Bank Assessment: Hundreds of multiple-choice
mitted. Professors then call on students who’ve offered questions are available for summative assessments
both correct and incorrect answers to the question to de- of the chapter content. Select problems are now of-
fend their answers to the class and lead the ensuing dis- fered as an algorithmic alternative, providing even
cussion. We’ve spent considerable effort drafting the more variation.
kinds of questions that reliably provoke animated discus-
All of the above assets can be implemented by in-
sions of this sort.
structors as preferred in order to satisfy as much or as
In summary, here are the resources we have devel-
little of the flipped-classroom approach as is desired.
oped to support the flipped-classroom and remote-­
instruction approaches, all available within McGraw Hill
Connect® specific to the fourth edition: KEY THEMES AND FEATURES

Before Class (Exposure) Economic Naturalism


● SmartBook Adaptive Reading Assignments:
® Relying on examples drawn from familiar contexts, we en-
SmartBook contains the same content as the print courage students to become “economic naturalists,” people
book, but actively tailors that content to the needs of who employ basic economic principles to understand and
the individual through adaptive probing and inte- explain what they observe in the world around them. An
grated learning resources. Instructions can assign economic naturalist understands, for example, that infant
SmartBook reading assignments for points to create safety seats are required in cars but not in airplanes because
incentives for students to come to class prepared. the marginal cost of space to accommodate these seats is
typically zero in cars but often hundreds of dollars in air-
● Learning Glass Lecture Videos: A collection of brief planes. Scores of such examples are sprinkled throughout
instructional videos featuring the authors, Kate Anto- the text. Each one, we believe, poses a question that should
novics and Ori Heffetz, utilize exciting learning glass make any curious person eager to learn the answer.
technology to provide students with an overview of Our ultimate goal is to produce economic naturalists—
important economic concepts. Perfect for an introduc- people who see each human interaction as the result of
tion to basic concepts before coming to class, or as a an implicit or explicit cost-benefit calculation.
quick review, these videos can be accessed as re- The economic naturalist sees mundane details of
sources within SmartBook, or are available as stand- ordinary existence in a new light and becomes actively
alone assignments within Connect. engaged in the attempt to understand them. Some repre-
sentative examples follow:
In Class (Engagement) ● Why do movie theaters offer discount tickets to
● Clicker Questions: Classroom-tested by the authors, ­students?
these multiple-choice questions are designed to fa-
cilitate discussion and group work in class. ● Why do we often see convenience stores located on
adjacent street corners?
● Economic Naturalist Application-Focused Videos: A
known hallmark of this franchise, the Economic Nat- ● Why do supermarket checkout lines all tend to be
uralist examples are now available as an expanded set roughly the same length?
of short, engaging video vignettes within Connect Economic Naturalist Video Series: We are very excited to
and SmartBook. offer an expanded video series based on Economic Natu-
ralist examples. A series of videos covering some of our
After Class (Reinforcement) favorite micro- and macro-focused examples can be used
● Connect Exercises: All end-of-chapter homework ex- as part of classroom presentations, or assigned for home-
ercises are available to be assigned within Connect. work along with accompanying questions within McGraw
Many of these exercises include algorithmic varia- Hill Connect®. These fascinating, fun, and thought-pro-
tions and require students to interact with the voking applications of economics in everyday life encour-
graphing and tool within the platform. Worked age students to think like an economist. Refer to the
Problem Videos, available as hints within Connect, distinguishing features pages of the preface for additional
work through these problems to aid in student un- information. You can view one of these dynamic videos
derstanding of core economic concepts and offer as- here: http://econeveryday.com/why-do-cooked-rotisserie-
sistance with more challenging material. chickens-cost-less-than-fresh-uncooked-chickens/
x PREFACE

Active Learning Stressed ● There is perhaps no more exciting toolkit for the eco-
The only way to learn to hit an overhead smash in tennis nomic naturalist than a few principles of elementary
is through repeated practice. The same is true for learn- game theory. In Chapter 7, Games and Strategic Behav-
ing economics. Accordingly, we consistently introduce ior, we show how these principles enable students to
new ideas in the context of simple examples and then answer a variety of strategic questions that arise in
follow them with applications showing how they work in the marketplace and everyday life. In new Chapter 8,
familiar settings. At frequent intervals, we pose self-tests An Introduction to Behavioral Economics, we survey
that both test and reinforce the understanding of these many of the most exciting developments in what has
ideas. The end-of-chapter questions and problems are become the economics profession’s most vibrant
carefully crafted to help students internalize and extend new field. We believe that the insights of the Nobel
basic concepts, and are available within Connect as as- Laureate Ronald Coase are indispensable for under-
signable content so that instructors can require students standing a host of familiar laws, customs, and social
to engage with this material. Experience with earlier edi- norms. In Chapter 9, Externalities and Property Rights,
tions confirms that this approach really does prepare we show how such devices function to minimize mis-
students to apply basic economic ideas to solve economic allocations that result from externalities.
puzzles drawn from the real world.
Both the Economic Naturalist and Learning Glass
videos and accompanying multiple-choice questions that CHANGES IN THE FOURTH EDITION
test students’ understanding of the principles illustrated
in the videos have become valued tools for instructors Changes Common to All Chapters
who incorporate elements of the flipped-classroom ap- In all chapters, the narrative has been tightened. Many
proach in their teaching, or those who are relying more of the examples have been updated, with a focus on
heavily on other forms of remote learning. Our less-is- ­student-centered examples that connect to current ­topics
more approach to topic coverage is also uniquely well such as the COVID-19 pandemic. The examples, self-
suited to these new instructional approaches. tests, and the end-of-­chapter material from the previous
edition have been ­redesigned to provide more clarity
Modern Microeconomics and ease of use. Data have been updated throughout.
● The cost-benefit principle, which tells us to take only
those actions whose benefits exceed their costs, is the Chapter-by-Chapter Changes
core idea behind the economic way of thinking. Intro- Chapter 1
duced in Chapter 1 and employed repeatedly there- ● Updated student-centered examples, such as Netflix,
after, this principle is more fully developed here
wireless keyboards, dogwalking, and Jeff Bezos
than in any other text. It underlies the argument for
economic efficiency as an important social goal. ● New and updated end-of-chapter problems that re-
Rather than speak of trade-offs between efficiency inforce the chapter’s learning objectives
and other goals, we stress that maximizing economic ● Updated appendix on working with equations,
surplus—that is, taking those actions whose benefits
graphs, and tables based on electric scooter rentals
exceed their costs—facilitates the achievement of
every goal we care about. Chapter 2
● One of the biggest hurdles to the fruitful applica- ● Updated student-centered examples, such as digital
tion of cost-benefit thinking is to recognize and versus print ads and Marvel Studio films
measure the relevant costs and benefits. Common ● New Economic Naturalist, “Why was there a
decision pitfalls identified by 2002 Nobel Laureate
shortage of toilet paper during the COVID-19
Daniel Kahneman and others—such as the ten-
pandemic?”
dency to ignore implicit costs, the tendency not to
ignore sunk costs, and the tendency to confuse av- ● Three new end-of-chapter questions that reinforce
erage and marginal costs and benefits—are intro- the chapter’s learning objectives, including a ques-
duced early in Chapter 1 and invoked repeatedly tion related to the drop in crude oil prices during the
in subsequent chapters. COVID-19 pandemic
PREFACE xi

Chapter 3 goods and services and its supply and demand anal-
ysis in this chapter; also covers issues such as intel-
● Minor updates only
lectual property and national security
● Updated student-centered examples, such as LeBron
James
ORGANIZED LEARNING IN THE FOURTH
● New Economic Naturalist, “Why would Jeff Bezos
EDITION
live in a smaller house in Manhattan than in ­Medina,
Washington?” Chapter Learning Objectives
Chapter 4 Students and professors can be confident that the orga-
nization of each chapter surrounds common themes
● Minor updates only
outlined by four to seven learning objectives listed on
Chapter 5 the first page of each chapter. These objectives, along
● Minor updates only with AACSB and Bloom’s Taxonomy Learning Catego-
ries, are connected to all test bank questions and end-of-
Chapter 6 chapter material to offer a comprehensive, thorough
● Updated student-centered examples, such as Insta- teaching and learning experience. Reports available
gram, electric scooter rentals, iTunes, HBO, Netflix, within Connect allow instructors to easily output data
and cable Internet related to student performance across chapter learning
objectives, AACSB criteria, and Bloom’s Taxonomy
● Updated end-of-chapter problems Learning Categories.
Chapter 7
Assurance of Learning Ready
● Updated student-centered examples, such as the Many educational institutions today are focused on the
Ford Mustang and Chevrolet Camaro notion of assurance of learning, an important element
Chapter 8 of some accreditation standards. Principles of Microeco-
nomics, A Streamlined Approach, 4/e, is designed specifi-
● New to this edition, this chapter serves as an cally to support your assurance of learning initiatives
introduction to behavioral economics for those with a simple, yet powerful, solution. Instructors can
who wish to incorporate this thought-provoking use Connect to easily query for learning objectives that
material directly relate to the objectives of the course and then
Chapter 9 use the reporting features of Connect to aggregate stu-
dent results in a similar fashion, making the collection
● Updated student-centered examples, such as room- and presentation of assurance of learning data simple
mate conflicts and easy.
● Updated end-of-chapter questions
AACSB Statement
Chapter 10
The McGraw Hill Companies is a proud corporate mem-
● Updated information on carbon taxes, including ber of AACSB International. Recognizing the impor-
mention of the Paris Agreement tance and value of AACSB accreditation, the authors of
Principles of Microeconomics, A Streamlined Approach, 4/e,
● Updated material on welfare payments, in-kind
have sought to recognize the curricula guidelines de-
transfers, and the negative income tax
tailed in AACSB standards for business accreditation by
Chapter 11 connecting questions in the test bank and end-of-chap-
ter material to the general knowledge and skill guide-
● Updated student-centered examples, such as inte-
lines found in AACSB standards.
rior designer Kelly Wearstler
It is important to note that the statements contained
● Revised Economic Naturalist that discusses the U.S.- in Principles of Microeconomics, A Streamlined Approach,
China trade war that started in 2018, highlighting 4/e, are provided only as a guide for the users of this
that there is more to trade than the exchange of text.
xii PREFACE

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Anoshua Chaudhuri, San Francisco State University


Our thanks first and foremost go to our portfolio direc- Nan-Ting Chou, University of Louisville
tor, Anke Weekes, and our senior product developer, Maria Luisa Corton, University of South Florida–
Christina Kouvelis. Anke encouraged us to think deeply St. Petersburg
about how to improve the book and helped us transform Manabendra Dasgupta, University of Alabama at
our ideas into concrete changes. Christina shepherded Birmingham
us through the revision process with intelligence, sound Craig Dorsey, College of DuPage
advice, and good humor. We are grateful as well to the
Dennis Edwards, Coastal Carolina University
production team, whose professionalism (and patience)
was outstanding: Christine Vaughan, lead content proj- Tracie Edwards, University of Missouri–St. Louis
ect manager; Emily Windelborn, content project man- Roger Frantz, San Diego State University
ager; Matt Diamond, senior designer; and all of those Mark Frascatore, Clarkson University
who worked on the production team to turn our manu- Amanda Freeman, Kansas State University
script into the book you see now. Finally, we also thank Greg George, Macon State College
Bobby Pearson, marketing manager, for getting our mes-
sage into the wider world. Seth Gershenson, Michigan State University
Special thanks to Peggy Dalton Verner, Frostburg Amy D. Gibson, Christopher Newport University
State University, for her energy, creativity, and help in Rajeev Goel, Illinois State University
refining the assessment material in both the text and Mehdi Haririan, Bloomsburg University of Pennsylvania
Connect; Sukanya Kemp, University of Akron, for her Susan He, Washington State University
detailed accuracy check of the learning glass and
John Hejkal, University of Iowa
­economic naturalist videos; Alvin Angeles and team at
the University of California, San Diego, for their efforts Kuang-Chung Hsu, Kishwaukee College
in the production and editing of the learning glass vid- Greg Hunter, California State University–Pomona
eos; and Kevin Bertotti and the team at ITVK for their David W. Johnson, University of Wisconsin–Madison
creativity in transforming Economic Naturalist examples Derek Johnson, University of Connecticut
into dynamic and engaging video vignettes. Sukanya Kemp, University of Akron
Finally, our sincere thanks to the following teach-
Brian Kench, University of Tampa
ers and colleagues, whose thorough reviews and
thoughtful suggestions led to innumerable substantive Fredric R. Kolb, University of Wisconsin–Eau Claire
improvements to Principles of Microeconomics, A Stream- Daniel D. Kuester, Kansas State University
lined Approach, 4/e. Valerie Lacarte, American University
Mark Abajian, San Diego Mesa College Donald J. Liu, University of Minnesota–Twin Cities
Richard Agesa, Marshall University Ida Mirzaie, The Ohio State University
Seemi Ahmad, Dutchess Community College Jelena Nikolic, Northeastern University
Donald L. Alexander, Western Michigan University Anthony A. Noce, State University of New York
Chris Azevedo, University of Central Missouri (SUNY)–Plattsburgh
Narine Badasyan, Murray State University Diego Nocetti, Clarkson University
Sigridur Benediktsdottir, Yale University Stephanie Owings, Fort Lewis College
Robert Blewett, St. Lawrence University Dishant Pandya, Spalding University
Brian C. Brush, Marquette University Martin Pereyra, University of Missouri
Colleen Callahan, American University Tony Pizelo, Northwest University
Giuliana Campanelli Andreopoulos, William Paterson Ratha Ramoo, Diablo Valley College
University Thomas Rhoads, Towson University
J. Lon Carlson, Illinois State University Bill Robinson, University of Nevada–Las Vegas
David Chaplin, Northwest Nazarene University Brian Rosario, University of California–Davis
Joni Charles, Texas State University Elyce Rotella, Indiana University
PREFACE xiii

Jeffrey Rubin, Rutgers University Markland Tuttle, Sam Houston State University
Naveen Sarna, Northern Virginia Community College David Vera, California State University–Fresno
Sumati Srinivas, Radford University Nancy Virts, California State University–Northridge
Thomas Stevens, University of Massachusetts Gilbert J. Werema, Texas Woman’s University
Carolyn Fabian Stumph, Indiana University and Purdue Elizabeth Wheaton, Southern Methodist University
University–Fort Wayne William C. Wood, James Madison University
issues that might be covered in an introductory course, but only limited time in
however, since they must now havewhich to pay
to coverthe higher
them. world
There’s no price
free lunch. of coffee,
Covering andmeans
some inevitably canomit-
ting others.
therefore consume less. Thus domestic consumers
All textbook of forced
authors are exported goods
to pick and choose.are hurt that
A textbook by covered
free all
the issues would take up more than a whole floor of your campus library. It is our
trade.
DISTINGUISHING FEATURES
firm view that most introductory textbooks try to cover far too much. One reason
Free trade is efficient in the sense thatof it
that each increases
us was drawn to thethestudysize of theispie
of economics that aavailable tolist of
relatively short
the discipline’s core ideas can explain a great deal of the behavior and events we see
the economy. Indeed, the efficiencyin the of world
freearound
trade us. is an application
So rather than cover a largeof theofequilibrium
number ideas at a superficial
principle: Markets in equilibrium leave no
level, our unexploited
strategy is to focus on opportunities for
this short list of core ideas, individuals.
returning to each entry
again and again, in many different contexts. This strategy will enable you to inter-
Despite the efficiency of free trade, nalizehowever, some groups
these ideas remarkably mayspanlose
well in the brief fromcourse.
of a single trade,And the
which generates political pressuresbenefit
ofto
having
of learning a small number of important ideas well will far outweigh the cost
block or arestrict
to ignore trade.
host of other, In the
less important next section we
ones.
will discuss the major types of policy used A second toimportant
restrict trade.
element in our philosophy is a belief in the importance of
active learning. In the same way that you can learn Spanish only by speaking and
writing it, or tennis only by playing the game, you can learn economics only by doing
economics. And because we want you to learn how to do economics, rather than just
Economic The Economic Naturalist 11.1
to read or listen passively as the authors or your instructor does economics, we’ll
make every effort to encourage you to stay actively involved.
Naturalist For example, instead of just telling you about an idea, we’ll usually first motivate
the idea by showing you how it works in the context of a specific example. Often,
What is the China trade shock?
Examples and these examples will be followed by self-tests for you to try, as well as applications that
show the relevance of the idea to real life. Try working the self-tests before looking up

Videos The China trade shock, a term most commonly associated with economists David
the answers (which are at the back of the corresponding chapter).
Think critically about the applications: Do you see how they illustrate the point
Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon Hanson, is used to describe the dramatic change
being made? Do they give you new insight into the issue? Work the problems at the
Each Economic Natural-
in international trade patterns that resulted from China’s rise as a major player in
end of the chapters and take extra care with those relating to points that you don’t
ist example starts with a fully understand. Apply economic principles to the world around you. (We’ll say
the global economy over the past few decades. more about this when we discuss economic naturalism below.) Finally, when you
question to spark curios- come across an idea or example that you find interesting, tell a friend about it.
You’ll be surprised to discover how much the mere act of explaining it helps you
ity and interest in learn- In a series of influential studies, these economists and their collaborators in-understand and remember the underlying principle. The more actively you can
ing an answer. These vestigated the costs of the shock to U.S. workers. They found that employment become engaged in the learning process, the more effective your learning will be.

examples fuel interest has fallen in U.S. industries and regions most exposed to import competition from
while teaching students China—something that our theory ECONOMIC in this chapter NATURALISM
helps explain. However, they did
With the rudiments of the cost-benefit framework under your belt, you are now in a
to see economics in the world not find strong evidence of simultaneous position to become offsetting employment
an “economic naturalist,” someone who increases
uses insights from in eco-
around them. Videos of selectother
and sectors in the same regions, suggesting
nomics to help make sense that ofthe transition
observations of
from everyday workers
life. Peopleinto
studied biology are able to observe and marvel at many details of nature that would
®
who have

new Economic Naturalist exam- sectors in which the U.S.


⊲ Visit your has
instructor’s comparative
Connect otherwise haveadvantage
escaped their notice. has Forbeen
example,neither
on a walk inquick the woods norin early
April, the novice may see only trees. In contrast, the biology student notices many
ples are denoted in the margineasy—something
of that theviewtheory
course and access your eBook to
this video. does not emphasize.
different species of trees and understands why some are already in leaf while others
the material to which they pertain.Overall, these economists conclude thatLikewise,
still lie dormant. workers’ the noviceadjustment
may notice thatto trade
in some
are much larger than females, but the biology student knows that pattern occurs
animalshocks
species males

They are housed within Connectis often a slow and difficult process, only in andspeciesthat local
in which maleslabor force
take several participation
mates. Natural selection rates favors larger
with accompanying questions. andAunemployment rates in affected regions may take a decade or more
males in those species because their greater size helps them prevail in the often
bloody contests among males for access to females. In contrast, males tend to be
to re-
cover.
full list of Economic Naturalist ex- Moreover, the slow adjustment roughlymeansthe same size that tradein shocks
as females monogamous could
species, lead
in whichto pro-
there is much
less fighting for mates.
amples and videos can be foundlonged
in economic and social problems in affected communities.
the following pages. While the research underlying 8 CHAPTER 1 these
THINKING LIKEconclusions
AN ECONOMIST is still new and is still being
examined, it serves as a reminder that for many workers, the short-term costs of
Numbered Examples trade may outweigh the Eshort-term X A M P L E 1 . 3 benefits. Implicit Cost While opposition to trade among
fra26395_ch01_001-030.indd 14 08/12/20 9:21 AM
Throughout the text, numbered such workers
and titledis understandable, we should Should not conclude
you use thatcoupon
your frequent-flyer thetooverall
fly to Cancun costs of
for spring
break?
examples are referenced and trade outweigh
called out tothe overall benefits. Rather, as these economists conclude in
With spring break only a week away, you are still undecided about whether to go
one
further illustrate concepts.ofOurtheirengaging
studies: to Cancun with a group of classmates at the University of Iowa. The round-trip
airfare from Cedar Rapids is $500, but you have a frequent-flyer coupon you could
questions and examples from everyday life use for the trip. All other relevant costs for the vacation week at the beach total
exactly $1,000. The most you would be willing to pay for the Cancun vacation is

highlight how each human action is the Better understanding when and where $1,350.trade is costly,
That amount and
is your benefit how
of taking the and why
vacation. Your only alternative
use for your frequent-flyer coupon is for a trip to Boston the weekend after spring
it may
­result of an implicit or explicit cost-benefitbe beneficial, is a key item on the
break research
to attend agenda
your brother’s for
wedding. (Your trade
coupon and
expires shortly thereafter.) If
the Cedar Rapids–Boston round-trip airfare is $400, should you use your

­calculation. labor economists. Developing effective tools


frequent-flyer for
coupon tomanaging and
fly to Cancun for spring mitigat-
break?
The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that you should go to Cancun if the benefits
ing the costs of trade adjustment should
of the tripbe high
exceed onIf not
its costs. the agenda
for the complicationfor
of thepoli-
frequent-flyer coupon,
solving this problem would be a straightforward matter of comparing
cymakers and applied economists.1 your benefit from the week at the beach to the sum of all relevant costs.
And because your airfare and other costs would add up to $1,500, or
$150 more than your benefit from the trip, you would not go to Cancun.
But what about the possibility of using your frequent-flyer coupon
to make the trip? Using it for that purpose might make the flight to Can-
Bkindler/E+/Getty Images

1 12 Autor,
David CHAPTER
David1 Dorn,
THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST
and Gordon Hanson, “The China Shock: Learning from Labor Market cun seem free, suggesting you’d reap an economic surplus of $350 by
making the trip. But doing so also would mean you’d have to fork over
Adjustment to Large Changes in Trade,” Annual Review of Economics 8 (October 2016), pp. 205–240.
$400 for your airfare to Boston. So the implicit cost of using your cou-
pon to go to Cancun is really $400. If you use it for that purpose, the
contexts, however, people seemtrip still ends up being a loser because the cost of the vacation, $1,400,
more inclined to compare the average cost and benefit
exceeds the benefit by $50. In cases like these, you’re much more
Is your flight to Cancun “free”
of travel
if you theonactivity. As Example 1.5likely
a frequent-flyer made clear,sensibly
to decide increasing the
if you ask level“Should
yourself, of anI activity may not
use my frequent-
flyer coupon for this trip or save it for an upcoming trip?”
be justified, even though its average benefit at the current level is significantly greater
coupon?

than its average cost.


We cannot emphasize strongly enough that the key to using the Cost-Benefit

SELF-TESTS Principle correctly lies in recognizing precisely what taking a given action pre-
vents us from doing. Self-Test 1.3 illustrates this point by modifying the details of
SELF-TEST 1.5 Example 1.3 slightly.
These self-test questions in the body
fra26395_ch11_261-280.indd 269 of the chap-
Should a basketball team’s best player take all the team’s shots?
ter enable students to determine whether the SELF-TEST 1.3
A professional basketball team has a new assistant coach. The assistant
Refer to given information in Example 1.3, but this time your frequent-flyer cou-
preceding material has been understood and re- notices that one player scores on a higher percentage of her shots than other
pon expires in a week, so your only chance to use it will be for the Cancun trip.
players. Based on this information,
Should the assistant suggests to the head coach
you use your coupon?
inforce understanding before reading further. that the star player take all the shots. That way, the assistant reasons, the team
Detailed answers to the self-test questions are will score more points and win more games.
Pitfall 3: Failing to Think at the Margin
On hearing this suggestion, the head coach fires her assistant for incompe-
found at the end of each chapter. tence. What was wrong
When deciding whether to take an action, the only relevant costs and benefits are
with theoccur
assistant’s
those that would as a result ofidea?
taking the action. Sometimes people are influ-
enced by costs they ought to ignore. Other times they compare the wrong costs and
benefits. The only costs that should influence a decision about whether to take an action are
those we can avoid by not taking the action. Similarly, the only benefits we should consider
are those that would not occur unless the action were taken. As a practical matter, how-
ever, many decision makers appear to be influenced by costs or benefits R Ethat
CA would
P
xiv THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS
1. The pitfall of measuring costs or benefits proportionally. Many decision
makers treat a change in cost or benefit as insignificant if it constitutes
fra26395_ch01_001-030.indd 8 08/12/20 9:21 AM
only a small proportion of the original amount. Absolute dollar amounts,
DISTINGUISHING FEATURES xv

CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

Recap
RECAP
COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS Sprinkled throughout each chapter are Recap
Scarcity is a basic fact of economic life. Because of it, having more of one boxes that underscore and summarize the impor-
good thing almost always means having less of another. The Cost-Benefit tance of the preceding material and key concept
Principle holds that an individual (or a firm or a society) should take an action
if, and only if, the extra benefit from taking the action is at least as great as takeaways.
the extra cost. The benefit of taking any action minus the cost of taking the
action is called the economic surplus from that action. Hence, the Cost-
Benefit Principle suggests that we take only those actions that create addi-
tional economic surplus.

THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS1


Rational people will apply the Cost-Benefit Principle most of the time, although
probably in an intuitive and approximate way, rather than through explicit and
precise calculation. Knowing that rational people tend to compare costs and bene-
Worked Problem Videos
fits enables economists to predict their likely behavior. As noted earlier, for exam-
ple, we can predict that students from wealthy families are more likely than others
Brief videos
to attend work
colleges through
that offer end-of-chapter
small classes. prob-
(Again, while the cost of small classes is
the same for all families, their benefit, as measured by what people are willing to
lems to aid in student understanding
pay for them, tends to be higher for wealthier families.)
of core
economic concepts
Yet researchers and offer
have identified assistance
situations with
in which people tend to apply the Cost-
Benefit
more Principle inconsistently.
challenging material. In these
Thesituations,
videos the
areCost-Benefit
avail- Principle may
not predict behavior accurately. But it proves helpful in another way, by identifying
able as hints
specific within
strategies Connect.
for avoiding bad decisions.

Pitfall 1: Measuring Costs and Benefits as Proportions


Rather Than Absolute Dollar Amounts
As the next example makes clear, even people who seem to know they should weigh
the pros and cons of the actions they are contemplating sometimes don’t have a clear
sense of how to measure the relevant costs and benefits.

Comparing Costs and Benefits

LEARNING GLASS
Should you walk
computer?
downtownVIDEOS
to save $10 on a $2,020 laptop

Dozens of lecture
You are about to buy a videos featuring
$2,020 laptop computer authors Kate
at the nearby campus store when
Antonovics and
a friend tells you Ori
that the Heffetz
same computerutilize
is on sale learning
at a downtown store for only
$2,010. If the downtown store is half an hour’s walk away, where should you buy
glass technology to provide you with an over-
the computer?
viewAssuming
of important concepts. These videos can be
that the laptop is light enough to carry without effort, the structure
®
accessed as resources
of this example is exactly thewithin
same asSmartBook
that of Example 1.1.orThe
asonly difference is
assignable
that the pricecontent with
of the laptop questions
is dramatically via than
higher McGraw
the price of the wireless
keyboard. As before,
® the benefit of buying downtown is the dollar amount you’ll
Hill
save,Connect
namely, $10.. And because it’s exactly the same trip, its cost also must be the

1
The examples in this section are inspired by the pioneering research of Daniel Kahneman and the late
Amos Tversky. Kahneman was awarded the 2002 Nobel Prize in Economics for his efforts to integrate in-
sights from psychology into economics. You can read more about this work in Kahneman’s brilliant 2011
book, Thinking Fast and Slow (New York: Macmillan).

11/01/21 12:58 PM

xv
EC ONOMI C NATUR A LIST
V I DEO SE RIE S

Behavioral Economics: Why do real estate agents often Supply and Demand: Why are rotisserie chickens less
show clients two nearly identical houses, even though one is ­expensive than fresh chickens?
both cheaper and in better condition than the other? Tariffs: Why do consumers in the United States often pay
Comparative Advantage: Why are many products designed more than double the world price for sugar?
in one place yet assembled in another? The Demand for Money: Why does the average Argentine
Cost Benefit 1: Why does the light come on when you open ­citizen hold more U.S. dollars than the average U.S. citizen?
the refrigerator door but not when you open the freezer? The Invisible Hand: Why do supermarket checkout lines all
Cost Benefit 2: Why are child safety seats required in auto- tend to be roughly the same length?
mobiles but not in airplanes? The Law of Demand: Why are smaller automobile engines
Discount Pricing: Why might an appliance retailer hammer more common in Europe than in the United States?
dents into the sides of its stoves and refrigerators? The Optimal Amount of Information: Why might a patient
Elasticity: Why do people buy the same amount of salt as be more likely to receive an expensive magnetic resonance
before even when the price of salt doubles? ­imaging (MRI) exam for a sore knee if covered under a con-
Menu Costs: Will new technologies eliminate menu costs? ventional health insurance rather than a health maintenance
Monopolistic Competition: Why do we often see conve- organization (HMO) plan?
nience stores located on adjacent street corners? The Tragedy of the Commons and Property Rights: Why
Prisoner’s Dilemma: Why do people shout at parties? do blackberries in public parks get picked before they’re
Production Costs: Why are brown eggs more expensive than ­completely ripe?
white ones?

xvi
ECO N O M I C N ATUR A LI ST
EX A M P L E S

1.1 Why do many hardware manufacturers include 6.2 Why do many movie theaters offer discount tick-
more than $1,000 worth of “free” software with a ets to students?
computer selling for only slightly more than that? 6.3 Why might an appliance retailer instruct its clerks
1.2 Why don’t auto manufacturers make cars without to hammer dents into the sides of its stoves and
­heaters? refrigerators?
1.3 Why do the keypad buttons on drive-up auto- 7.1 Why are cartel agreements notoriously unstable?
mated teller machines have Braille dots? 7.2 How did Congress unwittingly solve the television
2.1 When the federal government implements a large advertising dilemma confronting cigarette
pay increase for its employees, why do rents for ­producers?
apartments located near Washington Metro sta- 7.3 Why do people shout at parties?
tions go up relative to rents for apartments located 7.4 Why do we often see convenience stores located
far away from Metro stations? on adjacent street corners?
2.2 Why do major term papers go through so many 8.1 Why did the American Olympic swimmer Shirley
more revisions today than in the 1970s? Babashoff, who set one world record and six na-
2.3 Why do the prices of some goods, like airline tick- tional records at the 1976 Olympics, refuse to ap-
ets to Europe, go up during the months of heavi- pear on the cover of Sports Illustrated?
est consumption, while others, like sweet corn, go 8.2 Why would people pay thousands of dollars to at-
down? tend a weight-loss camp that will feed them only
2.4 Why was there a shortage of toilet paper during 1,500 calories per day?
the COVID-19 pandemic? 8.3 Why was Obamacare difficult to enact and is
3.1 Why does California experience chronic water harder still to repeal?
shortages? 8.4 Why have attempts to privatize Social Security
3.2 Why would Jeff Bezos live in a smaller house in proved so politically unpopular in the United
Manhattan than in Medina, Washington? States?
3.3 Why did people turn to four-cylinder cars in the 8.5 If prosperous voters would be happier if they
1970s, only to shift back to six- and eight-cylinder spent less on positional goods and lived in envi-
cars in the 1990s? ronments with more generously funded public
3.4 Why are automobile engines smaller in England sectors, why haven’t they elected politicians who
than in the United States? would deliver what they want?
3.5 Why are waiting lines longer in poorer neighbor- 9.1 What is the purpose of free speech laws?
hoods? 9.2 Why does the government subsidize private prop-
3.6 Will a higher tax on cigarettes curb teenage erty owners to plant trees on their hillsides?
smoking? 9.3 Why do blackberries in public parks get picked
3.7 Why was the luxury tax on yachts such a disaster? too soon?
4.1 When recycling is left to private market forces, 9.4 Why are shared milkshakes consumed too
why are many more aluminum beverage contain- quickly?
ers recycled than glass ones? 9.5 Why do football players take anabolic steroids?
4.2 Why are gasoline prices so much more volatile 10.1 Why is a patient with a sore knee more likely to
than car prices? receive an MRI exam if he has conventional health
5.1 Why do supermarket checkout lines all tend to be insurance than if he belongs to a health mainte-
roughly the same length? nance organization?
5.2 Are there “too many” smart people working as 11.1 What is the China trade shock?
corporate earnings forecasters? 11.2 Why did the U.S. start a trade war with China?
6.1 Why does Intel sell the overwhelming majority of 11.3 What is fast track authority?
all microprocessors used in personal computers?

xvii
S UP P LE M E N TS

The following ancillaries are available for quick down- textbook, accompanied by animated graphs and slide
load and convenient access via the Instructor Resource notes. You can edit, print, or rearrange the slides to fit
material available through McGraw Hill Connect®. the needs of your course.

Solutions Manual Customizable Micro Lecture Notes and


Prepared by the authors with assistance from Peggy PowerPoints
Dalton Verner, Frostburg State University, this manual One of the biggest hurdles to an instructor considering
provides detailed answers to the end-of-chapter review changing textbooks is the prospect of having to prepare
questions and problems. new lecture notes and slides. For the microeconomics
chapters, this hurdle no longer exists. A full set of lecture
Test Bank
notes for principles of microeconomics, prepared by Bob
The test bank has been carefully revised and reviewed Frank for his award-winning introductory microeconom-
for accuracy. Hundreds of questions have been catego- ics course at Cornell University, is available as Microsoft
rized by chapter learning objectives, AACSB learning Word files that instructors are welcome to customize as
categories, Bloom’s Taxonomy objectives, and level of they see fit. The challenge for any instructor is to rein-
difficulty. Select problems are now offered as an algo- force the lessons of the text in lectures without generat-
rithmic alternative, providing even more variation. ing student unrest by merely repeating what’s in the
book. These lecture notes address that challenge by con-
Test Builder in Connect
structing examples that run parallel to those presented
Available within Connect, Test Builder is a cloud-based in the book, yet are different from them in interesting
tool that enables instructors to format tests that can be contextual ways. Also available is a complete set of richly
printed or administered within an LMS. Test Builder of- illustrated PowerPoint files to accompany these lecture
fers a modern, streamlined interface for easy content notes. Instructors are also welcome to customize these
configuration that matches course needs, without requir- files as they wish.
ing a download.
Test Builder allows you to: Remote Proctoring and Browser-Locking
Capabilities
• access all test bank content from a particular title.
• easily pinpoint the most relevant content through
robust filtering options.
• manipulate the order of questions or scramble ques- New remote proctoring and browser-locking capabilities,
tions and/or answers. hosted by Proctorio within Connect, provide control of
the assessment environment by enabling security op-
• pin questions to a specific location within a test.
tions and verifying the identity of the student.
• determine your preferred treatment of algorithmic Seamlessly integrated within Connect, these services
questions. allow instructors to control students’ assessment experi-
ence by restricting browser activity, recording students’
• choose the layout and spacing.
activity, and verifying students are doing their own work.
• add instructions and configure default settings. Instant and detailed reporting gives instructors an
at-a-glance view of potential academic integrity con-
Test Builder provides a secure interface for better protec-
cerns, thereby avoiding personal bias and supporting
tion of content and allows for just-in-time updates to
evidence-based claims.
flow directly into assessments.

PowerPoints FOR MORE INFORMATION ABOUT CONNECT AND


Presentation slides contain a detailed, chapter-by-­ ITS AVAILABLE RESOURCES, REFER TO THE PAGES
chapter review of the important ideas presented in the THAT FOLLOW.

xix
Connect Economics
Asset Alignment with
Bloom’s Taxonomy
Principles of Microeconomics: A Streamlined Approach, 4e

We Take Students Higher


As a learning science company we create content that supports higher order thinking skills.
Within Connect®, we tag assessments accordingly so you can filter your search, assign it, and
receive reporting on it. These content asset types can be associated with one or more levels of
Bloom’s Taxonomy.

The chart below shows a few of the key assignable economics assets with McGraw Hill
Connect aligned with Bloom’s Taxonomy. Take your students higher by assigning a variety of
applications, moving them from simple memorization to concept application.

ECON
ECON Application- Writing
SmartBook Interactive Everyday
Adaptive Videos Exercises Based Assignment
2.0 Graphs Current
Math Prep Activities Plus
Events Blog*


Thinking Skills
Higher Order

CREATE

EVALUATE
✓ ✓ ✓
ANALYZE
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
APPLY
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
UNDERSTAND
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
Thinking Skills
Lower Order

REMEMBER
✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
* Outside of Connect.
SmartBook 2.0
Adaptively aids students to study more efficiently by highlighting where in the
chapter to focus, asking review questions and pointing them to passages in the
text until they understand. Assignable and assessable.

Adaptive Econ Prep


Math and graphing preparedness assignments help students refresh important
prerequisite topics necessary to be successful in economics. New Adaptive Econ
Prep Tool provides students just-in-time math remediation that is prerequisite to
success in Principles of Economics courses and adapts to each student.

Videos
Worked examples and real-world application videos help students learn economics.
Learning Glass videos reinforce challenging topics featuring the authors and innovative
learning glass technology. Economic Naturalist videos bring examples to life showing
interesting applications of economic concepts. Worked Problem videos work through
select end-of-chapter questions for extra help and guidance through challenging material.

Exercises
Exercises with algorithmic variations provide ample opportunities for students to
practice and hone quantitative skills. Graphing Exercises provide opportunities for
students to draw, interact with, manipulate, and analyze graphs.

Interactive Graphs
Interactive Graphs provide visual displays of real data and economic concepts for
students to manipulate. All graphs are accompanied by assignable assessment
questions and feedback to guide students through the experience of learning to read
and interpret graphs and data.

Application-Based Activities
Immersive real-life scenarios engage students and put them in the role of everyday
economists. Students practice their economic thinking and problem-solving skills as they
apply course concepts and see the implications of their decisions as they go. Each activity is
designed as a 15-minute experience, unless students eagerly replay for a better outcome.

ECON Everyday Blog*


Our ECON Everyday blog saves instructors time bringing current, student-centered
content into their course all semester long. Short articles, written for principles-level
students, are tagged by topic to bring currency into your course. We also provide
discussion questions to help you drive the conversation forward. Visit
www.econeveryday.com and subscribe for updates. (*Outside of Connect.)

Writing Assignment Plus


Writing Assignment Plus delivers a learning experience that helps students improve
their written communication skills and conceptual understanding. Faculty can assign,
monitor, grade, and provide feedback on writing projects efficiently. Built-in grammar
and writing review helps students improve writing quality while an originality check
helps students correct central plagiarism before submission. End result? Improved
workplace skills of writing in critical thinking.

For more information, please visit: www.mheducation.com/highered/economics


®

Instructors: Student Success Starts with You


Tools to enhance your unique voice
Want to build your own course? No problem. Prefer to use our turnkey,
prebuilt course? Easy. Want to make changes throughout the semester?
65%
Less Time
Sure. And you’ll save time with Connect’s auto-grading too.
Grading

Study made personal


Incorporate adaptive study resources like
SmartBook® 2.0 into your course and help your
students be better prepared in less time. Learn
more about the powerful personalized learning
experience available in SmartBook 2.0 at
www.mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook

Laptop: McGraw Hill; Woman/dog: George Doyle/Getty Images

Affordable solutions, Solutions for


added value your challenges
Make technology work for you with A product isn’t a solution. Real
LMS integration for single sign-on access, solutions are affordable, reliable,
mobile access to the digital textbook, and come with training and
and reports to quickly show you how ongoing support when you need
each of your students is doing. And with it and how you want it. Visit www.
our Inclusive Access program you can supportateverystep.com for videos
provide all these tools at a discount to and resources both you and your
your students. Ask your McGraw Hill students can use throughout the
representative for more information. semester.

Padlock: Jobalou/Getty Images Checkmark: Jobalou/Getty Images


Students: Get Learning That Fits You
Effective tools for efficient studying
Connect is designed to make you more productive with simple, flexible, intuitive tools that maximize
your study time and meet your individual learning needs. Get learning that works for you with Connect.

Study anytime, anywhere “I really liked this


Download the free ReadAnywhere app and access your app—it made it easy
online eBook or SmartBook 2.0 assignments when it’s to study when you
convenient, even if you’re offline. And since the app don't have your text-
automatically syncs with your eBook and SmartBook 2.0
assignments in Connect, all of your work is available
book in front of you.”
every time you open it. Find out more at
www.mheducation.com/readanywhere - Jordan Cunningham,
Eastern Washington University

Everything you need in one place


Your Connect course has everything you need—whether reading on
your digital eBook or completing assignments for class, Connect makes
it easy to get your work done.

Calendar: owattaphotos/Getty Images

Learning for everyone


McGraw Hill works directly with Accessibility Services
Departments and faculty to meet the learning needs
of all students. Please contact your Accessibility
Services Office and ask them to email
accessibility@mheducation.com, or visit
www.mheducation.com/about/accessibility
for more information.

Top: Jenner Images/Getty Images, Left: Hero Images/Getty Images, Right: Hero Images/Getty Images
C O MPA R I S O N GUIDE F OR F RANK , BE RNA NKE,
A NTO N OVI C S , AND HE F F E T Z PRODUCTS
Principles of Economics provides enhanced coverage and offers more topics and mathematical rigor. Principles of Economics: A Streamlined
­Approach is a stripped-down version of the big book featuring core content with a less-is-more approach. See which product is right for you!

Comparison Guide
Principles of Economics, 8th edition Principles of Economics: A Streamlined Approach, 4th edition
Econ Micro Macro Streamlined Streamlined Streamlined
Chapter Title 8e 8e 8e Chapter Title 4e Econ 4e Micro 4e Macro
Thinking Like an Economist 1 1 1 Thinking Like an Economist 1 1 1
Comparative Advantage 2 2 2
Supply and Demand 3 3 3 Supply and Demand 2 2 2
Elasticity 4 4
Demand and Elasticity 3 3
Demand 5 5
Perfectly Competitive Supply 6 6 Perfectly Competitive Supply 4 4
Efficiency, Exchange, and the 7 7 Efficiency, Exchange, and 5 5
Invisible Hand in Action the Invisible Hand in Action
Monopoly, Oligopoly, and 8 8 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and 6 6
Monopolistic Competition Monopolistic Competition
Games and Strategic 9 9 Games and Strategic 7 7
Behavior Behavior
An Introduction to 10 10 An Introduction to Behavioral 8 8
Behavioral Economics Economics (NEW)
Externalities, Property 11 11 Externalities and Property 9 9
Rights, and the Environment Rights
The Economics of Information 12 12
Using Economics to Make
Labor Markets, Poverty, and 13 13 10 10
Better Policy Choices
Income Distribution
Public Goods and Tax Policy 14 14
International Trade and 15 15 16 International Trade and 11 11 12
Trade Policy Trade Policy
Macroeconomics: The Bird’s- 16 4 Macroeconomics: The Bird’s 12 3
Eye View of the Economy Eye View of the Economy
Measuring Economic Activity: 17 5
Measuring Economic Activity:
GDP and Unemployment
GDP, Unemployment, and 13 4
Measuring the Price Level 18 6
Inflation
and Inflation
Economic Growth, Productivity, 19 7 Economic Growth, Productivity, 14 5
and Living Standards and Living Standards
The Labor Market: Workers, 20 8 The Labor Market: Workers, 15 6
Wages, and Unemployment Wages, and Unemployment
Saving and Capital Formation 21 9 Saving and Capital Formation 16 7
Money, Prices, and the 22 10
Money, the Federal
Federal Reserve
Reserve, and Global 17 8
Financial Markets and 23 11
Financial Markets
International Capital Flows
Short-Term Economic 24 12
Short-Term Economic
Fluctuations: An Introduction
Fluctuations and Fiscal 18 9
Spending and Output in the 25 13
Policy
Short Run
Stabilizing the Economy: The 26 14 Stabilizing the Economy: The 19 10
Role of the Fed Role of the Fed
Aggregate Demand, 27 15 Aggregate Demand, 20 11
Aggregate Supply, and Aggregate Supply, and
Inflation Inflation
Exchange Rates and the 28 17 Exchange Rates and the 21 13
Open Economy Open Economy
BR I EF C ONTE N TS

PART 1 Introduction
1 Thinking Like an Economist 1
2 Supply and Demand 31

PART 2 Competition and the Invisible Hand


3 Demand and Elasticity 65
4 Perfectly Competitive Supply 91
5 Efficiency, Exchange, and the Invisible Hand in Action 119

PART 3 Market Imperfections


6 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition 141
7 Games and Strategic Behavior 169
8 An Introduction to Behavioral Economics 195
9 Externalities and Property Rights 217

PART 4 Economics of Public Policy


10 Using Economics to Make Better Policy Choices 241

PART 5 International Trade


11 International Trade and Trade Policy 261

xxvi
C ON T E N TS

PART 1 Introduction THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.4 57


Summary 58 ▯ Key Terms 59 ▯ Review Questions 59 ▯
Chapter 1 Thinking Like an Economist 1 Problems 59 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 60 ▯ Appendix: The
Algebra of Supply and Demand 63
Economics: Studying Choice in a World of Scarcity 2
Applying the Cost-Benefit Principle 3
Economic Surplus 4
Opportunity Cost 4 PART 2 Competition and the
The Role of Economic Models 5 Invisible Hand
Three Important Decision Pitfalls 6
Chapter 3 Demand and Elasticity 65
Pitfall 1: Measuring Costs and Benefits as Proportions
The Law of Demand 66
Rather Than Absolute Dollar Amounts 6
Pitfall 2: Ignoring Implicit Costs 7 The Origins of Demand 66
Pitfall 3: Failing to Think at the Margin 8 Needs versus Wants 67
Normative Economics versus Positive Economics 13 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.1 67
Economics: Micro and Macro 13 Applying the Law of Demand 68

The Approach of This Text 14 Substitution at Work 68

Economic Naturalism 14 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.2 68


THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.3 69
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 1.1 15
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.4 70
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 1.2 15
The Importance of Income Differences 70
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 1.3 16
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.5 71
Summary 17 ▯ Key Terms 17 ▯ Review Questions 17 ▯
Problems 18 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 19 ▯ Appendix: Working Individual and Market Demand Curves 71
with Equations, Graphs, and Tables 21 Horizontal Addition 71
Elasticity 73
Chapter 2 Supply and Demand 31
Price Elasticity of Demand 73
What, How, and for Whom? Central Planning Price Elasticity Defined 73
versus the Market 33 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand 75
Buyers and Sellers in Markets 34 Some Representative Elasticity Estimates 76
The Demand Curve 35 Using Price Elasticity of Demand 77
The Supply Curve 36 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.6 77
Market Equilibrium 38 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 3.7 77
Rent Controls Reconsidered 41 A Graphical Interpretation of Price Elasticity 78
Pizza Price Controls? 43 Price Elasticity Changes along a Straight-Line
Predicting and Explaining Changes in Prices Demand Curve 80
and Quantities 44 Two Special Cases 81
Shifts in Demand 45 Elasticity and Total Expenditure 82
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.1 47 Income Elasticity and Cross-Price Elasticity
Shifts in the Supply Curve 48 of Demand 86
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.2 51 Summary 87 ▯ Key Terms 87 ▯ Review Questions 88 ▯
Four Simple Rules 51 Problems 88 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 89
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 2.3 54
Efficiency and Equilibrium 54 Chapter 4 Perfectly Competitive Supply 91
Cash on the Table 55 Thinking about Supply: The Importance of
Smart for One, Dumb for All 56 Opportunity Cost 92

xxvii
xxviii CONTENTS

Individual and Market Supply Curves 94 PART 3 Market Imperfections


Profit-Maximizing Firms in Perfectly
Competitive Markets 95 Chapter 6 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and
Profit Maximization 95 Monopolistic Competition 141
The Demand Curve Facing a Perfectly Perfect and Imperfect Competition 142
Competitive Firm 96 Different Forms of Imperfect Competition 142
Production in the Short Run 97 The Essential Difference between Perfectly and
Choosing Output to Maximize Profit 98 Imperfectly Competitive Firms 144
Price Equals Marginal Cost: The Seller’s Supply Five Sources of Market Power 145
Rule 101 Exclusive Control over Important Inputs 145
Graphing Marginal Cost 101 Patents and Copyrights 145
The “Law” of Supply 103 Government Licenses or Franchises 145
Applying the Theory of Supply 104 Economies of Scale and Natural Monopolies 146
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 4.1 104 Network Economies 146
Determinants of Supply Revisited 107 Economies of Scale and the Importance of Start-Up Costs 147
Technology 107 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 6.1 150
Input Prices 107 Profit Maximization for the Monopolist 150
The Number of Suppliers 107 Marginal Revenue for the Monopolist 150
Expectations 108 The Monopolist’s Profit-Maximizing Decision Rule 152
Changes in Prices of Other Products 108 Being a Monopolist Doesn’t Guarantee
The Price Elasticity of Supply 108 an Economic Profit 154
Determinants of Supply Elasticity 111 Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down under
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 4.2 112 Monopoly 155
Unique and Essential Inputs: The Ultimate Supply Using Discounts to Expand the Market 156
Bottleneck 114 Price Discrimination Defined 157
Summary 115 ▯ Key Terms 116 ▯ Review Questions 116 ▯
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 6.2 157
Problems 116 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 117
How Price Discrimination Affects Output 157
The Hurdle Method of Price Discrimination 160
Chapter 5 Efficiency, Exchange, and the Is Price Discrimination a Bad Thing? 163
Invisible Hand in Action 119 Examples of Price Discrimination 163
The Central Role of Economic Profit 120 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 6.3 164
Three Types of Profit 120 Summary 165 ▯ Key Terms 166 ▯
The Invisible Hand Theory 123 Review Questions 166 ▯ Problems 166 ▯
Two Functions of Price 123 Answers to Self-Tests 168
Responses to Profits and Losses 123
The Effect of Market Forces on Economic Chapter 7 Games and Strategic Behavior 169
Profit 125
Using Game Theory to Analyze Strategic Decisions 170
The Importance of Free Entry
The Three Elements of a Game 170
and Exit 126
Nash Equilibrium 172
The Invisible Hand in Action 127
The Prisoner’s Dilemma 174
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.1 127
The Original Prisoner’s Dilemma 174
Economic Rent versus Economic Profit 129
The Economics of Cartels 175
The Distinction between an Equilibrium and a
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 7.1 175
Social Optimum 130
Tit-for-Tat and the Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma 177
Smart for One, Dumb for All 131
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 7.2 178
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 5.2 131
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 7.3 179
Market Equilibrium and Efficiency 132
Games in Which Timing Matters 180
The Cost of Preventing Price Adjustments 136
Credible Threats and Promises 182
Summary 138 ▯ Key Terms 139 ▯
Monopolistic Competition When Location Matters 184
Review Questions 139 ▯ Problems 139 ▯
Answers to Self-Tests 140 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 7.4 184
CONTENTS xxix

Commitment Problems 186 Summary 237 ▯ Key Terms 237 ▯ Review Questions 237 ▯

Solving Commitment Problems with Psychological Problems 238 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 239
Incentives 188
Summary 190 ▯ Key Terms 190 ▯ Review Questions 191 ▯
PART 4 Economics of Public Policy
Problems 191 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 194
Chapter 10 Using Economics to Make Better
Chapter 8 An Introduction to Behavioral Policy Choices 241
Economics 195 The Economics of Health Care 242
Judgmental Heuristics or Rules of Thumb 196 The Case for Mandatory Immunization Laws 242
Availability 196 Explaining Rising Health Care Costs 243
Representativeness 197 Designing a Solution 244
Regression to the Mean 198 The HMO Revolution 245
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.1 198 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 10.1 245
Anchoring and Adjustment 199 The Problem with Health Care Provision
Misinterpretation of Contextual Clues 200 through Private Insurance 246
The Psychophysics of Perception 200 The Affordable Care Act of 2010 247
The Difficulty of Actually Deciding 200 Using Price Incentives in Environmental Regulation 248
Impulse-Control Problems 202 Taxing Pollution 248
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.2 203 Auctioning Pollution Permits 250
Loss Aversion and Status Quo Bias 205 Climate Change and Carbon Taxes 252
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.3 206 Methods of Income Redistribution 253
Concerns about Relative Position 207 Welfare Payments and In-Kind Transfers 254
Means-Tested Benefit Programs 254
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.4 210
The Negative Income Tax 255
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 8.5 211
Minimum Wages 255
Summary 214 ▯ Key Terms 215 ▯ Review Questions 215 ▯
Problems 215 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 216 The Earned-Income Tax Credit 256
Public Employment for the Poor 256
Chapter 9 Externalities and Property Rights 217 A Combination of Methods 256
External Costs and Benefits 217 Summary 258 ▯ Key Terms 258 ▯ Review Questions 258 ▯
Problems 258 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 259
How Externalities Affect Resource Allocation 218
The Coase Theorem 219
Remedies for Externalities 223 PART 5 International Trade
Laws and Regulations 223
Chapter 11 International Trade and Trade
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.1 225
Policy 261
The Optimal Amount of Negative
Externalities Is Not Zero 225 Comparative Advantage as a Basis for Trade 262
Compensatory Taxes and Subsidies 226 A Supply and Demand Perspective on Trade 266
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.2 226 Winners and Losers from Trade 268
Property Rights and the Tragedy of the Commons 227 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.1 269
The Problem of Unpriced Resources 227 Protectionist Policies: Tariffs and Quotas 270
The Effect of Private Ownership 229 Tariffs 270
When Private Ownership Is Impractical 230 Quotas 272
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.3 230 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.2 275
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.4 231 The Inefficiency of Protectionism 276
Positional Externalities 232 THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 11.3 276
Payoffs That Depend on Relative Performance 232 Summary 277 ▯ Key Terms 278 ▯ Review Questions 278 ▯
Problems 278 ▯ Answers to Self-Tests 280
THE ECONOMIC NATURALIST 9.5 232
Positional Arms Races and Positional
Glossary G-1
Arms Control Agreements 234
Social Norms as Positional Arms Control Agreements 235 Index I-1
FOURTH EDITION

Principles of
MICROECONOMICS
A STREAMLINED APPROACH
1
LEARNING OBJECTIVES

Thinking Like
After reading this chapter, you
should be able to:

L O 1 Explain why having

an Economist
more of any good
thing necessarily
­requires having less
of something else.

L O 2 Explain and apply the


How many students are in your introductory economics class? Some classes have just Cost-Benefit Principle,
20 or so. Others average 35, 100, or 200 students. At some schools, introductory eco- which says that an ac-
nomics classes may have as many as 2,000 students. What size is best? tion should be taken if,
If cost were no object, the best size might be a single student. Think about it: the but only if, its benefit is
whole course, all term long, with just you and your professor! Everything could be at least as great as its
custom-­tailored to your own background and ability. You could cover the material at cost.
just the right pace. The tutorial format also would promote close communication and L O 3 Discuss three important
personal trust between you and your professor. And your grade would depend more pitfalls that occur when
heavily on what you actually learned than on your luck when taking multiple-choice applying the Cost-
exams. Let’s suppose, for the sake of discussion, that students have been shown to Benefit Principle
learn best in the tutorial format. inconsistently.
Why, then, do so many introductory classes still have hundreds of students?
The simple reason is that costs do matter. They matter not just to the university ad- L O 4 Explain why if you want
ministrators who must build classrooms and pay faculty salaries, but also to you. to predict people’s be-
The direct cost of providing you with your own personal introductory economics havior, a good place to
course might easily top $50,000. Someone has to pay these costs. In private universi- start is by examining
ties, a large share of the cost would be recovered directly from higher tuition pay- their incentives.
ments. In state universities, the burden would be split between higher tuition
payments and higher tax payments. But, in either case, the course would be unaf-
fordable for most students.
With larger classes, of course, the cost per student goes down. For example, an
introductory economics course with 300 students might cost as little as $200 per stu-
dent. But a class that large could easily compromise the quality of the learning envi-
ronment. Compared to the custom tutorial format, however, it would be dramatically
more affordable.
In choosing what size introductory economics course to offer, then, university
administrators confront a classic economic trade-off. In making the class larger, they
risk lowering the quality of instruction—a bad thing. At the same time, they reduce
costs and hence the tuition students must pay—a good thing.

1
2 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

In this chapter, we’ll introduce some simple ideas that will help you understand
and explain patterns of behavior you observe in the world around you. These princi-
ples also will help you avoid three pitfalls that plague decision makers in everyday
life.

ECONOMICS: STUDYING CHOICE


IN A WORLD OF SCARCITY
Even in rich societies like the United States, scarcity is a fundamental fact of life.
There is never enough time, money, or energy to do everything we want to do or
have everything we’d like to have. Economics is the study of how people make
choices under conditions of scarcity and of the results of those choices for society.
In the class-size example just discussed, a motivated economics student might
definitely prefer to be in a class of 20 rather than a class of 100, everything else be-
ing equal. But other things, of course, are not equal. Students can enjoy the bene-
fits of having smaller classes, but only at the price of having less money for other
activities. The student’s choice inevitably will come down to the relative impor-
tance of competing activities.
That such trade-offs are widespread and important is one of the core principles
of economics. Although we have boundless needs and wants, the resources available
to us are limited. So having more of one good thing usually means having less of
­another.
Inherent in the idea of a trade-off is the fact that choice involves compromise
Are small classes “better” than between competing interests. Economists resolve such trade-offs by using cost-­
large ones? benefit analysis, which is based on the disarmingly simple principle that an action
should be taken if, and only if, its benefits exceed its costs. We call this statement the
economics the study of how Cost-Benefit Principle, a core principle of economics.
people make choices under With this principle in mind, let’s think about our class-size question again.
conditions of scarcity and of Imagine that classrooms come in only two sizes—100-seat lecture halls and 20-seat
the results of those choices classrooms—and that your university currently offers introductory economics courses
for society to classes of 100 students. Question: Should administrators reduce the class size to 20
students? Answer: Reduce if, and only if, the value of the improvement in instruction
outweighs its additional cost.
This rule sounds simple. But to apply it we need some way to measure the
relevant costs and benefits, a task that’s often difficult in practice. If we make a
few simplifying assumptions, however, we can see how the analysis might work.
On the cost side, the primary expense of reducing class size from 100 to 20 is
that we’ll now need five professors instead of just one. We’ll also need five
smaller classrooms rather than a single big one, and this too may add slightly to
the expense of the move. Let’s suppose that classes with 20 cost $1,000 per stu-
dent more than those with 100. Should administrators switch to the smaller
class size? If they apply the Cost-Benefit Principle, they will realize that doing so
makes sense only if the value of attending the smaller class is at least $1,000 per stu-
dent greater than the value of attending the larger class.
Would you (or your family) be willing to pay an extra $1,000 for a smaller class?
If not, and if other students feel the same way, then sticking with the larger class size
makes sense. But if you and others would be willing to pay the extra tuition, then
reducing the class size makes good economic sense.
Notice that the “best” class size, from an economic point of view, will generally not be
the same as the “best” size from the point of view of an educational psychologist. That’s
because the economic definition of “best” takes into account both the benefits and
the costs of different class sizes. The psychologist ignores costs and looks only at the
learning benefits of different class sizes.
In practice, of course, different people feel differently about the value of
smaller classes. People with high incomes, for example, tend to be willing to pay
more for the advantage. That helps explain why average class size is smaller, and
APPLYING THE COST-BENEFIT PRINCIPLE 3

tuition higher, at private schools whose students come predominantly from


high-income families.
The cost-benefit framework for thinking about the class-size problem also sug-

Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images


gests a possible reason for the gradual increase in average class size that has been
taking place in American colleges and universities. During the last 30 years, profes-
sors’ salaries have risen sharply, making smaller classes more costly. During the
same period, median family income—and hence the willingness to pay for smaller
classes—has remained roughly constant. When the cost of offering smaller classes
goes up but willingness to pay for smaller classes does not, universities shift to
larger class sizes.
Scarcity and the trade-offs that result also apply to resources other than If Jeff Bezos saw a $100 bill lying
money. Jeff Bezos is one of the richest people on Earth. His wealth is estimated at on the sidewalk, would it be worth
his time to pick it up?
more than $180 billion. That’s more than the combined wealth of the poorest
54 percent of Americans. Bezos could buy more houses, cars, vacations, and
other consumer goods than he could possibly use. Yet he, like the rest of us, has
only 24 hours each day and a limited amount of energy. So even he confronts
trade-offs. Any activity he pursues—whether it be building his business empire or
redecorating his mansion—uses up time and energy that he could otherwise
spend on other things. Indeed, someone once calculated that the value of Bezos’s
time is so great that pausing to pick up a $100 bill from the sidewalk simply
wouldn’t be worth his while.

APPLYING THE COST-BENEFIT PRINCIPLE


In studying choice under scarcity, we’ll usually begin with the premise that people
are rational, which means they have well-defined goals and try to fulfill them as best rational person someone
they can. The Cost-Benefit Principle is a fundamental tool for the study of how ratio- with well-defined goals who
nal people make choices. tries to fulfill those goals as
As in the class-size example, often the only real difficulty in applying the cost-­ best he or she can
benefit rule is to come up with reasonable measures of the relevant benefits and
costs. Only in rare instances will exact dollar measures be conveniently available.
But the cost-benefit framework can lend structure to your thinking even when no
relevant market data are available.
To illustrate how we proceed in such cases, the following example asks you to
decide whether to perform an action whose cost is described only in vague, qualita-
tive terms.

EXAMPLE 1.1 Comparing Costs and Benefits

Should you walk downtown to save $10 on a $25 wireless keyboard?


Imagine you are about to buy a $25 wireless keyboard at the nearby campus
store when a friend tells you that the same keyboard is on sale at a downtown
store for only $15. If the downtown store is a 30-minute walk away, where should
you buy the keyboard?
The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that you should buy it downtown if the
­ enefit of doing so exceeds the cost. The benefit of taking any action is the dol-
b
lar value of everything you gain by taking it. Here, the benefit of buying down-
town is exactly $10, because that’s the amount you’ll save on the price of the
keyboard. The cost of taking any action is the dollar value of everything you
give up by taking it. Here, the cost of buying downtown is the dollar value you
assign to the time and trouble it takes to make the trip. But how do we estimate
that value?
4 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

One way is to perform the following hypothetical auction. Imagine that a


stranger has offered to pay you to do an errand that involves the same walk
downtown (perhaps to drop off a package for her at the post office). If she offered
you a payment of, say, $1,000, would you accept? If so, we know that your cost of
walking downtown and back must be less than $1,000. Now imagine her offer
being reduced in small increments until you finally refuse the last offer. For ex-
ample, if you’d agree to walk downtown and back for $9 but not for $8.99, then
your cost of making the trip is $9. In this case, you should buy the keyboard
downtown because the $10 you’ll save (your benefit) is greater than your $9 cost
of making the trip.
But suppose your cost of making the trip had been greater than $10. In that
case, your best bet would have been to buy the keyboard from the nearby cam-
pus store. Confronted with this choice, different people may choose differently,
depending on how costly they think it is to make the trip downtown. But although
there is no uniquely correct choice, most people who are asked what they would
do in this situation say they would buy the keyboard downtown.

Economic Surplus
Suppose that in Example 1.1 your “cost” of making the trip downtown was $9. Com-
pared to the alternative of buying the keyboard at the campus store, buying it down-
economic surplus the town resulted in an economic surplus of $1, the difference between the benefit of
benefit of taking an action making the trip and its cost. In general, your goal as an economic decision maker is
minus its cost to choose those actions that generate the largest possible economic surplus. This
means taking all actions that yield a positive total economic surplus, which is just an-
other way of restating the Cost-­Benefit Principle.
Note that the fact that your best choice was to buy the keyboard downtown doesn’t
imply that you enjoy making the trip, any more than choosing a large class means that
you prefer large classes to small ones. It simply means that the trip is less unpleasant
than the prospect of paying $10 extra for the keyboard. Once again, you’ve faced a
trade-off. In this case, the choice was between a cheaper keyboard and the free time
gained by avoiding the trip.

Opportunity Cost
Of course, your mental auction could have produced a different outcome. Suppose,
for example, that the time required for the trip is the only time you have left to study
for a difficult test the next day. Or suppose you are watching one of your favorite
shows on Netflix, or that you are tired and would love a short nap. In such cases, we
opportunity cost the value say that the opportunity cost of making the trip—that is, the value of what you must
of what must be forgone to sacrifice to walk downtown and back—is high and you are more likely to decide
undertake an activity against making the trip.
Strictly speaking, your opportunity cost of engaging in an activity is the value of ev-
erything you must sacrifice to engage in it. For instance, if seeing a movie requires not
only that you buy a $10 ticket, but also that you give up a $20 dogwalking job that you
would have been willing to do for free, then the opportunity cost of seeing the film is $30.
Under this definition, all costs—both implicit and explicit—are opportunity costs.
Unless otherwise stated, we will adhere to this strict definition.
We must warn you, however, that some economists use the term opportunity cost
to refer only to the implicit value of opportunities forgone. Thus, in the example just
discussed, these economists wouldn’t include the $10 ticket price when calculating
the opportunity cost of seeing the film. But virtually all economists would agree that
your opportunity cost of not doing the dogwalking job is $20.
APPLYING THE COST-BENEFIT PRINCIPLE 5

In the previous example, if watching another hour of your favorite show on


­ etflix is the most valuable opportunity that conflicts with the trip downtown, the
N
opportunity cost of making the trip is the dollar value you place on pursuing that
­opportunity. It is the largest amount you’d be willing to pay to avoid watching your
show at another time. Note that the opportunity cost of making the trip is not the
combined value of all possible activities you could have pursued, but only the value
of your best alternative—the one you would have chosen had you not made the trip.
Throughout the text we’ll pose self-tests like the one that follows. You’ll find
that pausing to answer them will help you master key concepts in economics. Be-
cause doing these self-tests isn’t very costly (indeed, many students report that
they’re actually fun), the Cost-Benefit Principle indicates that it’s well worth your
while to do them.

SELF-TEST 1.1
You would again save $10 by buying the wireless keyboard downtown rather
than at the campus store, but your cost of making the trip is now $12, not $9. By
how much would your economic surplus be smaller if you bought the keyboard
downtown rather than at the campus store?

The Role of Economic Models


Economists use the Cost-Benefit Principle as an abstract model of how an idealized
rational individual would choose among competing alternatives. (By “abstract model”
we mean a simplified description that captures the essential elements of a situation
and allows us to analyze them in a logical way.) A computer model of a complex phe-
nomenon like climate change, which must ignore many details and includes only the
major forces at work, is an example of an abstract model.
Noneconomists are sometimes harshly critical of the economist’s cost-benefit
model on the grounds that people in the real world never conduct hypothetical men-
tal auctions before deciding whether to make trips downtown. But this criticism be-
trays a fundamental misunderstanding of how abstract models can help explain and
predict human behavior. Economists know perfectly well that people don’t conduct
hypothetical mental auctions when they make simple decisions. All the Cost-Benefit
Principle really says is that a rational decision is one that is explicitly or implicitly
based on a weighing of costs and benefits.
Most of us make sensible decisions most of the time, without being consciously
aware that we are weighing costs and benefits, just as most people ride a bike with-
out being consciously aware of what keeps them from falling. Through trial and er-
ror, we gradually learn what kinds of choices tend to work best in different contexts,
just as bicycle riders internalize the relevant laws of physics, usually without being
conscious of them.
Even so, learning the explicit principles of cost-benefit analysis can help us
make better decisions, just as knowing about physics can help in learning to ride a
bicycle. For instance, when a young economist was teaching his oldest son to ride a
bike, he followed the time-honored tradition of running alongside the bike and
holding onto his son, then giving him a push and hoping for the best. After several
hours and painfully skinned elbows and knees, his son finally got it. A year later,
someone pointed out that the trick to riding a bike is to turn slightly in whichever
direction the bike is leaning. Of course! The economist passed this information
along to his second son, who learned to ride almost instantly. Just as knowing a little
physics can help you learn to ride a bike, knowing a little economics can help you
make better decisions.
6 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

RECAP
COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS
Scarcity is a basic fact of economic life. Because of it, having more of one
good thing almost always means having less of another. The Cost-Benefit
Principle holds that an individual (or a firm or a society) should take an action
if, and only if, the extra benefit from taking the action is at least as great as
the extra cost. The benefit of taking any action minus the cost of taking the
action is called the economic surplus from that action. Hence, the Cost-­
Benefit Principle suggests that we take only those actions that create addi-
tional economic surplus.

THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS1


Rational people will apply the Cost-Benefit Principle most of the time, although
probably in an intuitive and approximate way, rather than through explicit and
precise calculation. Knowing that rational people tend to compare costs and bene-
fits enables economists to predict their likely behavior. As noted earlier, for exam-
ple, we can predict that students from wealthy families are more likely than others
to attend colleges that offer small classes. (Again, while the cost of small classes is
the same for all families, their benefit, as measured by what people are willing to
pay for them, tends to be higher for wealthier families.)
Yet researchers have identified situations in which people tend to apply the Cost-­
Benefit Principle inconsistently. In these situations, the Cost-Benefit Principle may
not predict behavior accurately. But it proves helpful in another way, by identifying
specific strategies for avoiding bad decisions.

Pitfall 1: Measuring Costs and Benefits as Proportions


Rather Than Absolute Dollar Amounts
As the next example makes clear, even people who seem to know they should weigh
the pros and cons of the actions they are contemplating sometimes don’t have a clear
sense of how to measure the relevant costs and benefits.

EXAM PLE 1.2 Comparing Costs and Benefits

Should you walk downtown to save $10 on a $2,020 laptop


computer?
You are about to buy a $2,020 laptop computer at the nearby campus store when
a friend tells you that the same computer is on sale at a downtown store for only
$2,010. If the downtown store is half an hour’s walk away, where should you buy
the computer?
Assuming that the laptop is light enough to carry without effort, the ­structure
of this example is exactly the same as that of Example 1.1. The only difference is
that the price of the laptop is dramatically higher than the price of the wireless
keyboard. As before, the benefit of buying downtown is the dollar amount you’ll
save, namely, $10. And because it’s exactly the same trip, its cost also must be the

1
The examples in this section are inspired by the pioneering research of Daniel Kahneman and the late
Amos Tversky. Kahneman was awarded the 2002 Nobel Prize in Economics for his efforts to integrate in-
sights from psychology into economics. You can read more about this work in Kahneman’s brilliant 2011
book, Thinking Fast and Slow (New York: Macmillan).
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS 7

same as before. So if you are perfectly rational, you should make the same deci-
sion in both cases. Yet when people are asked what they would do in these situa-
tions, the overwhelming majority say they’d walk downtown to buy the keyboard
but would buy the laptop at the campus store. When asked to explain, most of
them say something like, “The trip was worth it for the keyboard because you
save 40 percent, but not worth it for the laptop because you save only $10 out of
$2,020.”
This is faulty reasoning. The benefit of the trip downtown is not the proportion
you save on the original price. Rather, it is the absolute dollar amount you save.
The benefit of walking downtown to buy the laptop is $10, exactly the same as for
the wireless keyboard. And because the cost of the trip must also be the same in
both cases, the economic surplus from making both trips must be exactly the
same. That means that a rational decision maker would make the same decision
in both cases. Yet, as noted, most people choose differently.

The pattern of faulty reasoning in the decision just discussed is one of several
decision pitfalls to which people are often prone. In the discussion that follows, we
will identify two additional decision pitfalls. In some cases, people ignore costs or
benefits that they ought to take into account. On other occasions they are influenced
by costs or benefits that are irrelevant.

SELF-TEST 1.2
Which is more valuable: saving $100 on a $2,000 plane ticket to Tokyo or saving
$90 on a $200 plane ticket to Chicago?

Pitfall 2: Ignoring Implicit Costs


Sherlock Holmes, Arthur Conan Doyle’s legendary detective, was successful be-
cause he saw details that most others overlooked. In Silver Blaze, Holmes is called
on to investigate the theft of an expensive racehorse from its stable. A Scotland
Yard inspector assigned to the case asks Holmes whether some particular aspect
of the crime requires further study. “Yes,” Holmes replies, and describes “the curi-
ous incident of the dog in the nighttime.” “The dog did nothing in the nighttime,”2
responds the puzzled inspector. But, as Holmes realized, that was precisely the
problem! The watchdog’s failure to bark when Silver Blaze was stolen meant that
the watchdog knew the thief. This clue ultimately proved the key to unraveling the
mystery.
Just as we often don’t notice when a dog fails to bark, many of us tend to over-
look the implicit value of activities that fail to happen. As discussed earlier, however,
intelligent decisions require taking the value of forgone opportunities properly into
account.
The opportunity cost of an activity, once again, is the value of all that must be
forgone in order to engage in that activity. If buying a wireless keyboard downtown
means not watching another hour of your favorite show on Netflix, then the value to
you of watching the show is an implicit cost of the trip. Many people make bad deci-
sions because they tend to ignore the value of such forgone opportunities. To avoid
overlooking implicit costs, economists often translate questions like “Should I walk
downtown?” into ones like “Should I walk downtown or watch another hour of my
favorite show?” Implicit costs are like dogs
that fail to bark in the night.
2
Arthur Conan Doyle, “The Adventure of Silver Blaze,” The Memoirs of Sherlock Holmes (London: George Many of us tend to overlook
Newnes Ltd., 1893). activities that fail to happen.
8 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

EXAM PLE 1.3 Implicit Cost

Should you use your frequent-flyer coupon to fly to Cancun for spring
break?
With spring break only a week away, you are still undecided about whether to go
to Cancun with a group of classmates at the University of Iowa. The round-trip
airfare from Cedar Rapids is $500, but you have a frequent-flyer coupon you could
use for the trip. All other relevant costs for the vacation week at the beach total
exactly $1,000. The most you would be willing to pay for the Cancun vacation is
$1,350. That amount is your benefit of taking the vacation. Your only alternative
use for your frequent-flyer coupon is for a trip to Boston the weekend after spring
break to attend your brother’s wedding. (Your coupon expires shortly thereafter.) If
the Cedar Rapids–Boston round-trip airfare is $400, should you use your
­frequent-flyer coupon to fly to Cancun for spring break?
The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that you should go to Cancun if the benefits
of the trip exceed its costs. If not for the complication of the frequent-flyer coupon,
solving this problem would be a straightforward matter of comparing
your benefit from the week at the beach to the sum of all relevant costs.
And because your airfare and other costs would add up to $1,500, or
$150 more than your benefit from the trip, you would not go to Cancun.
But what about the possibility of using your frequent-flyer coupon
to make the trip? Using it for that purpose might make the flight to Can-
Bkindler/E+/Getty Images

cun seem free, suggesting you’d reap an economic surplus of $350 by


making the trip. But doing so also would mean you’d have to fork over
$400 for your airfare to Boston. So the implicit cost of using your cou-
pon to go to Cancun is really $400. If you use it for that purpose, the
trip still ends up being a loser because the cost of the vacation, $1,400,
Is your flight to Cancun “free” exceeds the benefit by $50. In cases like these, you’re much more
if you travel on a frequent-flyer likely to decide sensibly if you ask yourself, “Should I use my frequent-
coupon? flyer coupon for this trip or save it for an upcoming trip?”

We cannot emphasize strongly enough that the key to using the Cost-Benefit
Principle correctly lies in recognizing precisely what taking a given action pre-
vents us from doing. Self-Test 1.3 illustrates this point by modifying the details of
Example 1.3 slightly.

SELF-TEST 1.3
Refer to given information in Example 1.3, but this time your frequent-flyer cou-
pon expires in a week, so your only chance to use it will be for the ­Cancun trip.
Should you use your coupon?

Pitfall 3: Failing to Think at the Margin


When deciding whether to take an action, the only relevant costs and benefits are
those that would occur as a result of taking the action. Sometimes people are influ-
enced by costs they ought to ignore. Other times they compare the wrong costs and
benefits. The only costs that should influence a decision about whether to take an action are
those we can avoid by not taking the action. Similarly, the only benefits we should consider
are those that would not occur unless the action were taken. As a practical matter, how-
ever, many decision makers appear to be influenced by costs or benefits that would
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS 9

have occurred no matter what. Thus, people are often influenced by sunk costs—costs sunk cost a cost that is
that are beyond recovery at the moment a decision is made. For example, money spent beyond recovery at the
on a nontransferable, nonrefundable airline ticket is a sunk cost. moment a decision must
As the following example illustrates, sunk costs must be borne whether or not an be made
action is taken, so they are irrelevant to the decision of whether to take the action.

EXAMPLE 1. 4 Sunk Cost

How much should you eat at an all-you-can-eat restaurant?


Sangam, an Indian restaurant in Philadelphia, offers an all-you-can-eat lunch b ­ uffet
for $10. Customers pay $10 at the door, and no matter how many times they refill
their plates, there is no additional charge. One day, as a goodwill gesture, the
owner of the restaurant tells 20 randomly selected guests that they can eat at the
all-you-can-eat buffet for free. The remaining guests pay the usual price. If all diners
are rational, will those who are able to eat at the buffet for free consume a different
amount of food, on average, than those who have to pay $10 for the buffet?
Having eaten their first helping, diners in each group confront the following
question: “Should I go back for another helping?” For rational diners, if the benefit of
doing so exceeds the cost, the answer is yes; otherwise it is no. Note that at the mo-
ment of decision, the $10 charge for the lunch is a sunk cost. Those who paid it have
no way to recover it. Thus, for both groups, the (extra) cost of another helping is
exactly zero. And because the people who received the free lunch were chosen at
random, there’s no reason their appetites or incomes should be any different from
those of other diners. The benefit of another helping thus should be the same, on
average, for people in both groups. And because their respective costs and benefits
are the same, the two groups should eat the same number of helpings, on average.
Psychologists and economists have experimental evidence, however, that
people in such groups do not eat similar amounts.3 In particular, those who have
to pay for the all-you-can-eat buffet tend to eat substantially more than those for
whom the buffet is free. People in the former group somehow seem determined to
“get their money’s worth.” Their implicit goal is apparently to minimize the average
cost per bite of the food they eat. Yet minimizing average cost is not a particularly
sensible objective. The irony is that diners who are determined to get their mon-
ey’s worth usually end up eating too much.

The fact that the cost-benefit criterion failed the test of prediction in Example 1.4
does nothing to invalidate its advice about what people should do. If you are letting
sunk costs influence your decisions, you can do better by changing your behavior.
In addition to paying attention to costs and benefits that should be ignored, peo-
ple often use incorrect measures of the relevant costs and benefits. This error often
occurs when we must choose the extent to which an activity should be pursued (as
opposed to choosing whether to pursue it at all). We can apply the Cost-Benefit Prin-
marginal cost the increase in
ciple in such situations by repeatedly asking the question, “Should I increase the
total cost that results from
level at which I am currently pursuing the activity?”
carrying out one additional
In attempting to answer this question, the focus should always be on the benefit
unit of an activity
and cost of an additional unit of activity. To emphasize this focus, economists refer to
the cost of an additional unit of activity as its marginal cost. Similarly, the benefit of marginal benefit the
an additional unit of the activity is its marginal benefit. increase in total benefit that
When the problem is to discover the proper level for an activity, the cost-benefit results from carrying out one
rule is to keep increasing the level as long as the marginal benefit of the activity additional unit of an activity

3
See, for example, Richard Thaler, “Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice,” Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization 1, no. 1 (1980).
10 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

exceeds its marginal cost. As the following example illustrates, however, people often
fail to apply this rule correctly.

EXAM PLE 1.5 Focusing on Marginal Costs and Benefits

Should SpaceX expand its launch program from four launches per
year to five?
SpaceX accountants have estimated that the gains from the company’s jumbo
rocket launch program are currently $24 billion a year (an average of $6 billion
per launch) and that its costs are currently $20 billion a year (an average $5 bil-
lion per launch). On the basis of these estimates, they have recommended that
the company increase its number of launches. Should SpaceX CEO Elon Musk
follow their advice?
To discover whether the advice makes economic sense, we must compare
the marginal cost of a launch to its marginal benefit. The accountants’ estimates,
average cost the total cost of however, tell us only the average cost and average benefit of the program. These
undertaking n units of an are, respectively, the total cost of the program divided by the number of launches
activity divided by n and the total benefit divided by the number of launches.
Knowing the average benefit and average cost per launch for all rockets
average benefit the total
launched thus far is simply not useful for deciding whether to expand the pro-
benefit of undertaking n units
gram. Of course, the average cost of the launches undertaken so far might be the
of an activity divided by n
same as the cost of adding another launch. But it also might be either higher or
lower than the marginal cost of a launch. The same holds true regarding average
and marginal benefits.
Suppose, for the sake of discussion, that the benefit of an additional launch is in
fact the same as the average benefit per launch thus far, $6 billion. Should SpaceX
add another launch? Not if the cost of adding the fifth launch would be more than $6
billion. And the fact that the average cost per launch is only $5 billion simply does
not tell us anything about the marginal cost of the fifth launch.
Suppose, for example, that the relationship between the number of rockets
launched and the total cost of the program is as described in Table 1.1. The aver-
age cost per launch (third column) when there are four launches would then be
$20 billion/4 = $5 billion per launch, just as the accountants reported. But note in
the second column of the table that adding a fifth launch would raise costs from
$20 billion to $32 billion, making the marginal cost of the fifth launch
$12 billion. So if the benefit of an additional launch is $6 billion, increasing the
number of launches from four to five would make absolutely no economic sense.

TABLE 1.1
How Total Cost Varies with the Number of Launches

Number of Total cost Average cost


launches ($ billions) ($ billion/launch)
0 0 0
1 3 3
2 7 3.5
3 12 4
4 20 5
5 32 6.4
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS 11

The following example illustrates how to apply the Cost-Benefit Principle correctly
in this case.

EX AMPLE 1.6 Focusing on Marginal Costs and Benefits

How many rockets should SpaceX launch?


SpaceX must decide how many rockets to launch. The benefit of each launch is
­estimated to be $6 billion, and the total cost of the program again depends on the
number of launches as shown in Table 1.1. How many rockets should SpaceX launch?
SpaceX should continue to launch its jumbo rockets as long as the marginal
benefit of the program exceeds its marginal cost. In this example, the marginal
benefit is constant at $6 billion per launch, regardless of the number of rockets
launched. SpaceX should thus keep launching rockets as long as the marginal
cost per launch is less than or equal to $6 billion.
Applying the definition of marginal cost to the total cost entries in the second
column of Table 1.1 yields the marginal cost values in the third column of Table 1.2.
(Because marginal cost is the change in total cost that results when we change
the number of launches by one, we place each marginal cost entry midway be-
tween the rows showing the corresponding total cost entries.) Thus, for example,
the marginal cost of increasing the number of launches from one to two is $4 bil-
lion, the difference between the $7 billion total cost of two launches and the
$3 billion total cost of one launch.

TABLE 1.2
How Marginal Cost Varies with the Number of Launches
Number of Total cost Marginal cost
launches ($ billions) ($ billion/launch)
0 0
3
1 3
4
2 7
5
3 12
8
4 20
12
5 32

As we see from a comparison of the $6 billion marginal benefit per launch


with the marginal cost entries in the third column of Table 1.2, the first three
launches satisfy the cost-benefit test, but the fourth and fifth launches do not.
SpaceX should thus launch three rockets.

SELF-TEST 1.4
If the marginal benefit of each launch had been not $6 billion but $9 billion,
how many rockets should SpaceX have launched?

The cost-benefit framework emphasizes that the only relevant costs and benefits
in deciding whether to pursue an activity further are marginal costs and benefits—­
measures that correspond to the increment of activity under consideration. In many
12 CHAPTER 1 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

contexts, ­however, people seem more inclined to compare the average cost and benefit
of the activity. As Example 1.5 made clear, increasing the level of an activity may not
be justified, even though its average benefit at the current level is significantly greater
than its average cost.

SELF-TEST 1.5
Should a basketball team’s best player take all the team’s shots?
A professional basketball team has a new assistant coach. The assistant
notices that one player scores on a higher percentage of her shots than other
players. Based on this information, the assistant suggests to the head coach
that the star player take all the shots. That way, the assistant reasons, the team
will score more points and win more games.
On hearing this suggestion, the head coach fires her assistant for incompe-
tence. What was wrong with the assistant’s idea?

RECAP
THREE IMPORTANT DECISION PITFALLS
1. The pitfall of measuring costs or benefits proportionally. Many decision
makers treat a change in cost or benefit as insignificant if it constitutes
only a small proportion of the original amount. Absolute dollar amounts,
not proportions, should be employed to measure costs and benefits.
2. The pitfall of ignoring implicit costs. When performing a cost-benefit
analysis of an action, it is important to account for all relevant costs, in-
cluding the implicit value of alternatives that must be forgone in order to
carry out the action. A resource (such as a frequent-flyer coupon) may
have a high implicit cost, even if you originally got it “for free,” if its best
alternative use has high value. The identical resource may have a low
implicit cost, however, if it has no good alternative uses.
3. The pitfall of failing to think at the margin. When deciding whether to
perform an action, the only costs and benefits that are relevant are those
that would result from taking the action. It is important to ignore sunk
costs—those costs that cannot be avoided even if the action isn’t taken.
Even though a ticket to a concert may have cost you $100, if you’ve al-
ready bought it and cannot sell it to anyone else, the $100 is a sunk cost
and shouldn’t influence your decision about whether to go to the concert.
It’s also important not to confuse average costs and benefits with mar-
ginal costs and benefits. Decision makers often have ready information
about the total cost and benefit of an activity, and from these it’s simple to
compute the activity’s average cost and benefit. A common mistake is to
conclude that an activity should be increased if its average benefit ex-
ceeds its average cost. The Cost-Benefit Principle tells us that the level of
an activity should be increased if, and only if, its marginal benefit exceeds
its marginal cost.

Some costs and benefits, especially marginal costs and benefits and implicit
costs, are important for decision making, while others, like sunk costs and average
costs and benefits, are essentially irrelevant. This conclusion is implicit in our orig-
inal statement of the Cost-Benefit Principle (an action should be taken if, and only
if, the extra benefits of taking it exceed the extra costs).
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
The Project Gutenberg eBook of An introduction
to the study of fishes
This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this ebook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.

Title: An introduction to the study of fishes

Author: Albert C. L. G. Günther

Release date: November 7, 2023 [eBook #72060]

Language: English

Original publication: Edinburgh: Adam and Charles Black, 1880

Credits: Peter Becker, Karin Spence and the Online Distributed


Proofreading Team at https://www.pgdp.net (This file
was produced from images generously made available
by The Internet Archive)

*** START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK AN


INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF FISHES ***
AN INTRODUCTION
TO THE

STUDY OF FISHES
BY

ALBERT C. L. G. GÜNTHER
M.A. M.D. Ph.D. F.R.S.
KEEPER OF THE ZOOLOGICAL DEPARTMENT IN THE BRITISH MUSEUM

Carpit aquas pinnis.

EDINBURGH
ADAM AND CHARLES BLACK
1880

[All rights reserved.]


Printed by R. & R. Clark, Edinburgh.
PREFACE.

The scope of the present work is to give in a concise form an


account of the principal facts relating to the structure, classification,
and life-history of Fishes. It is intended to meet the requirements of
those who are desirous of studying the elements of Ichthyology; to
serve as a book of reference to zoologists generally; and, finally, to
supply those who, like travellers, have frequent opportunities of
observing fishes, with a ready means of obtaining information. The
article on “Ichthyology,” prepared by the late Sir J. Richardson for the
eighth edition of the “Encyclopædia Britannica,” is the only
publication which has hitherto partly satisfied such requirements; and
when I undertook, some years ago, to revise, or rather rewrite that
article for the new edition of that work, it occurred to me that I might
at the same time prepare a Handbook of Ichthyology, whilst
reserving for the article an abstract so condensed as to be adapted
for the wants of the general reader.
From the general plan of the work I have only departed in those
chapters which deal with the Geographical Distribution of Fishes.
This is a subject which has never before been treated in a general
and comprehensive manner, and seemed to demand particular
attention. I have, therefore, thought it right to give nominal lists of the
Faunæ, and the other details of fact on which I have based my
conclusions, although all the necessary materials may be found in
my “Catalogue of Fishes.”
A few references only to the numerous sources which were
consulted on the subjects of Chapters 1–12, are inserted in the text;
more not required by the beginner; he is introduced to a merely
elementary knowledge of facts well known to the advanced student.
With regard to the illustrations, about twenty have been prepared
after originals published by Cuvier, J. Müller, Owen, Traquair,
Duméril, Cunningham, Hasse, Poey, Siebold, and Gegenbaur. A
similar number, representing extinct fishes, have been taken, with
the kind permission of the author, from Owen’s “Palæontology.” My
best thanks are due also to the Committee of Publications of the
Zoological Society, and to the Editors of the “Annals and Magazine
of Natural History,” and of the “Journal des Museum Godeffroy,” for
the loan of woodcuts illustrating some of my papers on South
American fishes and on larval forms. The remainder of the
illustrations (about three-fourths) are either original figures, or formed
part of the article on ‘Ichthyology’ in the former edition of the
“Encyclopædia Britannica.”
London, 3d October 1880.
CONTENTS.

INTRODUCTORY REMARKS.
PAGE
Fish defined—Ichthyology defined 1

CHAPTER I.
History and Literature 2
Aristotle, 2—Belon, 4—Salviani, 6—Rondelet, 6—Faunists and
Anatomists of the Seventeenth Century, 7—Ray and Willughby, 8—
Artedi, 9—Linnæus, 10—Gronow and Klein, 12—Pupils and
Successors of Linnæus, 12—Bloch, 13—Lacépède, 15—Anatomists
and Faunists preceding Cuvier, 16—Cuvier, 17—Agassiz, 20—J.
Müller, 22—Discovery of Ceratodus, 25—Recent publications on
Fishes, 26—Latest systematic works, 33.

CHAPTER II.
Topographical description of the External Parts of Fishes 35
Form of the body, 35—External parts of the head, 36—Trunk and Tail, 39
—Fins; their structure, position, and function, 40—Skin and Scales, 45.

CHAPTER III.
Terminology and Topography of the Skeleton 51
Axial portion, 51—Vertebra and its parts; terms defined, 51—Skull; bones
topographically enumerated, 53—Bones of the limbs, 59—Synonymic
list of bones, 59.

CHAPTER IV.
Modifications of the Skeleton 63
Branchiostoma, 63—Cyclostomes, 64—Chondropterygians, 66—
Holocephali, 70—Ganoids, 71—Dipnoi, 71—Chondrostei, 74—
Polypteroidei, 77—Lepidosteoidei, 80—Amioidei, 82—Teleostei, 83—
Classification of the bones of the Teleosteous skull according to the
vertebral doctrine, 85—their morphological classification, 86—Limb-
bones of Teleosteans, 92.

CHAPTER V.
Myology 93
General arrangement of the Muscles, 93—Electric organs, 94.

CHAPTER VI.
Neurology 96
Of Branchiostoma, 96—Spinal chord, 96—Brain, its size, 97—Brain of
Osseous fishes, 97—of Ganoids, 98—of Chondropterygians, 100—of
Cyclostomes, 101—Spino-cerebral nerves, 103—Spinal nerves, 107—
Sympathic system, 108.

CHAPTER VII.
The Organs of Sense 109
Smell, 109—Sight, 111—Hearing; connection of the ear with the air-
bladder, 116—Taste, 119—Touch, 120.

CHAPTER VIII.
The Organs of Nutrition and Digestion 121
Food and mode of feeding, 121—Buccal and abdominal cavities and their
openings, 123—Mouth and tongue, 123—Forms, texture, and
arrangement of teeth, 124—Intestinal tract, 127—Liver, 132—
Pancreas, 133—Spleen, 133.

CHAPTER IX.
Organs of Respiration 135
Respiration, 135—Structure and arrangement of the gills, 136—
Pseudobranchiæ, 140—Accessory respiratory organs, 142—Air-
bladder; its varieties, structure, and functions, 142.

CHAPTER X.
Organs of Circulation 150

CHAPTER XI.
Urinary Organs 155

CHAPTER XII.
Organs of Reproduction 157
Fishes are dioecious, 157—Hermaphroditism, 157—Oviparous and
viviparous fishes, 157—Generative organs of Branchiostoma, 157—of
Cyclostomes; their ova, 158—Female organs of Teleosteans and their
ova, 158—Instances of females taking care of their progeny, 160—
Male organs of Teleosteans, 162—Instances of males taking care of
their progeny, 163—Generative organs of Ganoids, 163—of
Chondropterygians and their ova, 166.

CHAPTER XIII.
Growth and Variation of Fishes 170
Changes of form of the body or certain parts, normally accompanying
growth, 170—Changes dependent on sexual development, 176—
Secondary sexual differences, 176—Mixogamous, polygamous, and
monogamous fishes, 177—Hybridism as a cause of variation, 178—
Regular and irregular growth of fishes, 178—Leptocephali not a normal
state of development, 179—Changes of colour of the muscles and
external parts; chromatophors, 182—Albinism, 183.

CHAPTER XIV.
Domesticated and Acclimatised Fishes, etc. 185
Domesticated fishes, 185—Acclimatisation of fishes, 185—Artificial
impregnation of ova, 186—Tenacity of life, 186—Reproduction of lost
parts, 188—Hybernation, 188—Useful fishes, 189—Poisonous fishes,
189—Poison-organs, 190.

CHAPTER XV.
Distribution of Fishes in time 193
Oldest fish-remains, 193—Devonian fishes, 194—Carboniferous, 196—
Permian, 197—Triassic, 197—Liassic, 198—Oolitic, 199—Cretaceous,
199—Tertiary, 200—Post-pliocene, 201.

CHAPTER XVI.
The Distribution of existing Fishes over the Earth’s Surface.—
General Remarks 202
Freshwater-, Marine-, and Brackish-water Fishes, 202—Changes of the
habitat of numerous fishes, active, 203—or dependent on geological
changes, 204—Agencies operating upon the distribution of Freshwater
and Marine fishes, 205.

CHAPTER XVII.
The Distribution of Freshwater Fishes 208
List of Freshwater Fishes, 208—Continuous and interrupted range of
distribution, 209—The ways of dispersal of Freshwater fishes, 211—A
wide range of a type is not necessarily proof of its antiquity, 212—Each
fauna is composed of ancient, autochthont, and immigrant species, 213
—Division of the globe into zoological regions; freshwater fishes have
been spread in circumpolar zones, 215—Cyprinidæ and Siluridæ, most
important families in recognising the zoo-geographical regions, 216—
Division of the faunæ of Freshwater fishes, 217—I. Equatorial Zone,
218—Indian Region, 220—African Region, 227—Tropical American or
Neotropical Region, 233—Tropical Pacific Region, 238—II. Northern
Zone, 240—Europe-Asiatic or Palæarctic Region, 243—North
American or Nearctic Region, 246—III. Southern Zone, with
Tasmanian, New Zealand, and Fuegian Sub-regions, 248.

CHAPTER XVIII.
The Fishes of the Brackish Water 251

CHAPTER XIX.
The Distribution of Marine Fishes 255
Shore-fishes, Pelagic, and Deep-sea fishes, 255—List of Shore-fishes,
257—Oceanic areæ as determined by Shore-fishes, 259—Distribution
of Shore-fishes compared with that of Freshwater-fishes, 260—I. Arctic
Ocean, 261—II. Northern Temperate Zone, 262—Temperate North-
Atlantic, 262—with British, 263—Mediterranean, 264—and North
American districts, 266—Temperate North-Pacific, 268—with
Kamtschatkan, 269—Japanese, 270—and Californian districts, 271—
III. Equatorial Zone, 272—with Tropical Atlantic, 278—Indo-Pacific
Ocean, 278—and the Pacific Coasts of Tropical America, 279—IV.
Southern Temperate Zone, 281—with the Cape of Good Hope, 283—
South Australia and New Zealand, 283—Chile, 288—and Patagonia,
289—V. Antarctic Ocean, 289.

CHAPTER XX.
Distribution of Pelagic Fishes 292

CHAPTER XXI.
The Fishes of the Deep Sea 296
Deep-sea fishes a recent discovery, 296—Physical conditions affecting
these fishes, 297—Characteristics of Deep-sea fishes, 299—Their
vertical and horizontal distribution, 304—List of Deep-sea fishes, 305.
SYSTEMATIC AND DESCRIPTIVE PART.

First Sub-class—Palæichthyes.
PAGE
First Order—Chondropterygii 313
I. Plagiostomata 313
A. Selachoidei—Sharks 314
Families: Carchariidæ (Blue Shark, Tope, Hammerhead, Hound),
316—Lamnidæ (Porbeagle, Carcharodon, Fox-Shark, Basking-
Shark), 319—Rhinodontidæ, 323—Notidanidæ, 324—Scylliidæ
(Dog-fishes), 325— Hybodontidæ, 328—Cestraciontidæ (Port
Jackson Shark), 328—Spinacidæ (Spiny Dogs, Greenland
Shark), 330—Rhinidæ, 334—Pristiophoridæ, 335.
B. Batoidei—Rays 335
Families: Pristidæ (Saw-fishes), 336—Rhinobatidæ, 337—
Torpedinidæ (Electric Rays), 338—Rajidæ (Rays and Skates),
340—Trygonidæ (Sting Rays), 342—Myliobatidæ (Eagle Rays),
344.
II. Holocephala 348
Family: Chimæridæ, 348.
Second Order—Ganoidei 350
I. Placodermi 351
II. Acanthodini 355
III. Dipnoi 355
Families: Sirenidæ (Lepidosiren, Protopterus, Ceratodus), 355—
Ctenododipteridæ, 359—Phaneropleuridæ, 360.
IV. Chondrostei 360
Families: Acipenseridæ (Sturgeons), 360—Polyodontidæ, 362.
V. Polypteroidei 363
Families: Polypteridæ, 364—Saurodipteridæ, 365—
Coelacanthidæ, 365—Holoptychidæ, 365.
VI. Pycnodontoidei 366
Families: Pleurolepidæ, 366—Pycnodontidæ, 366.
VII. Lepidosteoidei 367
Families: Lepidosteidæ, 367—Sauridæ, 368—Stylodontidæ, 368
—Sphærodontidæ, 368—Aspidorhynchidæ, 369—
Palæoniscidæ, 369—Platysomidæ, 370.
VIII. Amioidei 370
Families: Caturidæ, 371—Leptolepidæ, 371—Amiidæ (Bow-fin),
371.
Second Sub-class—Teleostei.
First Order—Acanthopterygii 374
I. A. perciformes 374
Families: Percidæ (Freshwater-Perches, Bass, Sea-Perches,
Centrarchus), 375—Squamipinnes (Coral-Fishes), 397—
Mullidæ (Red-Mullets), 403—Sparidæ (Sea-breams), 405—
Hoplognathidæ, 410—Cirrhitidæ, 410—Scorpænidæ, 412—
Nandidæ, 418—Polycentridæ, 418—Teuthididæ, 418.
II. A. beryciformes 419
Family: Berycidæ, 420.
III. A. kurtiformes 424
Family: Kurtidæ, 424.
IV. A. polynemiformes 425
Family: Polynemidæ, 425.
V. A. sciæniformes 426
Family: Sciænidæ (Meagres), 426.
VI. A. xiphiiformes 431
Family: Xiphiidæ (Sword-fishes), 431.
VII. A. trichiuriformes 433
Families: Trichiuridæ (Scabbard-fishes, Hairtails), 433—
Palæorhynchidæ, 437.
VIII. A. cotto-scombriformes 438
Families: Acronuridæ (Surgeons), 438—Carangidæ (Horse-
Mackerels, Pilot-fish, Boar-fish), 440—Cyttidæ (John Dorey),
450—Stromateidæ, 452—Coryphænidæ (Dolphin, Sun-fish),
452—Nomeidæ, 455—Scombridæ (Mackerel, Tunny, Bonito,
Albacore, Sucking-fish), 456—Trachinidæ (Stare-gazer,
Weever, etc.), 462—Malacanthidæ, 467—Batrachidæ, 467—
Psychrolutidæ, 469—Pediculati (Angler, Antennarius, etc.), 469
—Cottidæ (Bull-heads, Gurnards), 476—Cataphracti (Flying
Gurnards), 480—Pegasidæ, 482.
IX. A. gobiiformes 483
Families: Discoboli (Lump-suckers), 483—Gobiidæ (Gobies,
Dragonets), 485.
X. A. blenniiformes 490
Families: Cepolidæ (Band-fishes), 490—Trichonotidæ, 490—
Heterolepidotidæ, 491—Blenniidæ (Wolf-fish, Blennies), 492—
Acanthoclinidæ, 498—Mastacembelidæ, 499.
XI. A. mugiliformes 499
Families: Sphyrænidæ (Barracudas), 499—Atherinidæ
(Atherines), 500—Mugilidæ (Mullets), 501.
XII. A. gastrosteiformes 504
Families: Gastrosteidæ (Sticklebacks), 504—Fistulariidæ (Flute-
mouths), 507.
XIII. A. centrisciformes 508
Family: Centriscidæ, 508.
XIV. A. gobiesociformes 510
Family: Gobiesocidæ, 512.
XV. A. channiformes 513
Family: Ophiocephalidæ, 513.
XVI. A. labyrinthibranchii 514
Families: Labyrinthici (Climbing Perch, Gourami), 514—
Luciocephalidæ, 519.
XVII. A. lophotiformes 519
Family: Lophotidæ, 519.
XVIII. A. tæniiformes 520
Family: Trachypteridæ (Ribbon-fishes), 520.
XIX. A. notacanthiformes 523
Family: Notacanthidæ, 523.
Second Order—Acanthopterygii Pharyngognathi 523
Families: Pomacentridæ (Coral-fishes), 524—Labridæ (Wrasses,
Parrot-wrasses), 525—Embiotocidæ, 533—Chromides, 534.
Third Order—Anacanthini 537
I. A. gadoidei 537
Families: Lycodidæ, 537—Gadidæ (Cod-fishes, Hake, Burbot,
Ling, Rockling, Torsk), 539—Ophidiidæ (Brotula, Fierasfer,
Sand-eel, Congrogadus), 546—Macruridæ, 551.
II. A. pleuronectoidei 553
Family: Pleuronectidæ (Flat-fishes), 553.
Fourth Order—Physostomi 559
Families: Siluridæ; their skeleton, 559—divided into eight subdivisions
and sixteen groups; Clariina, 563—Plotosina, 563—Silurina, 565—
Hypophthalmina, 566—Bagrina, 567—Amiurina, 567—Pimelodina, 568
—Ariina, 569—Doradina, 572—Rhinoglanina, 573—Malapterurina
(Electric Catfish), 574—Hypostomatina (Preñadillas, Loricaria, etc.),
575—Aspredinina, 580—Nematogenyina and Trichomycterina, 581—
Stegopholina, 581.
Families of Physostomi continued: Scopelidæ, 582—Cyprinidæ (Carps),
587—divided into fourteen groups, viz. Catostomina (Suckers), 588—
Cyprinina (Carp, Crucian Carp, Gold-fish, Barbels, Gudgeons), 589—
Rohteichthyina, 596—Leptobarbina, 597—Rasborina, 597—
Semiplotina, 598—Xenocypridina, 598—Leuciscina (White fish, Tench,
Dace, etc.), 598—Rhodeina, 601—Danionina, 601—
Hypophthalmichthyina, 602—Abramidina (Bream, Bleak), 602—
Homalopterina, 604—Cobitidina (Loaches), 604.
Families of Physostomi continued: Kneriidæ, 606—Characinidæ, 606—
Cyprinodontidæ, 613—Heteropygii (Blind Fish of the Mammoth Cave),
618—Umbridæ, 619—Scombresocidæ (Gar-pike, Saury, Half-beak,
Flying Fish), 619—Esocidæ (Pike), 623—Galaxiidæ, 624—Mormyridæ,
625—Sternoptychidæ, 627—Stomiatidæ, 629.
Families of Physostomi continued—Salmonidæ: Salmo, difficulty of
distinguishing species, 630; constant specific characters, 635—hybrids,
638—sexual development, 638—migratory species and their retention
in freshwater, 639—Growth of Salmonoids, 641—their domestication
and acclimatisation, 641—species enumerated, 642—Smelt and
Capelin, 646—Coregonus, 647—Grayling, 649—marine genera, 650.
Families of Physostomi continued: Percopsidæ, 651—Haplochitonidæ,
651—Gonorhynchidæ, 652—Hyodontidæ (Moon-eye), 653—
Pantodontidæ, 653—Osteoglossidæ, 653—Clupeidæ (Herrings,
Anchovies, Shads, Mossbanker, Menhaden, etc.), 655—
Bathythrissidæ, 663—Chirocentridæ, 663—Alepocephalidæ, 664—
Notopteridæ, 664—Halosauridæ, 665—Hoplopleuridæ, 665—
Gymnotidæ (Electric Eel), 666—Symbranchidæ, 668—Murænidæ
(Eels, Congers, Murænas, etc.), 669.
Fifth Order—Lophobranchii 678
Families: Solenostomidæ, 678—Syngnathidæ (Pipe-fishes, Sea-horses),
679.
Sixth Order—Plectognathi 683
Families: Sclerodermi (File-fishes, Coffer-fishes), 684—Gymnodontes
(Globe-fishes, Sun-fish), 686.
Third Sub-class—Cyclostomata.
Families: Petromyzontidæ (Lampreys), 691—Myxinidæ, 694.
Fourth Sub-class—Leptocardii.
Family: Cirrhostomi (Lancelets), 696.
APPENDIX.
Directions for Collecting and Preserving Fishes 697
Alphabetical Index 707
INTRODUCTORY REMARKS.

According to the views generally adopted at present, all those


Vertebrate animals are referred to the Class of Fishes, which living in
water, breathe air dissolved in water by means of gills or branchiæ;
whose heart consists of a single ventricle and single atrium; whose
limbs, if present, are modified into fins, supplemented by unpaired,
median fins; and whose skin is either naked, or covered with scales
or osseous plates or bucklers. With few exceptions fishes are
oviparous. However, there are not a few members of this Class
which show a modification of one or more of these characteristics, as
we shall see hereafter, and which, nevertheless, cannot be
separated from it. The distinction between the Class of Fishes and
that of Batrachians is very slight indeed.
The branch of Zoology which treats of the internal and external
structure of fishes, their mode of life, and their distribution in space
and time, is termed Ichthyology.[1]

You might also like